Is Europe an optimum currency area? Symmetric versus asymmetric shocks in the EC.
Caporale, Guglielmo Maria
Introduction
Much of the debate on the desirability of a monetary union in Europe
has focused on the question of whether Europe can be described as an
optimum currency area (OCA). The European Commission in its report
'One money, one market' takes the view that this theoretical
framework gives useful insights for the analysis of the economics of EMU
and its potential costs and benefits, even though it is not decisive,
but it has to be complemented by other approaches. Many studies have
tried to provide an answer to the topical question of the optimality of
introducing a single currency, adopting different research strategies.
This note explains why a knowledge of the nature of the shocks is
crucial to evaluating the potential costs of creating a monetary union,
and applies a statistical technique known as principal components
analysis to distinguish between common and country-specific shocks.
After surveying the existing literature on OCAs, we present some new
empirical results which confirm the relative importance of asymmetric
shocks in the Community. A well-functioning monetary union could require
some instruments for adjusting to shocks of this kind, for example
fiscal transfers across the member countries.
Optimum currency areas
The adoption of a single currency will have both benefits and costs.
The former will be mainly in the form of lower transaction costs and of
the disappearance of currency risks. The latter will be due to the
inability of national governments and central banks to pursue
independent monetary policies to stabilise the economy. The extent to
which the loss of this policy instrument will affect the adjustment to
equilibrium will depend on the degree of flexibility of factor markets
and the nature of the shocks hitting the economy: the more rigid factor
markets and the more country-specific the shocks, the more important
will be the loss of monetary autonomy. These issues are addressed by the
theory of optimum currency areas (OCAs), whose implications are crucial
to answering the question whether Europe should proceed to adopting a
single currency. If factors of production are not sufficiently mobile,
asymmetric shocks result in high costs of adjustment, in terms of higher
unemployment and lower output, in the presence of fixed exchange
rates.(1)
New Classical economists have long suggested that the transaction
costs resulting from multiple currencies should be weighed against the
benefits of each country being able to adopt its own optimal monetary
policy. In their view, the problem of setting monetary policy in an
optimal way is not dissimilar from that of choosing the optimal tax
structure, as the process of money creation can be seen as being
essentially a tax on private agents' money holdings. Consequently,
if the macroeconomic environment is significantly different across
countries, different tax structures and currencies are the optimal
outcome.
The arguments for and against monetary integration are not as
straightforward as those concerning economic integration more generally.
As Paul Krugman (1989) says:
'The economics of international money, by contrast |to those of
trade integration~, are not at all well understood; they hinge crucially
not only on sophisticated and ambiguous issues like credibility and
coordination, but on even deeper issues like transaction costs and
bounded rationality'
In its study 'One Market, One Money' (1990), the European
Commission relies heavily upon the theory of optimum currency areas to
evaluate the economic impact of EMU. Much of the analysis is based on
the framework developed by Robert Mundell, Ronald McKinnon and other
economists in the 1960s, though it is stressed that other fields of
economic research are relevant for the analysis of EMU. They include new
contributions to the analysis of the following topics:
* the workings of markets in the presence of externalities,
adjustment or information costs (see Baldwin, 1990);
* the choice of an optimal exchange-rate regime in a stochastic
environment (see Argy, 1990, for a survey);
* macroeconomic games between the authorities and the private
sector and policy coordination issues (see the seminal paper by Barro
and Gordon, 1983, and the survey by Currie, Holtham and Hughes Hallett,
1989);
* the relative performance of alternative exchange-rate systems
(see Baxter and Stockman, 1988);
* the economics of EMU (see Brociner and Levine, 1992).
