The state of the public finances.
Pain, Nigel ; Young, Garry ; Westaway, Peter 等
Introduction
The public sector borrowing requirement (PSBR) was |pounds~36.7
billion (6 per cent of GDP) in the last fiscal year and was forecast by
the government in the March Budget to rise to |pounds~50 billion (8 per
cent of GDP) in the current fiscal year. Yet as recently as 1988/9, the
public sector was able to make a debt repayment of |pounds~14.7 billion
(3 per cent of GDP). Such a large change has prompted concerns about the
present state of the public finances and indeed caused the government to
set in place future increases in taxation designed to ameliorate the
situation.
The purpose of this note is to assess the sustainability of the
current fiscal position. In doing this we pay particular attention to
the development of the stock of public sector debt in relation to
national income and the public sector's stock of capital. Whereas
the PSBR measures the amount of borrowing the public sector needs to do
within a particular period, the debt stock measures the total amount of
obligations to pay interest that the public sector has outstanding. It
is this concept that is most useful in discussing the sustainability of
fiscal policy. The ultimate constraint on the budgetary decisions of the
public sector is that it is able to pay the interest on its debt.
Interest payments will tend to rise in line with the debt stock and, for
given interest rates, will tend to rise as a proportion of GDP when the
debt stock is rising as a proportion of GDP. Such a situation is not
sustainable: ultimately the public sector would be forced to change its
budgetary policy or repudiate its debt.
It is also important to examine the relationship between the
evolution of the public sector's debt stock and the amount of
capital it owns. Public sector capital assets typically provide services
over a number of years. Some investments, such as council houses,
generate future revenue for the public sector. Other items of capital
expenditure, such as expenditure on roads, do not (as yet) provide a
direct source of future revenue. In either case it can be argued that it
is appropriate for the public sector to finance such capital expenditure
by borrowing and that the revenue required to finance the interest
payments on the resulting debt will become due in line with the services
provided by the capital. For capital that generates revenue, the revenue
itself can be used to cover the interest. For capital that does not
generate revenue, the tax levied to finance interest payments can be
seen as a payment for services provided.
We begin by considering the proximate causes of the sharp change in
the state of the public finances since 1988/89 and attempt to quantify the extent to which those changes are related to the general economic
cycle. Cyclical changes in the fiscal position are less worrying than
other more structural changes since there is a tendency for them to be
reversed as the economy recovers, ensuring that they do not have a long
term adverse effect on the debt stock.
Our estimates suggest that around 2 1/2 percentage points of the 9
percentage point swing in the PSBR/GDP ratio since 1988/9 can be
directly attributed to the economic cycle. Borrowing is presently being
used to finance both current and capital spending, with non-oil tax
revenues some 2 percentage points lower, as a proportion of GDP, than at
the trough of the previous two recessions in the UK. In this light the
recent decisions to restrain public sector pay and announce future tax
increases appear to have some justification.
We also examine the long-run trends in the PSBR over the last two
decades and attempt to isolate the factors that have led to a generally
lower rate of borrowing. If it is reasonable to expect these factors to
continue then the recent increase in the PSBR might be viewed as a
temporary aberration about a gradual downward trend. Finally we consider
the future prospects for the public sector finances using the
Government's own projections for its spending and tax plans
together with our forecast for the development of the economy more
generally. This makes it possible to calculate the likely path for the
ratios of both the debt stock and the capital stock to GDP in the medium
term on the basis of the announced budgetary policy of the government.
Our analysis suggests that the current fiscal policy is sustainable,
in that the forecast suggests that the recent actions announced by the
government will tend to stabilise the PSBR at some 2 1/2 per cent of GDP
by the late-1990s, with the ratio of general government gross debt to
GDP tending to 50 per cent. We also explore the impact on the fiscal
position of a failure by the government to implement its announced
policies. This shows that the actions that the authorities presently
intend to undertake are necessary to prevent the outlook becoming
significantly worse.
