Pay at the top: a study of the sensitivity of top director remuneration to company specific shocks.
Conyon, Martin J. ; Gregg, Paul
1. Introduction
Public attention has recently focused on pay awards of senior
executives in UK companies. This focus involves both the absolute sums
involved and an implicit question mark over whether such executive pay
increases are justified by the performance of their companies. In spite
of media and public interest it is als the case that determination of
executive compensation has, unlike in the United States, attracted
relatively little attention from academic economists in the UK.(1) This
article aims to partially rectify this situation by examining the
determination of top directors' pay in a sample of UK quoted
companies between 1985 and 1990.
The empirical modelling of top directors' pay is usually couched
in terms of th principal agent paradigm.(2) The shareholders, who are
collectively the principals, attempt to control the chief executives,
who are their agents, by the use of explicit incentives, including
bonuses or share options, which relat their remuneration to the
performance of the firm. In this way they overcome th problem which can
arise if the interests of the executive, who actually runs th firm, are
not the same as the shareholders. However, there are other
considerations which may also be important in shaping the pay of senior
executives (see Tirole, 1988). The behaviour of chief executives may be
constrained to some degree by competition in the product market, and the
risk o take-over or bankruptcy. The performance of the chief executive
may be judged i terms of yardstick competition, comparing the growth of
the firm with others in the same industry for example, and this will
provide information to the shareholders of the firm concerned and also
other potential employers (see for example Gibbons and Murphy, 1992).
This article assesses the importance of changes in the company
specific operating environment, which we call company shocks, in shaping
the compensatio packages of chief executives. Using a unique panel of
industrial companies(3) w address two related issues:
(1) To what extent, if any, are the compensation packages of chief
executives justified by the performance of their companies?
(2) What is the importance of company specific information available
to shareholders (company specific shocks) in conditioning executive pay?
The article is organised as follows. In section 2 we briefly discuss
the role o principal agent theories and the limits to managerial
discretion. The discussio motivates our subsequent empirical analysis.
In section 3 we describe the data together with our modelling strategy.
In section 4 we consider the results and, finally, in section 5 we offer
some concluding remarks.
Our results indicate that growth of directors' pay has averaged
just under 10 per cent per annum in real terms between 1985 and 1990 in
our sample of around 170 firms. Over the period as a whole, therefore,
pay of top executives has risen by 77 per cent in real terms. This
contrasts with real average earnings growth of 2.6 per cent per annum
over the same period for the same firms or 17 per cent over the period
as a whole. In our econometric results it turns out that whilst top
director pay growth is positively related to sales growth it is only
weakly related to a long-term performance measure (total shareholder
returns) and not at all to current accounting profits. There is evidence
to suggest that implicit constraints on managerial discretion are
important. For example, relative measures of performance, yardstick
competition, appear to be applied with sales growth but not shareholder
returns. The ownership status of the firm run by the top manager
(whether it is a parent or subsidiary), the extent to which the firm is
cash constrained and whether the firm derecognised trade union are all
important factors in shaping top pay. More surprisingly, th growth in
executive pay is systematically higher amongst enterprises that expanded
by take-over activity rather than through internal growth and the
returns to sales growth by this method are equally or more highly
rewarded than internal growth, whilst performance as measured by
shareholder returns appears to be unrelated to pay in these
circumstances. This is important because sales growth is substantially
higher after a take-over but performance is often below normal. This
appears to be at odds with the principal agent framework and so raises
questions as to whether effective control of managerial pay setting by
shareholders is in place.
2. Compensation, company performance and operating environment
The principal agent framework has become a widely used theoretical
model to explain the remuneration of high level management and chief
executives (see Main, 1992). Such models typically predict that a
positive relationship between compensation and company performance can
emerge. In the typical agency framewor shareholders (who collectively
act as a risk neutral principal) delegate decision making authority to
managers (the risk averse agent) whose interests potentially diverge from those of the shareholders. This hierarchical structure has an
important source of market failure namely that the effort levels of the
manager are not directly observable by the principal and so cannot be
fully contracted upon. Moreover, the shareholders and the managers'
interests potentially diverge since managerial effort positively affects
the output variable which the shareholder is interested in and hence
adds to the shareholders' payoff, but is costly to the agent and so
detracts from the managers interests.