Costs and benefits of EMU are evaluated in 'One market, one
money' by running a set of simulations with two macroeconomic
models: the Quest model developed by the Commission Services, and the
IMF Multimod model. The Commission concludes that EMU ensures more
microeconomic efficiency and macroeconomic stability. The improvement in
the latter is put down especially to a reduction in the degree of
exchange-rate instability, and to higher credibility of the monetary
authorities. The Commission, however, recognises that the nature of
macroeconomic shocks is crucial to assessing the net benefit of EMU. As
they put it:
'..the only important disadvantage of EMU concerns macroeconomic
stability in the presence of asymmetric shocks. This is indeed a
well-known argument and has unambiguously to be considered a cost, but
one that should be weighed against the clear advantages EMU yields in
other fields' ('One Market, One Money', p. 56).
The Commission also points out that, while country-specific shocks
are by definition asymmetric, common shocks may affect national
economies either symmetrically or asymmetrically, and that the main
factors determining whether or not their impact is symmetric are the
degree of product market integration, and differences in economic
behaviour and structures. They empirically examine the degree of
asymmetry in sector-specific shocks and find that sectors producing
homogeneous goods with few trade barriers mainly experience symmetric
shocks. In the other sectors, there appears to be an inverse correlation
between the existence of trade barriers and the degree of symmetry of
the shocks, with the obvious implication that the completion of the
common market should decrease sector-specific asymmetric shocks.
The seminal paper on optimum currency areas (OCAs) is due to Mundell
(1961). In his definition, an optimum currency area is an economic unit
where factors of production are mobile and whose regions are affected
symmetrically by shocks. Mundell stressed that the degree of labour
mobility should be the main criterion for the choice of such an area. In
a famous example, he considered the case of two countries A and B
producing good a and b respectively. If there is a permanent preference
shift from a to b, equilibrium can be restored by a change either in
quantities or in the relative price. Migration of the labour force
across the two countries will achieve the first. As for the second,
given the fact that the nominal exchange rate can not be changed if
there is a common currency, the remaining possibility is a fall in the
price level in A relative to B. In the presence of rigidities, there
will be a sluggish adjustment and A will incur unemployment costs. Hence
the adoption of a single currency is optimal only if factors are highly
mobile. However, even high labour mobility does not necessarily imply
that the adoption of a single currency should be optimal, as
'It is simply doubtful that the movement of working masses can
be relied on as a substitute for payments adjustment when it can be
assumed that they are reluctant to move even within the same
country' (Ishiyama, 1975)
A further criticism often levelled against Mundell's type of
analysis is that it ignores the fact that floating exchange rates can
result in non-cooperative or sub-optimal policies.
The permanent preference shock discussed above is an example of an
asymmetric shock, in which case the constraints of a monetary union are
binding if labour is not sufficiently mobile. The recessionary effects
are transmitted across countries because the exchange rates are fixed,
and they can not be used to offset disturbances. Under these
circumstances, it would be optimal to adjust the exchange rates, i.e.
the countries are not an OCAs. Clearly, a common policy response would
be optimal only if the disturbance affected all the countries in the
same direction and to the same extent. Hence some knowledge of the
incidence of the two different types of shocks, i.e. Community-wide and
country-specific disturbances, is necessary to give a realistic
assessment of the prospects for EMU.
Mundell's criterion of a high factor mobility (capital as well
as labour) is not the only one proposed in the theoretical literature on
currency unions to determine the desirability of such a union (see
Masson and Taylor, 1992, for a similar discussion). We mentioned above
the reduction in transaction costs which derives from the creation of a
currency union. This clearly implies that, the higher the degree of
interdependence between the prospective members of the union in terms of
trade flows, the greater will be the benefits from a monetary union. A
related result is due to McKinnon (1963), who showed that in more open
countries the exchange rate is less effective as a policy instrument,
and hence its loss represents a lower cost. Krugman (1989) argues that
the costs of fixing the exchange rates are outweighed by the benefits if
there is intensive trade within the currency area.
A further criterion is based on the degree of diversification of the
economy (see Kenen, 1969). The more specialised countries are in the
production of different goods, the more likely it is that shocks will be
asymmetric, the more costly it is to forego exchange-rate flexibility.