A comparison of the changes in the components of the PSBR in the
prospective recovery with those in earlier periods of economic recovery
shows large differences between our forecasts for tax revenues and net
capital spending and previous historical experience. Whilst the need to
reduce the PSBR to GDP ratio is now as pressing as it was in the
mid-1970s, the likely future decline in proceeds from asset sales and in
income from the remaining assets of the public sector reinforces the
need to correct the present deficit through higher tax revenues.
It is also the case that to the extent that the share of current
government expenditure in national income was a problem in the mid-1970s
and the early-1980s, it remains so today. Arguments that suggest that
the present high level of borrowing arises solely from shortfalls in tax
revenue ignore the fact that the secular decline in the share of total
government expenditure in the 1980s arose entirely from the reduction in
capital accumulation within the public sector rather than from any
sustained reduction in current expenditure. If a case is to be made for
correcting the present deficit by means of tax changes alone, it
requires a more detailed analysis of the separate effects of changes in
expenditure and taxation on the wider economy.
Although the present fiscal policy may be a sustainable one, it is
not necessarily an optimum one, though an optimum one must be
sustainable. There are many different sustainable policies; what is
required is a means of choosing between them. In the short term, the
present stance of fiscal policy implies that the ratio of government
debt to capital is likely to rise sharply, to levels last seen
twenty-five years ago, with the government continuing to borrow to
finance current expenditure. Whilst such a development might have been
appropriate prior to the exploitation of assets such as North Sea oil,
it is less so now, given what is known about future trends in the age
structure of the population. A very full discussion of these issues can
be found in Odling-Smee and Riley (1985).
Preliminaries
As a preliminary to the more detailed description of the development
of the public finances to be considered below, it is useful to set down
briefly the accounting framework that we use to guide the discussion and
also the relationship between debt and deficits.
The public sector borrowing requirement is by definition equal to
public sector expenditure less receipts. In discussing the state of the
public finances it is useful to classify government activity in five
separate categories: current expenditure, capital expenditure, general
tax revenue, net income from public sector assets and miscellaneous
financial transactions. Within this classification, we have chosen to
treat certain activities in a slightly different way to that adopted in
the public sector accounts. Current expenditure is equal to total
expenditure less capital expenditure and debt interest payments. Net
capital expenditure is given by gross fixed capital formation less the
proceeds from privatisations, the sales of council houses, land and
other buildings.(1) The net income from public sector assets is given by
the sum of revenues from the North Sea (tax and royalties), the gross
trading surpluses of public corporations and rent receipts, less net
payments of property income (largely debt interest). All of these latter
categories of income are dependent upon the size and scope of the public
sector.
The cash basis on which government accounts are normally presented
fails to distinguish adequately between current and capital
expenditures. Indeed the failure to consolidate gross capital
expenditure with capital divestments through privatisation gives a
misleading impression of the extent to which net capital formation by
the public sector is changing over time.(2)
An alternative classification of the PSBR would be into expenditure
on debt interest and the 'primary deficit': the deficit
excluding debt interest. This indicates how the change in the stock of
public sector debt (which is is equal to the PSBR absent of revaluations
and 'high powered' money creation)is related to the previous
level of the debt stock through the effects of debt interest. A debt
spiral can arise if a high debt stock leads to high interest payments
and an even higher debt stock in the future. The likelihood of this
scenario is greater when the rate of interest is greater than the rate
of growth of the economy. Under these circumstances the debt income
ratio will rise unsustainably as debt interest is rolled up into the
debt stock unless there are primary surpluses of sufficient magnitude.
In the converse situation where the rate of interest is less than the
rate of growth of the economy the debt to income ratio will tend to fall
as income growth reduces the relative size of the debt stock unless
there are primary deficits of sufficient magnitude.
In general the stock of debt will settle down as a proportion of GDP
when the PSBR to GDP ratio settles down. Further simple debt arithmetic
indicates that in the steady state the debt to GDP ratio is given by
(1+g)/g.PSBR/GDP, where g is the nominal growth rate of the economy.
Thus, for example, a constant ratio of the PSBR to GDP of 5 per cent
will lead to a debt to GDP ratio of 55 per cent with nominal growth of
10 per cent per annum and to a debt to GDP ratio of 105 per cent when
growth is only 5 per cent per annum: the slower the nominal growth rate
the longer it takes to reduce the size of outstanding debt in relation
to GDP.