The problem for the principal is to design a contract such that the
expected monitoring costs for the shareholders are minimised bur still
induce the executive manager to act in the best interests of the
shareholders although now at the executive's own volition (see
Tirole, 1988). The contract offered will depend on the relative risk
attitudes of the parties involved and will also be subject to a
participation and incentive constraint. The participation constraint requires that the manager receive at least his fall back outside option.
The incentive constraint requires that it is in the agent's
interest to undertake the costly action. The contract offered typically
ties the reward received by the manager to a variable that the principal
is interested in such as company performance or shareholder returns (see
Gibbons and Murphy, 1990).
The recent empirical literature has paid much attention to the notion
of relative performance evaluation (yardstick competition). Here the
compensation of the executive, [y.sub.i], in firm i is a function of own
firm performance (o profits), [z.sub.i], but also of other firms'
output [z.sub.i] in the product market. That is the pay scheme is
designed such that [y.sub.i]=[y.sub.i] ([z.sub.i], [z.sub.j]). See
Lazear and Rosen (1981) and Gibbons and Murphy (1990) for an empirical
application of relative performance evaluation. In essence the output of
other firms provides shareholders with important information about the
effort levels of own firm managers. If other firms in similar
circumstances out-perform the original firm, the manager cannot
attribute own poor performance to adverse shocks not under his control.
Strong and Waterson (1987) further entertain the idea that there is a
broader range of company specific signals which also reveal information
about manageria effort levels. In the case of yardstick competition this
was achieved by observing the outturn of other firms. All information
available to shareholders which describes firm performance potentially
reveals underlying effort level of managers. Hence, the shareholder
might offer an incentive payment scheme which can be characterised as
y(z, s) where s is an alternative signal indicating other observable
information available to shareholders upon which the contract may be
conditioned unless of course z itself is a sufficient statistic. This ca
include indicators of yardstick competition, but also firm specific
characteristics. Indeed this provides an important route by which
product marke structures, the risk of bankruptcy and so on can
potentially influence executiv effort, and hence performance, by
increasing the information base for incentive contracts.
As well as providing information to shareholders signals may also
influence managers outside employment opportunities. Fama (1980) argues
that explicit incentives contracts may be redundant since managers are
disciplined through th managerial labour market. That is, superior
performers are suitably rewarded with high wage offers whereas inferior
performers receive low offers. Holmstrom (1982) augmented this
theoretical notion arguing that whilst the disciplining effect of the
managerial labour market is not insubstantial it cannot be regarded as a
pure substitute for efficient contracts. In the absence of contracts he
shows that executive effort falls as the retirement period approaches.
The discipline in the managerial labour market assumes that manager
improve their outside options by effort, congruent with maximising
shareholder wealth (Gibbons and Murphy, 1992, test this empirically).
However, it might be possible for outside options to be related to other
factors not necessarily congruent with the interests of shareholders.(4)
3. Econometric modelling strategy and data description
Modelling strategy
To explore the factors which influence top pay we characterise the
following very general chief executive compensation equation:
COMPENSATIO[N.sub.it] = g (CORPORATE PERFORMANC[E.sub.it],
SIGNAL[S.sub.it]) + [e.sub.it]
where the left hand side variable is defined as the natural logarithm of total salary plus bonus for the highest paid director in company i at
time t.(5) We use two direct measures of corporate performance, namely
shareholder returns an company operating profits.(6) Shareholder return
is defined as the ln[([P.sub.t + [d.sub.t])/[P.sub.t-1]] where P is
share price and d is dividend per share. Operating profits are profits
before tax plus total interest payments and depreciation. In our
estimating model the performance variables pre-date the compensation
variable for two reasons. First, since we suspect that current
performance is not observable at the time of actual pay determination so
that shareholders are likely to use past performance measures as the
relevant information variable. Second, using the lagged performance
variable can avoid any bias induced by joint determination of pay and
performance. In addition, we include firm size as measured by sales.