Finally, an issue not considered in the original literature is the
flexibility of wages and prices. There is plenty of evidence that real
wages are quite rigid in Europe, which implies that the real exchange
rate is also quite rigid (see Eichengreen, 1991). Consequently
fluctuations in the nominal exchange rate do not have large real effects
in the labour market, and its irrevocable fixing (or, equivalently, the
adoption of a single currency) would not be particularly costly in terms
of unemployment.(2)
In the empirical literature, some studies have looked at the
variability of real exchange rates as an indication of the asymmetry of
the shocks, as this should be related to demand or supply shifts across
countries. Poloz (1990) found that real exchange rates between Canadian
provinces are more volatile than those between the major four European
countries, and hence a monetary union is feasible. Conversely, they seem
to be more variable in Europe than between US regions (see Eichengreen,
1990b, who uses consumer price indices for four geographical regions),
and less variable within European countries than between them (see De
Grauwe and Vanhaverbeke, 1991, whose analysis is based on unit labour
costs). Similarly, real share prices, which should reflect the present
value of present plus expected future profits, are found to diverge more
in Europe than in Canada, with the implication that shocks are less
symmetric across Europe (see Eichengreen, 1990a).
Other papers examine the behaviour of output with the aim of
establishing the nature of the shocks. Cohen and Wyplosz (1989), who
associate asymmetric with transitory shocks and symmetric with permanent
shocks, find that symmetric shocks to France and Germany dominate the
asymmetric ones. However, the opposite is true when France and Germany
taken together ('Europe') are compared to the US, suggesting
that a monetary union between France and Germany would be more
well-functioning than one between 'Europe' and the US. A
similar approach is taken by Weber (1990). He finds that, in the
original members of the ERM, real wages and the unemployment rate during
the EMS period are dominated by asymmetric shocks, whereas inflation is
mainly affected by symmetric shocks.
Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1992) point out that movements in relative
prices and output contain only limited information regarding the nature
of the shocks, as they could be due to either asymmetric shocks or
different speeds of adjustment. Their approach to identifying the
disturbances is, following Blanchard and Quah (1989), to decompose a
bivariate VAR including the first difference of the logarithm of output
and prices. They assume that demand and supply shocks are uncorrelated
and that only the latter have permanent effects on output. Their main
findings are that supply shocks are larger in magnitude and less
correlated across regions in Europe than in the US, and that there is a
core of EC members (Germany, France, Belgium, Luxembourg, the
Netherlands and Denmark) whose supply shocks are relatively small and
highly correlated and another group of states, the 'EC
periphery', with bigger and more country-specific shocks.
Principal components analysis
In this section we report some estimates of correlation matrices for
output innovations in EC countries. These correlation matrices will have
large positive off-diagonal elements if output fluctuations are mainly
due to aggregate shocks. We then employ a statistical technique known as
principal components analysis to determine to what extent the system is
driven by symmetric as opposed to asymmetric disturbances. Such
procedure is, however, subject to an important caveat. The assumption
made is that all comovements of the variables in the system can be
attributed to common factors, that are by definition unobservable and
that are identified as Community-wide shocks in our case. Since
comovements can also be generated by unique factors (in our case,
country-specific shocks) which are, however, correlated with each other,
only an upper limit for the explanatory power of the aggregate shocks
can be determined.
The percentage of the normalised total variance of each variable
which can be explained by the individual principal components equals the
squares of the factor loadings (also known as connection coefficients),
which show the weight applied to each component in expressing each
series as a function of the components. The sums of the squares of the
factor loadings, known as communality estimates, can therefore be
interpreted as the percentages of the total variance of each variable
explained by all principal components included in the model.