The current budgetary position
In order to assess the current fiscal position it is necessary to
understand how it has been reached. Chart 1 shows the behaviour of the
PSBR to GDP ratio from the beginning of the 1970s to date. The basic
pattern displayed here is that of a cycle about a gradual downward
trend. The cycle in the public finances reflects the economic cycle,
with the peaks in the PSBR being associated with the troughs of economic
activity. This is usually thought to be because of the operation of the
'automatic stabilisers'--higher transfers to the unemployed
and lower taxes on incomes--over the cycle. This suggests that some part
of the current problem is cyclical and therefore likely to correct
itself as the economy recovers from recession.
Table 1 reports the changes in the main components of the PSBR/GDP
ratio over the five years to the troughs of the three most recent
economic cycles. Some 5 percentage points of the 9 percentage point
swing in the PSBR/GDP ratio between 1988/9 and 1992/3 can be accounted
for by a rise in current public spending relative to GDP. A fall in tax
revenue relative to GDP accounts for some 2 1/2 percentage points, with
an increase in net capital spending relative to GDP (partly due to a
decline in asset sales) and a fall in income from public sector assets
relative to GDP both accounting for increases of a little under one
percentage point.
Examination of the components of these changes indicates that only a
relatively small proportion of the recent deterioration in the PSBR can
be attributed to
the economic cycle, particularly once allowance is made for the
decline in asset sales and income from assets. On the spending side, two
and a half percentage points of the change is due to an increase in
current expenditure on goods and services, which partly reflects an
increase in the relative pay of many public sector employees. On the tax
side, income tax payments as a share of GDP actually rose over the
period, reflecting the extent to which 'fiscal drag' raised
tax revenue in the late-1980s, in spite of repeated reductions in tax
rates. National Insurance contributions fell, but this is partly
attributable to the effects of lower rates announced in the 1989 budget
as well as to higher unemployment.
Non-oil company tax payments fell by more than other tax revenues
over this period but not all of this can be attributed to the effects of
the economic cycle. Instead this partly reflects the working through of
the changes to the corporation tax system announced in 1984. These
changes affected the timing at which capital allowances on new
investment could be claimed so that capital is now written off for tax
purposes over a longer period of time than was previously the case. This
had the effect of temporarily reducing the aggregate quantity of capital
allowances claimed in any one year.(3) At the same time the rate of
corporation tax was reduced from 52 per cent to 35 per cent and has
since been reduced further to 33 per cent. This is a genuine remission and the combined effect of this and the changes to capital allowances is
ultimately to reduce the yield from corporation tax.
The main cyclical elements in the change in the PSBR over the period
from 1988/9 are some of the change in current grants (which includes
unemployment related benefits) and some of the fall in taxation. It is
unlikely that this amounts to much more than a quarter of the
deterioration in the PSBR, although such an estimate is very
uncertain.(4) Even in the case of current grants, the trend in the real
level of expenditure was changed by the decision in 1991 to resume the
uprating of child benefit payments. Such a factor should be seen as
structural rather than cyclical.
It is interesting to compare the changes since 1988 with those that
occurred in earlier periods. One point that emerges from such an
exercise is that there is comparatively little that is common in the
different periods considered, reinforcing the worries about the accuracy
of any attempt to adjust the PSBR for the effects of the cycle. Table 1
shows a similar increase in the PSBR/GDP ratio in the five years to
1975/6 but a fall in the PSBR/GDP ratio in the five years to 1982/3,
even though the recession in the early-1980s was as severe as the most
recent one. The main difference in the components of the public accounts
appears to be on the tax side, with total tax revenues rising as a
proportion of GDP in both previous episodes. This suggests that on both
occasions the authorities had taken early action to prevent the deficit
becoming too large.
One factor that is likely to have stopped this from occurring this
time is the election in April 1992. Some TABULAR DATA OMITTED evidence
for this is borne out by the simple regression equation shown in Box A.