This, of course, reflects past performance but also measures the
importance of firm size in managerial organisation and structure. Firm
size has been found to be a key determinant of top pay in previous
studies (see Main, 1990, Gregg et al, 1993 for the UK and the survey by
Rosen, 1990).
Section 2 highlighted firm characteristics as important sources of
information to shareholders about the origins of performance. Many such
variables are not directly available in our data set. To control for
unobserved latent firm characteristics we first difference our data
matrix. This procedure implicitly nets out time invariant firm fixed
effects. This methodology is proposed by Murphy (1985), Main (1992) and
Gregg et al (1993) in relation to the determination of top
directors' pay. Expressing the model in first differences provides
a very strong test of which factors are important in shaping top
directors' pay.(7) Also we include a vector of up to T (where T =
time) aggregate time specific variables to filter out aggregate macro
economic shocks Thus, we estimate the following first difference
equation:
[Delta] COMPENSATIO[N.sub.it] = g([Delta]CORPORATE
PERFORMANC[E.sub.it-1], [Delta]SIGNAL[S.sub.it-1], [Delta]Time) +
[u.sub.it]
where the operator [Delta] on any variable X is simply current value
X minus last period value (that is, [Delta]X = [X.sub.t] - [X.sub.t-1])
and u is an error term(8).
As well as netting out firms specific characteristics we consider
five separate groups of variables that may act as signals. These are
product market, debt holding, acquisitions, company ownership status,
and union presence.
Within the product market group we consider industry sales growth or
industry average shareholder returns within the 2 digit SIC industry as
a measure of relative performance evaluation. These are derived from
other companies in our sample and those available from the original 558
firms but excluded for reasons of other missing data; a total of 260
firms were used. We also use a variable capturing managers'
assessment of changing product market competition. Increase competition
is defined by a dummy variable which takes a value one (zero otherwise)
if, in the view of management, the firm faced increasing product market
competition between 1985 and 1990.
A debt measure is included to isolate the potential disciplining
effects that debt holding may have on managerial discretion (see Tirole,
1988, or Nickell, Wadhwani and Wall, 1992). It has been suggested (see
Diamond, 1984) that debt holders, and banks in particular, may perform a
useful policing role for shareholders. Thus, the pay for performance
link need not be as important where debt discipline applies. The debt
variable used is cash to total current liabilities ratio (CLR). The
level of CLR is included lagged twice to remove an potential biases from
contemporaneous observation. This is, in effect, an inverse measure of
short-term cash constraints.
Acquisitions by firms represent a radically different method of firm
growth tha internal or organic expansion. For example, Cowling et al
(1980) conclude that the effects of merger on subsequent performance are
generally adverse?(9) The fact that delegated authority results in
aspects of acquisitive behaviour is clearly of interest to shareholders
in assessing firm performance. In our analysis we include two
specifications of acquisitions. The first is a dummy variable equal to
one (zero otherwise) if the firm engaged in one take-over in the
previous three time periods. The second dummy variable indicates whether
th firm engaged in two or more take-overs in the last three years. The
time lag is to allow for the net impact on pay to become fully apparent
and is a statistically accepted aggregation of the impact on pay over
the three separate years.
If the firm observed is not a parent but a subsidiary of another
(often foreign firm) then the control relationship is somewhat different
as another layer of management is in place to monitor effort and
authority to enact changes in management personnel or structure. Hence,
the pay-performance relationship is unlikely to be as great in these
firms. This variable is a dummy equal to one (zero otherwise) if the
company is a subsidiary. Whether the company divested itself of part of
its assets is also included as a control variable. This is defined as
for acquisitions above, except it applies to divestment.