We have to generate estimates of the shocks or innovations to the set
of economies of interest. One way of doing this is to estimate the
following vector autoregression (VAR):
|Delta~|y.sub.t~ = a + B|Delta~|y.sub.t - 1~ + C|Delta~|y.sub.t -2~ +
D|Delta~|y.sub.t - 3~ + E|Delta~|y.sub.t - 4~ + |u.sub.t~ (1)
where |y.sub.t~ stands for the logarithm of nominal GDP, a is a
vector of constants, B, C, D and E are coefficient matrices, and
|u.sub.t~ is a vector of disturbance terms. The estimation period is
1970: 1 1991:4.(3)
Table 1 reports the correlation matrix of the shocks, and suggests
that EC-wide disturbances do not play a very important role in driving
GDP fluctuations. Although all the off-diagonal elements but one are
different from zero, indicating that shocks are correlated across
countries, most of them are not significant at the 5 per cent level.(4)
The size of the correlation coefficients varies across countries, with
Germany exhibiting some of the biggest coefficients. In most cases the
correlation is positive, but the shocks to Belgium appear to be
negatively correlated to fluctuations in the Southern countries, and,
surprisingly, to shocks to the German economy. It is also to be noted
that the shocks to Italy move in the opposite direction of these to
France, and are not significantly correlated to shocks to the German or
UK economy. Conversely, the shocks affecting the UK and French economies
are highly correlated to the German ones. Disturbances in the
Netherlands do not appear to mirror closely the shocks to the German
economy, perhaps reflecting the role of energy in Dutch output. On the
whole, fluctuations in the remaining countries, especially the
Mediterranean ones, are less closely related to those in the three
'core' countries, although the correlations between Germany
and Denmark, France and Spain, and the UK and Belgium are quite high.
Table 1. Nominal GDP: correlation matrix of shocks
Denmark Spain Portugal Greece
Denmark 1.00
Spain 0.09 1.00
Portugal 0.39 0.02 1.00
Greece 0.18 0.24 0.26 1.00
Germany 0.34 0.03 0.47 0.07
France 0.17 0.26 0.10 0.12
Belgium -0.28 -0.02 -0.16 -0.21
Netherlands -0.15 0.36 0.00 0.04
Italy 0.08 -0.01 0.09 0.31
Ireland 0.17 0.17 0.15 0.08
UK 0.04 -0.21 0.01 -0.22
Germany France Belgium Netherlands
Germany 1.00
France 0.20 1.00
Belgium -0.31 0.01 1.00
Netherlands 0.01 0.16 0.40 1.00
Italy -0.11 -0.24 0.21 -0.03
Ireland 0.09 0.10 0.21 0.18
UK 0.25 0.25 0.22 0.10
Italy Ireland UK
Italy 1.00
Ireland 0.29 1.00
UK 0.01 0.16 1.00
Number of observations: 79.
Principal components analysis was then carried out on the estimated
residuals |u.sub.t~. For the EC as a whole, we find that a large
percentage of the fluctuations of GDP is driven by three principal
components. Table 2 contains the eigenvalues and cumulative |R.sup.2~
for each component. The characteristic roots equal the sum of the
squared loading factors, and the cumulative |R.sup.2~, which is the
fraction of the total variance of the original variables explained by
all the components up to and including the third, is equal to the
corresponding eigenvalue divided by the number of variables. It appears
that 50 per cent of the total variance is accounted for by the three
principal components, which can be interpreted as EC-wide shocks.
It is of interest to consider whether similar patterns can be
observed across the EC member states. Factor loadings by country are
reported in Table 3. They show the direction in which the corresponding
variable moves with regard to the other variables, positive loadings
indicating that there is comovement. The first principal component has
positive loadings for all countries, with the exception of Belgium and
the Netherlands, which seem to move in the opposite direction to their
European partners. The factor loadings for the second principal
component would indicate that Germany and the rest of the Community,
with the exception of Denmark and Portugal, do not have synchronised
cycles. Concerning the factor loadings for the third component, it
appears that Germany, France, the UK, Belgium and the Netherlands have
similar economic cycles, whilst the other countries, which have factor
loadings of the opposite sign, experience different economic
fluctuations.