This relates the PSBR, adjusted to remove the effects of oil revenues
and asset sales, to a measure of the business cycle, the indebtedness of
the public sector, inflation and a variable that takes account of the
electoral cycle. The equation suggests that the adjusted PSBR tends to
be about one and a half percentage points higher than otherwise in
election years and the years after elections. It also provides some
quantification of the typical effect of the economic cycle on the PSBR.
This indicates that about two and a half percentage points of the change
in the PSBR/GDP ratio from 1988/9 to 1992/3 is accounted for by the
cycle, an estimate broadly consistent with that obtained from the
earlier consideration of the changes in the individual components of the
PSBR.
Overall, the analysis of recent events confirms that temporary
(albeit protracted) events such as recessions and elections can have a
significant influence on the public finances. However the quantitative
importance of these events in explaining the deterioration in the public
finances from 1988/9 to 1992/3 is relatively small (since 1987/8 was
also an election year). There appears to be a much larger deterioration
that must be attributed to other causes. It is therefore of some
importance to investigate what has caused the reversal in the apparent
trend decline in the PSBR to GDP ratio shown in Chart 1. Table 2 lists
the broad components of the PSBR for each fiscal year from 1970/1 to
date and also shows how we foresee these developing in the forecast
period. The developments over the forecast are discussed in more detail
below.
The evolution of the PSBR and its causes
The most important components of the PSBR to GDP ratio shown in Table
2 are the balance between current public sector spending and tax
revenue, net capital spending and net income from assets. These separate
series are plotted in Chart 2. This suggests that much of the
explanation for the trend decline in the PSBR is attributable to a
similar decline in net capital spending. Gross capital spending by the
public sector has fallen steadily as a share of GDP since the
early-1970s, from a peak level of 9 1/4 per cent in 1975/6 to 3 1/3 per
cent in 1992/3, with public corporations gross investment falling by 3/4
per cent of GDP to 3 3/4 per cent, and general government investment
declining to 2.6 per cent of GDP from 4 3/4 per cent in 1975/6 (although
it has been relatively constant since 1982/3). The effects of this
downward trend have been accentuated by the sales of public TABULAR DATA
OMITTED sector assets, beginning with council house sales in the
mid-1970s and continuing with the privatisation programme that began in
earnest in 1984. At their peak in 1988/9, the resulting revenue was
equivalent to 2 3/4 per cent of GDP. By 1992/3 this had declined to 1
3/4 per cent.
Chart 3 compares the PSBR to GDP ratio with the net capital spending
to GDP ratio. This reveals both the strong correlation between the two
series and that the PSBR has been less than the borrowing required to
finance net capital spending in every year considered until 1991/2. This
indicates that the public sector has generally respected the idea that
borrowing not be used to finance current spending, the so-called
'golden rule'.
In fact, current spending exceeded tax revenue (on our definitions)
from 1975 to 1985. To a large extent any deficit of current spending
over tax revenue was offset in the past by the contribution of net
income from assets, ensuring that total borrowing remained below the
borrowing required to finance net investment. At present the degree to
which current expenditure exceeds tax revenues is larger as a proportion
of GDP than at any time over the period considered. The main components
of public sector expenditure and tax revenue are shown in Tables 3 and 4
respectively.
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
Net income from assets has been declining since its peak in 1982 and
is put at close to zero in 1992/3. Around half of this is due to the
decline in oil revenues. The remainder of the decline either reflects
the sale of many public assets for less than their true market value or
the use of the proceeds from the reduction in net capital expenditure to
finance net current expenditure rather than to repay debt. In principle,
the proceeds raised from the sale of such assets should be sufficient so
as to reduce net debt by such a degree as to offset exactly the
resulting loss of revenue with lower debt interest payments.(5)
The effects on the public sector balance sheet
The above analysis of the components of the PSBR suggests that the
decline in the PSBR to GDP ratio over the period under consideration has
been associated with a similar decline in net capital spending by the
public sector relative to GDP. Indeed, it could be argued that the fall
in the borrowing requirement was warranted by the decline in the public
sector capital stock relative to GDP. It is of some importance to assess
what effects these changes have had on the balance sheet of the public
sector.