The 1980s were a period of rapid change in industrial relations. The
reorganisation of the corporate industrial relations machinery may act
as a signal of increased managerial prerogative. The nature of the
industrial relations system is a major influence on corporate
performance (for example, se Machin and Stewart, 1990, Gregg and Machin,
1991, and Nickell, Wadhwani, and Wall, 1992). Specifically, union
recognition acts to raise wages and adversely affect profits. Our
empirical model, therefore, includes a variable reflecting firms where
union presence was diminished in this period. If management reporte that
at least one union was derecognised in any plant within the firm between
1985 and 1990, a derecognition dummy is set to unity. Since the
derecognition observed is normally partial (only 5 out of 30 firms had
total derecognition) then this dummy variable is likely to pick-up firms
where management are re-asserting their prerogative to manage rather
than the effect of union exclusion. A levels union control for all firms
is included to provide a test o the appropriate benchmark against which
to view derecognition.
Data sources
The basic data set that we use is drawn from a survey of companies
carried out in 1990 at NIESR. This produced 558 participating companies
and gives data on the firms' industrial relations conditions and
product market pressures. Datastream International and EXSTAT provide
the firm-level economic variables o interest (for example sales, profits
and so on). EXSTAT was the original sampling frame for the NIESR survey
and covers all industries except banking an insurance but consists of
mainly larger publicly quoted companies. Our top director pay variable
is drawn from Datastream International and is simply the total annual
remuneration package of the highest paid director of the company. This
will include salary and bonuses but not share options. Measures of
company performance including shareholder returns (that is, we need
share price data) i also only available from Datastream. Thus, the need
to use both of these compan based datasets, together with the
requirement that there are at least four continuous records in the
period under consideration for each company, reduces the available
sample size sharply from 558 to 169. The basic data set is augmented by
supplementary information on take-over activity. This was derived from
EXSTAT data tapes directly and from the monthly records of mergers and
acquisitions provided by EXTEL Financial for quoted companies.
The survey into firms' trade union and product market conditions
asked for details of changes that occurred in two sub-periods through
the 1980s, 1980-4 and 1985-90. Furthermore, as sample attrition for
details of directors' remuneration is high prior to 1984 this makes
1985 a sensible starting point fo our empirical analysis.
4. Results
Table 1 provides summary information on our key variables. It details
average total remuneration (salary plus bonus in thousand pounds) for
top directors for the period 1985 to 1990 and average real growth for
the same period. Average real wage growth (wage bill per employee) for
employees in the same companies i also shown by way of comparison. It is
revealed that real wage growth for top directors outstripped the average
pay of all employees by a factor of approximately 3.7. Not
unsurprisingly, however, the standard deviation of directors' pay
was also substantially higher. In the lower half of the table some
measures of current performance are given. Profits' growth over
this perio was extremely rapid and it broadly corresponds to the
considerable cyclical upswing of the mid-1980s. Sales' growth is
much more modest but the similarity of the growth rates of sales and
directors' pay and their standard deviations i quite striking.
Particularly when deviations across the two sub-periods in the sample
are considered, 1985 to 1987 and 1988 to 1990.
Table 2 presents estimates of the effect of the lagged firm
performance measure on top director pay. Column 1 includes the two
direct performance measures (proportional) growth in operating profits
and shareholder returns. All estimated models report Huber (1967)
standard errors and are robust to arbitrar heteroscedasticity. The
result in column 1 illustrates that the profits' term i not
significant but shareholder returns has a small but significant impact.
The importance of such long-term measures of performance is now well
documented (se Gibbons and Murphy, 1990, Gregg et al, 1993 and Conyon
and Leech, 1994). The co-efficient estimate reported here is broadly in
line with available UK evidence. It implies that a doubling of
shareholder returns raises directors' pay by just 6 per cent.