Table 2. Nominal GDP
Component Eigenvalue Cumulative |R.sup.2~
1 2.24 0.20
2 1.85 0.37
3 1.44 0.50
Table 3. Nominal GDP: factor loadings
PC1 PC2 PC3
Denmark 0.71 0.12 0.02
Spain 0.29 -0.43 0.20
Portugal 0.72 0.02 0.03
Greece 0.48 -0.07 0.56
Germany 0.70 0.08 -0.37
France 0.39 -0.33 -0.43
Belgium -0.44 -0.69 -0.03
Netherlands -0.02 -0.74 -0.08
Italy 0.07 -0.27 0.63
Ireland 0.28 -0.57 0.14
UK 0.07 -0.31 -0.59
Finally, Table 4 gives in turn the percentage of the variance of the
shocks affecting each country explained by each of the three principal
components, by the first two components, and by all three of them. As
can be seen, the percentage explained by the first two components ranges
from a minimum of 8 per cent in Italy to a maximum of 67 per cent in
Belgium. When a third component is added, the range is from 30 per cent
(Spain) to 67 per cent (Belgium). The third component adds significantly
to the explanatory power of the principal component model in many EC
countries, especially Italy, where it seems to be the only symmetric
shock of substantial importance.
We have carried out the same analysis for real GDP. A system of fixed
exchange rates requires nominal convergence but not necessarily real
convergence, where real TABULAR DATA OMITTED convergence is taken to
mean narrowing the dispersion of real variables, e.g. output per head or
unemployment rates(5). The latter might not even be desirable during the
transition period, although it is a long-term goal of European
integration. Therefore it is important to distinguish between static and
dynamic convergence. In steady state, given free factor mobility, factor
price equalisation (FPE) and purchasing power parity (PPP) for tradeable
goods will hold in EMU (see Mundell, 1961). However, the dynamic
adjustment towards the steady state might require the persistence of
some differentials to bring about convergence in the long run, which
means that further real convergence prior to the establishment of EMU
might not be called for.
The shocks are again generated by estimating a VAR and a principal
components model is then estimated. The correlation matrix (see Table 5)
now contains even less significant coefficients. The correlation
patterns, though, are rather similar, with the shocks to Belgium and the
Netherlands being negatively correlated to those to Denmark, Portugal,
Greece and France. The correlation coefficients between Ireland and the
UK, and the Southern countries are also negative. Furthermore, it
appears that the correlation between real shocks to the Dutch economy
and shocks to Germany and France is, if anything, negative. The
percentage of the total variance explained by the model is slightly
lower in the case of real shocks, equalling 49 per cent (see Table 6).
The factor loadings on the first two components (see Table 7) show,
respectively, that the cycles in the Netherlands and Ireland are not
synchronised with the rest of the Community, and that only fluctuations
in Denmark and Portugal follow those in Germany. As for the third
component, it suggests that Germany, Denmark, Ireland and the UK move in
the same direction in response to real shocks to their economies. The
first two components (see Table 8) account for a maximum of 64 per cent
of the total variance (France) and for a minimum of 13 per cent (UK).
When a third component is added, the maximum becomes 68 per cent
(France), and the minimum 23 per cent (Ireland).
Table 5. Real GDP: correlation matrix of shocks
Denmark Spain Portugal Greece
Denmark 1.00
Spain -0.08 1.00
Portugal 0.12 -0.10 1.00
Greece 0.09 0.10 0.21 1.00
Germany 0.32 0.04 0.32 0.20
France 0.29 0.48 0.04 0.27
Belgium -0.06 0.05 -0.12 -0.01
Netherlands -0.37 0.06 -0.19 -0.27
Italy 0.05 0.29 0.22 0.14
Ireland 0.09 0.08 -0.07 -0.09
UK 0.28 0.04 -0.14 0.02
Germany France Belgium Netherlands
Germany 1.00
France 0.16 1.00
Belgium 0.18 -0.01 1.00
Netherlands -0.12 -0.39 0.16 1.00
Italy -0.02 0.31 0.12 0.23
Ireland -0.01 0.05 0.09 0.18
UK 0.13 0.15 0.23 -0.01
Italy Ireland UK
Italy 1.00
Ireland 0.17 1.00
UK 0.05 0.05 1.00
Conclusions
In this note we have first briefly discussed the traditional criteria
under which a currency union is deemed to be viable in the 'optimum
currency area' literature. They are labour mobility, wage and price
flexibility, diversification of the economies of the member countries,
and interdependence as measured by the volume of trade between the
potential members of the monetary union. We have then surveyed the other
empirical studies carried out to date, which provide mixed evidence on
whether or not the EC is an optimum currency area. The conclusion most
often reached is that the forthcoming monetary union will be successful
only if it will be restricted, at least initially, to those states with
more economic homogeneity and who experience more similar disturbances
(see e.g. the 'two-track' EMU proposal put forward by
Dornbusch, 1990).