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
This presents some well known difficulties in first agreeing what
ought to be included in the balance sheet and then determining how it
should be measured. These two issues are very closely connected since
problems of measurement often dictate what is included in the balance
sheet. For example the depletion of oil reserves has provided revenue
for the public sector and there ought perhaps to be a corresponding
change in the value of oil reserves in the balance sheet of the public
sector. Similarly, those who have contributed to the National Insurance
Scheme can expect to receive benefits when they are sick, unemployed and
when they retire. It is in principle possible to calculate the present
value of the future obligations of the public sector, with the resulting
liability added to the balance sheet.
The public sector balance sheet produced by the Central Statistical
Office includes neither of these items. Instead it includes financial
assets and liabilities and tangible assets. Even the measurement of
tangible assets is not straightforward. In particular the CSO has not
produced estimates of the tangible assets in the balance sheet since
1987 (although it is expected to produce up to date estimates in this
year's Blue Book) and therefore does not include a period when the
capital stock of the public sector is likely to have been significantly
depleted as a consequence of the decline in net capital spending. In
order to provide up to date estimates of the net worth of the public
sector we use estimates of its net capital stock. This is measured on a
replacement cost basis rather than at market values and is typically
higher than market valuations. It may therefore overestimate the true
value of the public sector's tangible assets. It has the merit of
providing a consistent estimate of the trends in net capital assets, the
most important factor for current purposes where interest is focussed on
how the balance sheet is changing over time.(6)
Table 5 shows the key items in the balance sheet as they have
developed over the period from 1957. The stock of tangible assets owned
by the public sector has fallen as a proportion of GDP since the
mid-1970s. This is fully consistent with the decline in net capital
spending by the public sector described above. The table also reports
alternative measures of indebtedness. The ratio of general government
debt to GDP is the debt stock criterion TABULAR DATA OMITTED proposed in
the Maastricht treaty as a means to assess whether a country is ready to
join a monetary union. Net public sector financial liabilities (also
known as net financial debt) is the widest definition of public sector
debt.
The table shows a trend decline in debt in relation to both GDP and
public sector tangible assets. Both of these are measures of the
sustainability of fiscal policy. The first--the solvency ratio--is the
most widely used measure, but the second--the gearing ratio--is also
important because it shows how the public sector's debt is changing
in relation to the capital stock which it may be seen as financing. The
fact that the solvency and gearing ratios have both fallen over the
period since 1957 suggests that more of the financing of the capital
stock has come from current rather than future taxes. This is probably
appropriate given that the inherited debt stock in 1957 had largely
arisen as a consequence of borrowing during wartime.
The ratio of the stock of net financial debt to the stock of public
owned capital is now around 45 per cent and has remained close to this
ratio since the early-1970s. The fact that this is less than than 100
per cent suggests that future taxpayers are expected to contribute less
to the cost of existing capital than it is worth. However, in the
absence of a fully adumbrated balance sheet for the public sector, it
would be unwise to attach too much significance to the measured level of
the gearing ratio, although changes in the ratio over time will still
provide an indication of the sustainability of fiscal policy.
One implication of the debt to capital ratio being less than 100 per
cent is that its level can remain unchanged when capital assets are sold
even if the resulting repayment of debt is less than the reduction in
the value of the capital stock. Thus a privatisation can still reduce
the gearing ratio even if the sale of capital is not at the full market
value. It should be noted that this differs from the simultaneous
effects on the flows of net income from assets; if these are to be
unaffected, debt needs to be reduced so that the resulting fall in
interest payments offsets the loss of capital income.
The discussion of the longer-term trends in the components of the
PSBR and the arithmetic of debt accumulation points to some rather
unpalatable conclusions. First, the reduction in the ratio of the PSBR
to GDP observed since the 1970s has come about largely as a reduction in
net capital spending. This is partly due to the effects of sales of
assets but also reflects a decline in gross capital spending by the
public sector. There is a limit to how far this process can continue:
ultimately the stock of marketable public sector assets will run out.