Indeed, when evaluated at median executive earnings it implies that a
TABULAR DATA OMITTED 10 per cent increase in shareholder returns raises
top pay by only 491 pounds. The inclusion of a change in log sales'
term (column 2) does not change this pattern much but note that the
sales' growth term is much larger than that for shareholder
returns.(10) The result here is i line with other recent UK work (Main,
1992, Gregg, Machin and Szymanski, 1993 and Conyon and Leech, 1994 and
Conyon, 1994). These authors report top pay equations in which the
pay-performance link is weak and the relatively stronger variable is
sales' growth. Column 3 splits the shareholder return result betwee
1985 and 1987 and 1988 to 1990. This is purely to replicate Gregg et al,
1993, who demonstrated that for their sample of the FT top 500 firms the
pay-performance link diminished between the early and late-1980s. Our
sample would include some of these large firms but will also include a
TABULAR DATA OMITTED large number of smaller quoted companies (broadly
drawn from the top 2000 companies rather than the top 500). The evidence
in column 3 is consistent with the notion that there is heterogeneity in
the pay for performance link since there is no evidence of a pay and
performance link in the post-1987 period. This heterogeneity result is
also observed in Conyon, 1994, for a sampl of 214 firms from 1983 to
1987 and 1988 to 1993.
Column 4 is more central to our analysis. It introduces industry
benchmarks for the two key measures of company performance identified.
As would be expected from benchmark comparisons the industry sales
growth term is negative and insignificantly different from the
(negative) companies own sales growth. In other words sales growth
relative to competitors appears the correct specification. However,
industry shareholder returns is positively signed and insignificant.
Hence benchmark comparisons of share price and dividend performance of
other companies does not appear to be used in assessing managerial pay.
In column 1 of Table 3 we show the direct correlation between the
available corporate shock information and directors' pay without
including the performanc measures. The product market, debt, ownership,
union and take-over controls are now introduced. Only the debt measure,
the take-over dummies and whether the firms are subsidiaries have direct
and significant effects. All of these information sources are really
concerned with interpreting performance indicators in addition to any
direct effect on pay of top managers. Hence, column 2 introduces the
performance measures (relative sales growth and shareholder returns as
preferred from column 4 of Table 2. The derecognition term is now weakly
significant (at the 10 per cent significance level). The results are
somewhat curious as firms engaging in take-over activity, pay a
substantial premium to their top directors. A single take-over results
in highe pay growth of 2.7 per cent per annum for three years or just
under 8 per cent. Two or more take-overs attracts a coefficient of just
over twice the size at 6. per cent per annum. Firms which were became
more cash constrained raised pay levels. This could reflect the increase
of risk attached to continuing to work for liquidity constrained
companies. It implies that managers, engaging in cash financed take-over
activity, receive a considerable pay premium. Firms engaging in such a
strategy have been identified as highly vulnerable to the subsequent
1990-3 recession (see Geroski and Gregg, 1994).
Table 3. The responsiveness of top directors' pay to product market, debt,
merger and industrial relations shocks: 1985-90
Constant .1375 .1195 .1123
(.0169) (.0177) (.0135)
[Delta]Competition -.0107 -.0010
(.0169) (.0168)
CLR(t-2) -.0493 -.0467 -.0467
(.0191) (.0190) (.0189)
One acquisition in previous three years .0308 .0266 .0263
(.0188) (.0189) (.0186)
Two acquisitions in previous three years .0689 .0641 .0648
(.0281) (.0272) (.0272)
Assets sold -.0089 -.0062
(.0268) (.0272)
Subsidiary in 1990 -.0381 -.0354 -.0370
(.0203) (.0204) (.0203)
Trade union derecognition .0266 .0322 .0305
(.0192) (.0192) (.0176)
Recognised trade union -.0062 -.0011
(.0182) (.0179)
[Delta]log relative sales (t-1) .0851 .0873
(.0293) (.0286)
Shareholder returns (t-l) .0468 .0458
(.0241) (.0241)
Time dummies Yes Yes Yes
F=1.25 F=0.80 F=0.80
(5,677) (5,675) (5,678)
[R.sup.2] 0.037 0.061 0.061
Observations 691 691 691
Companies 169 169 169
1. Variable definitions are fully described in the data appendix. Note that CLR
is the cash liability ratio. An F test of joint significance of the time dummie
is presented.