Table 6. Real GDP
Component Eigenvalue Cumulative |R.sup.2~
1 1426893-5312.28 E0-21
2 1.73 0.36
3 1.38 0.49
We have shown that asymmetric shocks account for a sizeable
percentage of GDP fluctuations in the EC. Since principal components
analysis only sets an upper limit to TABULAR DATA OMITTED the percentage
of the total variance which can be explained by the common factors, they
could be even more important than suggested by our results. This does
not imply that EMU is not feasible, as real convergence is not required
in the transition period before the establishment of a monetary union.
However, it does indicate that the operation of a currency union could
be rather difficult, although, unlike Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1992), we
do not find conclusive evidence that there are in the EC a
'core' and a 'periphery'. Some instruments for
adjusting to asymmetric disturbances, e.g. fiscal transfers, could
therefore be necessary.
Table 7. Real GDP: factor loadings
PC1 PC2 PC3
Denmark 0.62 0.22 0.39
Spain 0.32 -0.62 -0.37
Portugal 0.42 0.32 -0.19
Greece 0.54 0.09 -0.24
Germany 0.74 -0.30 -0.22
France 0.74 -0.30 -0.22
Belgium 0.01 -0.43 0.52
Netherlands -0.57 -0.53 0.07
Italy 0.31 -0.60 -0.27
Ireland -0.00 -0.44 0.19
UK 0.27 0.24 0.65
APPENDIX
In principal component analysis the observations are normalised so
that their expected value equals 0 and their variance equals 1, to
yield:
|z.sub.gt~ = |x.sub.gt~/||Sigma~.sub.gt~ (t=1,2,...,T;g=2,...,N) (A1)
where |Mathematical Expression Omitted~ and ||Sigma~.sub.gt~ is the
standard deviation of the variable. The matrix of simple correlation
coefficients has then the following formula:
R = ZZ'/N (A2)
This normalisation, that expresses the deviations of the original
observations from their arithmetic mean in their standard deviations, is
done to make mutual comparison possible. The equation for a principal
components model is:
|z.sub.gt~ = |a.sub.il~|f.sub.lg~ + |a.sub.i2~|f.sub.2g~ +...+
|a.sub.im~|f.sub.mg~ + |e.sub.gt~ (A3)
where:
* |z.sub.gt~ is the value at time t of the normalised observation
on the gth variable (g=1,2,...N; t=1,2,...T);
* |a.sub.ig~ is the regression coefficient of the ith principal
component for predicting the jth variable (i=1,2,...n; j=1,2,...m);
* |f.sub.ig~ is the value of the jth observation on the gth
principal component;
* m is the number of principal components;
* |e.sub.gt~ is the error term.
The model can be written in matrix form as:
Z = AF + e (A4)
where Z is the matrix of normalised observations, A is the matrix
whose elements |a.sub.ij~ are known as factor loadings or connection
coefficients, F is the matrix of components, and e is the vector of
errors. Substitution of (A4) into (A2) gives the relationship between R,
the correlation matrix of the normalised observations, and A, the matrix
of the connection coefficients:
R = ZZ'/N = AF(AF)'/N = AFF'A'/N = AA' (A5)
where the product FF' is 1 since by construction the components
are uncorrelated with each other and have unit variance. It can be shown
that the vectors |a.sub.j~ are orthogonal because they are proportional
to the characteristic vectors |v.sub.j~ of the matrix R, being of the
following form:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
where the ||Lambda~.sub.j~ are the characteristic roots of R. Thus
the 'aspect' vectors |a.sub.j~ are nothing else than the
scaled characteristic vectors of the symmetric, positive definite matrix
R (the term 'aspect' is used to denote the column vector with
elements |a.sub.ij~ or |Mathematical Expression Omitted~, i=1,2,...n,
containing the pattern of motion produced by the general causal factor |f.sub.j~). Principal components analysis selects m characteristic
vectors |f.sub.j~ out of the n characteristic vectors of the matrix R
which can describe the variables in terms of equation (A4).
DATA APPENDIX
Quarterly GDP data are available only for the four major European
economies (Germany, France, Italy, UK). For the other countries, the
annual data have been interpolated to produce quarterly series. The
seasonally adjusted quarterly path for nominal GDP has been determined
using information from the industrial production and consumer prices
series; real GDP has been made to grow in line with industrial
production. The data sources are the following:
Nominal GDP:
* Germany: Statistische Beihefte zu den Monatsbereichten der
Deutschen Bundesbank, Reihe 4; DM billion.
* France: OECD Quarterly National Accounts; FF billion.
* Italy: Istituto Centrale di Statistica (ISTAT); Lire billion.
* UK: Economic Trends, Quarterly Article on National Income,
|pounds~ million.
* Other EC countries: OECD Economic Outlook diskettes (mnemonic:
GDP).
Real GDP:
* Germany: Statistische Beihefte zu den Monatsbereichten der
Deutschen Bundesbank, Reihe 4, Table 1, Brutto Inlandsprodukt, 1985
prices, DM billion.
* France: OECD Quarterly National Accounts, France section, Table
1B, GDP, 1980 prices, FF billion.
* Italy: Istituto Centrale di Statistica (ISTAT), 1985 prices, Lire
billion.
* UK: Economic Trends, Quarterly Article on National Income, Table
A1, GDP at 1985 market prices (CAOO), |pounds~ million.
* Other EC countries: OECD Economic Outlook diskettes (mnemonic:
GDPV), 1986 prices, million.
Industrial production series:
OECD Main Economic Indicators, total industrial production,
seasonally adjusted data.
Consumer prices series:
OECD Main Economic Indicators, not seasonally adjusted.
REFERENCES
Argy, V. (1989), 'Choice of exchange rate regime for a smaller
economy--A survey of some key issues', in Choosing an Exchange Rate
Regime: The Challenge for Smaller Industrial Countries, ed. by V. Argy
and P. De Grauwe, CEPS/IMF.
Baldwin, R. (1990), 'On the microeconomics of EMU',
European Economy.
Barrell, R. (ed.) (1992), Economic Convergence and Monetary Union in
Europe, Sage Publications, London.
Barro, R. J. and D. Gordon (1983), 'A critical theory of
monetary policy in a natural rate model', Journal of Political
Economy, 91, pp. 589-610.
Bayoumi, T. and B. Eichengreen (1992), 'Shocking aspects of
European monetary unification', NBER Working Paper no. 3949.
Baxter, M. and A. C. Stockman (1988), 'Business cycles and the
exchange rate system: some international evidence', NBER Working
Paper no. 2689.
Blanchard, O. and D. Quah (1989), 'The dynamic effects of
aggregate demand and supply disturbances', American Economic
Review, 79, pp. 655-673.
Britton, A. and D. Mayes (1992), Achieving Monetary Union in Europe,
Sage Publications, London.
Brociner, A. and P. Levine (1992), 'EMU: a survey',
Discussion Paper no. 07-92, Centre for Economic Forecasting, London
Business School.
Cohen, D. and C. Wyplosz (1989), 'The European Monetary Union:
an agnostic evaluation', CEPR Discussion Paper no. 306.
Commission of the European Communities (1990), 'One market, one
money: an evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an
economic and monetary union', European Economy, 44, October.