However, these results do not allow the pay for performance link to
vary according to whether performance is attributable to the shocks
described above. For instance an increase in firm size through
acquisitive behaviour is effectively a size shift rather than an
indicator of performance. We might expect the alternative methods of
growth to have differing relations with pay increases. We therefore
interact the two performance measures (relative sales' growth and
shareholder returns) with the shocks described above. However, to keep
the specification as parsimonious as possible given the small sample
sizes we drop the insignificant terms in column 2.
Table 4 reports these interactions separately for each type of shock
or signal. Column 1 is for take-over TABULAR DATA OMITTED activity. Both
interaction terms were insignificantly (and positive for sales but
negative for shareholder returns) different from the base group (of
organic growth). This implies that sales increases generated at times of
take-over activity are not less related t directors' pay growth
than at other times nor are the returns to shareholders despite the
direct involvement of chief executives in these decisions.
Column 2 of Table 4 looks at relative sales' growth and
shareholder returns where the lagged cash liabilities ratio is above
average for the sample (that is, a high CLR/low CLR dummy set equal to
unity). There is again no significant variation in terms of
pay-performance links where debt is high. The CLR(-2) measure itself
remains strongly significant.
Column 3 splits the performance measures according to whether the
firm is a subsidiary and hence where higher echelons of management will
be in place to monitor performance. Sales' growth in subsidiaries
proves unrelated to pay (wit a negative coefficient) and significantly
different from that relation in paren companies. There is no important
variation in shareholder returns, however.
Column 4 looks at performance where derecognition has occurred. The
derecognition term itself is better determined but the sales'
growth and shareholder returns offer no significant variation.
Thus, the only important variation occurs where control has not been
fully delegated and here the sales' growth term is unimportant.
However, the subsidiaries in our data are predominately not engaging in
merger/take-over activity. 17 per cent of subsidiaries engaged in a
take-over as opposed to 36 per cent of non-subsidiary firms (t test of
unequal means is 3.47). In column 5 we, therefore, re-evaluate the
acquisition/performance interaction with subsidiaries excluded. The step
returns to a take-over are now much greater at 4.6 per cent for the
three years after a take-over and 8.1 per cent if two or more take-overs
have occurred. The sales' growth term is nearly double that in the
absence of a take-over, although still not well determined. However, the
shareholder returns are clearly' unrelated to pay, unlike where
take-overs have not occurred. This is important because sales'
growth is higher after a take-over and shareholder returns lower (where
there has not been a take-over relative sales' growth is 6.5 per
cent, and where there has been a take-over it is 10.7 per cent. The t
test of the means is 1.93; shareholder returns in the absence of
take-overs is 23.9 per cent and where there has been a take-over it is
16.6 per cent; the t test rejecting equivalence is 2.73). It seems
perverse that top directors are rewarded for organising take-overs,
benefit again from any increase in sales associated with such a
take-over but are isolated from an costs in terms of shareholder returns
which are thus wholly born by the shareholders.
5. Conclusions
This article has addressed a number of issues concerning the
determination of top directors' pay. We have argued that as well as
corporate performance acting as a signal for managerial effort there are
also other important corporate specific information available to
shareholders (signals) which are likely to be taken into consideration
in pay setting. Indeed, we argued that signals emanating from product
market, debt holding, acquisitive behaviour and union presence all
potentially reveal information about the extent to which corporate
performance is due to managerial effort. In addition, these company
specific signals may reveal information about managers outside career
options which will also be reflected in managerial remuneration.
The empirical analysis suggests that all the types of signal
considered are important in shaping pay. Relative performance evaluation
or the use of the performance of other firms is taken into account in
determining pay and the coefficient is consistent with relative sales
growth being the appropriate measure of performance used. However, the
same result does not appear to apply to shareholder returns. Reduced
union presence results in higher pay for top executives but heading a
subsidiary lowered pay in this period. Most surprisingly however, was
the results of cash holding and acquisitive behaviour by firms. The
results indicated that lower cash holdings relative to current
liabilities raises pay, as does expansion through take-overs. Firm
growth by take-over which results in the firm being cash poor is a
strategy for managers which raises pay considerably, despite other
evidence which suggests that such behaviour does not enhance firm
performance. Indeed such a strategy left firms highly vulnerable to the
subsequent recession. This may be explicable if increasing firm size
improves managers outside options. Either way this result raises
questions about the degree of effective control of top managers pay and
over decision making concerning who controls and benefits from take-over
decisions.
Overall the results are consistent with other UK and US evidence that
corporate performance explains little of the very large pay growth
achieved by top executives in the late-1980s. Even after performance
effects and those associated with take-over activity and the like are
netted out (what can be described as the going rate) annual pay rises of
13 to 15 per cent per year wer achieved between 1985 and 1990. This
would imply that either managerial skills were becoming increasingly
valued by shareholders or that top executives were increasingly able to
influence their own pay levels.
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
NOTES
(1) The considerable US literature on the determinants of executive
compensatio includes Gibbons and Murphy (1992, 1990), Jensen and Murphy
(1990), Leonard (1990) and Murphy (1985). Recent UK research includes
Cosh (1975), Main (1991, 1992), Gregg et al (1993) and Conyon and Leech
(1994).
(2) The principal agent model, and the theoretical design of optimal
contracts, is considered formally by Grossman and Hart (1983).
Typically, such models examine how incentives schemes are constructed in
the presence of moral hazard. Tirole (1988) provides a formal review.
(3) This is augmented from the data set employed by Gregg and Yates
(1991).
(4) We have in mind that a managers' outside option is
positively related to th size of the firm they control. Hence growth via
takeover activity can raise outside options in the managerial labour
market, but takeovers are not necessarily consistent with shareholder
interests.
(5) Other authors have dealt at length with the appropriate
formulation of the dependent variable. For example, should the salary
component be separated from the bonus element? How should
directors' share holdings in the company be value prior to their
realisation? The empirical treatment of these important issues i dealt
with by Antle and Smith (1985). A partial justification of the salary
plu bonus measure is provided by Lewellen and Huntsman (1970) who
demonstrate a strong cross sectional association between a wider more
comprehensive measure o executive compensation and the salary plus bonus
variable.
(6) Many studies use market valuation type measures of corporate
performance rather than operating profits or sales. The results are
mixed. Conyon and Leech (1994) use market value measures and find only
small performance effects. Decko (1988) finds that accounting based
measures are important. Abowd (1990), however, discusses alternative
accounting and market based performance measures and concludes in favour
of market based measures.
(7) This follows since we are implicitly including individual firm
specific dummies in our equation as well as netting out aggregate
factors.
(8) In the case of profits it is the proportional growth
rate:[Delta]X = ([X.sub.t] - [X.sub.t-1])/[X.sub.t-1] since the profit
series contains some negative values.
(9) This result seems quite general. Acquisitions appear to do little
for post merger performance. A review is provided in Hay and Morris
(1991) which also considers alternative methods of assessing these
effects.
(10) We report the [R.sup.2] values for all models but note that by
the very nature of difference equations these values usually turn out to
be small in magnitude.
REFERENCES
Abowd, JM, (1990), 'Does performance-based managerial
compensation affect corporate performance?', Industrial and Labor
Relations Review, no 43, pp 52-73
Antle, R and A Smith, (1985), 'Measuring executive compensation:
methods and an application', Journal of Accounting Research, no 23,
pp 296-325.
Conyon, MJ, (1994), 'Corporate governance and executive
compensation', Oxford University mimeograph.