Currie, D., Holtham G. and A. Hughes Hallett (1989), 'The theory
and practice of international policy coordination: does coordination
pay?', in Macroeconomic Policies in an Interdependent World, ed. by
R. Bryant, D. Currie and R. Portes, CEPR/The Brookings Institution/IMF.
De Grauwe, P. and W. Vanhaverbeke (1991), 'Is Europe an optimum
currency area? Evidence from regional data', CEPR Discussion Paper
no. 555.
Dornbusch, R. (1990), 'Two-track EMU, now!', in K.O. Pohl
et al, Britain and EMU, pp. 103-112, Centre for Economic Performance,
London School of Economics.
Eichengreen, B. (1990a), 'Is Europe an optimum currency
are?', CEPR Discussion Paper no. 478, forthcoming in H. Grubel
(ed.), European Economic Integration: The View From Outside, London.
MacMillan.
Eichengreen, B. (1990b), 'One money for Europe: Lessons from the
US currency and customs union', Economic Policy 10, pp. 118-187.
Eichengreen, B. (1991), 'Labor markets and European monetary
unification', unpublished manuscript, University of California at
Berkeley.
Gorsuch, R.L. (1974), Factor Analysis, Philadelphia, W.B. Saunders
Co.
Harman, H.H. (1976), Modern Factor Analysis, 3rd edition, Chicago,
University of Chicago Press.
Ishiyama, Y. (1975), 'The theory of optimum currency areas: a
survey', IMF Staff Papers 22.
Kenen, P.B. (1969), 'The theory of optimum currency areas: an
eclectic view', in R.A. Mundell and A.K. Swoboda (eds), Monetary
Problems of the International Economy, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press.
Krugman, P. (1989), Exchange-Rate Instability, MIT Press, Cambridge,
Massachussetts.
Masson, P.R. and M.P. Taylor (1992), 'Common currency areas and
currency unions: an analysis of the issues', CEPR Discussion Paper
no. 617.
Mulaik, S.A. (1972), 'The foundations of factor analysis',
New York, McGraw Hill.
Mundell, R. (1961), 'A theory of optimum currency area',
American Economic Review, pp. 657-665.
Poloz, S.S. (1990), 'Real exchange rate adjustment between
regions in a common currency area', unpublished manuscript, Bank of
Canada.
Weber, A.A. (1990), 'Asymmetries and adjustment problems: some
empirical evidence', European Economy.
NOTES
(1) Note that it is argued by some that the theory of OCAs gives
limited insight because does not take into consideration that policy is
not a non-negligible source of disturbance to an economy. A change of
regime may imply a change in the institutional structure of policymaking and the incentive structure of policymakers. In the case of the EMS, it
may be argued, the operational requirements implied by the participation
in its exchange-rate mechanisms have changed the policy of member
governments and, therefore, the shocks that are caused by policy.
(2) Note that this result only holds for the evaluation of real
shocks, and it assumes that changes in the nominal rate do not have
permanent real effects. If some assets held abroad are fixed in nominal
foreign currency then a change in the nominal rate appears to have real
effects. Many shocks are nominal, and removing the nominal exchange rate
removes a nominal shock absorber.
(3) For a more technical explanation of principal components
analysis, see the Appendix. Standard references are Mulaik (1972),
Gorsuch (1974), and Harman (1976).
(4) Under the null hypothesis |H.sub.o~:p=0, p being the population
correlation coefficient, the variable Z=|z|Sigma~.sub.z~, where
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~ is the sample size and r is the sample
correlation coefficient, is distributed approximately N(0,1). The
critical value at the 5 per cent level is 1.96, which, given a sample
size of 79, implies that values of +/-0.22 are required for
significance.
(5) This raises the issue of 'cohesion', and it is mainly a
political judgement whether or not only market forces should be relied
upon to achieve real convergence (see Britton and Mayes, 1992, or
Barrell, ed., 1992). Note also that there is a third kind of
convergence, which can be called structural convergence, i.e. the
convergence of institutions and economic structures (see again Britton
and Mayes, 1992).
I would like to thank Ray Barrell and Nicholas Oulton for helpful
comments and suggestions.