Conyon, MJ and D Leech, (1994), 'Executive compensation,
corporate performance and ownership structure', Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, no 56, p 229-247.
Cosh, A, (1975), 'The remuneration of chief executives in the
United Kingdom', Economic Journal, pp 75-94.
Cowling, K .... et al, (1980), Mergers and Economic Performance,
Cambridge University Press.
Deckop, JR, (1988), 'Determinants of chief executive officer
compensation', Industrial and Labor Relations Review, no 41, pp
215-226.
Diamond, DW, (1984), 'Financial intermediation and delegated
monitoring', Revie of Economic Studies, no 51, pp 393-414.
Fama, E, (1980), 'Agency problems and the theory of the
firm', Journal of Political Economy, pp 288-307.
Geroski, P and P Gregg, (1993), 'Coping with recession',
National Institute Economic Review, no 146, pp 64-75.
Gibbons, R and KJ Murphy, (1990), 'Relative performance
evaluation for chief executive officers', Industrial and Labor
Relations Review, no 41, pp 30-51.
Gibbons, R and KJ Murphy, (1992), 'Optimal incentive contracts
in the presence of career concerns, theory and evidence', Journal
of Political Economy, no 100, pp 468-505.
Gregg, P and Yates, A (1991), 'Changes in wage setting
arrangements and trade union presence in the 1980s', British
Journal of Industrial Relations, no 29, p 361-377.
Gregg, P, Machin, S and Szymanski, S, (1993) 'The disappearing
relationship between directors' pay and corporate
performance', British Journal of Industria Relations, no 31, pp
1-9.
Grossman, S and O Hart, (1980), 'Take-over bids, the free rider
problem and the corporation', Bell Journal of Economics, no 11, pp
42-64.
Grossman, SJ and OD Hart, (1983), 'An analysis of the principal
agent problem', Econometrica, no 51, pp 7-45.
Hay D and D Morris, (1991), Industrial Economics and Organisation,
Oxford University Press.
Holmstrom, B, (1982), 'Managerial incentive problems: a dynamic
perspective', i Essays in Economics and Management in Honour of
Lars Wahlbeck.
Huber, PJ, (1967), 'The behavior of maximum likelihood estimates
under non-standard conditions', Proceedings of the Fifth Berkely
Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, no 1, pp 221-233.
Jensen MC and KJ Murphy, (1990), 'Performance pay and top
management incentives', Journal of Political Economy, no 98, pp
225-264.
Lazear, E and S Rosen, (1981), 'Rank-order tournaments as
optimal labour contracts', Journal of Political Economy, no 89, pp
841-864. Leonard, J, (1990) 'Executive pay and corporate
performance', Industrial and Labor Relations Review, no 43, pp
13-29.
Lewellen, WG and B Huntsman, (1970), 'Managerial pay and
corporate performance' American Economic Review, no 60, pp 710-720.
Machin, S and M Stewart, (1990), 'Unions and the financial
performance of British private sector establishments', Journal of
Applied Econometrics, no 5, pp 327-350.
Main, B, (1991), 'Top executive pay and performance',
Managerial and Decision Economics, no 12, pp 219-229.
Main, B, (1992), 'Top executive pay and company
performance', University of Edinburgh, mimeograph.
Murphy, K (1985), 'Corporate performance and managerial
incentives', Journal of Accounting and Economics, no 7, pp 11-42.
Nickell, S, S Wadhwani and M Wall, (1992), 'Productivity growth
in UK companies 1975-1986', European Economic Review, no36, pp
1055-85.
Rosen, S, (1990), 'Contracts and the market for
executives', NBER working paper 3542.
Stewart, MB, (1990), 'Union wage differentials, product market
influences and the division of rents', Economic Journal, no 100, pp
1122-1137.
Strong, N and M Waterson, (1987), 'Principals, agents and
information', in The Economics of the Firm, edited R Clarke and T
McGuinness.
Tirole, J, (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organisation, MIT press.