Indeed the recent decline in investment might have to be reversed in the
future if replacement investment has been neglected. Second, and a
direct consequence of the first point, the net income from assets
(including oil) has declined steadily since the mid-1980s. At present
this makes a zero contribution to the PSBR but, in the absence of any
adjustments to the stance of fiscal policy prevailing in 1992/3, might
be expected to make a negative contribution in the near future if
interest payments on an enlarged debt stock outstrip income from other
assets. Third, unlike in the 1970s, the rate of growth of nominal income is likely to be quite subdued in the 1990s so that the debt stock will
not be diminished in relation to GDP by growth in the latter.
Changes in prospect
These arguments suggest that it will now be more difficult than in
the past to reduce the PSBR to GDP ratio as temporary influences on the
public finances disappear. If the PSBR is to be reduced then it will
have to come about as a result of greater control over current spending
and tax revenue.
Our latest forecast for the development of the UK economy in the
short and medium term is described elsewhere in the Review. The forecast
shows a modest recovery over the next two years, with growth around 3
per cent in 1994 and 2 1/2 per cent in 1995. Inflation rises somewhat
from its present level, with consumer prices rising by 4-5 per cent in
each of the next two years. Unemployment is projected to average 2.8
million next year and 2 3/4 million in 1995. These developments of
themselves affect the fiscal position of the public sector. In addition,
the forecast builds in the various tax and spending plans announced by
the government in the March Budget this year and assumes that additional
net tax rises worth some |pounds~2 1/2 billion will be announced in the
November Budget.
The outlook for the various components of the PSBR contingent on the
implementation of these plans and other aspects of the forecast is
reported in Tables 2, 3 and 4. We expect the PSBR to GDP ratio to reach
a peak of 7 per cent in the current fiscal year before declining to a
level of about 2 1/2 per cent by the end of the decade. In broad terms
this turnaround comes about as a consequence of a fall in the ratio of
current spending to GDP of 2 1/2 percentage points, a rise in tax
revenue of a similar amount and an offsetting rise in net capital
spending relative to GDP of close to 2 percentage points. This latter
change largely reflects the projected decline in proceeds from
privatisation. The PSBR is projected to exceed net capital spending
and thereby break the 'golden rule' until 1996/7.
The change in current expenditure is largely accounted for by
changes, in expenditure on goods and services and current grants. These
settle down at levels below those of the current year, but above those
prevailing in the late-1980s. On the tax side, the rise in revenues is
due to similar increases, relative to GDP, in income taxes, non-oil
company taxes and indirect taxes. None of the resulting tax shares
appears implausible when judged against previous historical experience.
The overall impact of these developments on the balance sheet of the
public sector is set out in Table 5. The net debt to GDP ratio is
expected to rise throughout the period, due to a combination of a run of
relatively high deficits and relatively slow growth in nominal income.
The debt arithmetic suggests that a constant PSBR to GDP ratio of 2 1/2
per cent will, with a 6 per cent growth rate in nominal income, lead to
a ratio of net financial debt to GDP of 44 per cent. This is similar to
the level reached by the debt to GDP ratio at the end of the decade in
the forecast. The general government gross debt stock rises to 48.6 per
cent of GDP by this time, well within the guidelines set out in the
Maastricht Treaty. Thus, in answer to the question that this note is
attempting to address, it does appear that the future path of fiscal
policy as set out in the present plans of the government is sustainable.
However, it is important to consider the development of the public
sector capital stock over this period. Table 6 indicates that this is
expected to increase in line with the anticipated increase in net
capital spending by the public sector. However it does not increase by
as much as the predicted rise in the ratio of net financial debt to GDP,
suggesting that the public sector gearing ratio will rise. This is in
line with the projected contravention of the 'golden rule'.
This is illustrated in Chart 4 which shows the gearing ratio from the
early-1970s to the end of the forecast period.
This sharp rise in the ratio of public sector debt to capital over
the forecast period suggests one of two things; either the public sector
is prepared to allow more of its capital to be financed by debt than in
the recent past or fiscal policy can be expected to be adjusted further
to maintain the past relationship between public sector debt and
capital. Both possibilities present difficulties for the government. The
policy changes that are already built into the forecast suggest that
fiscal policy is set to be quite tough throughout the forecast period
and a further tightening may not be welcomed. But, at the same time
there is less justification than in earlier periods for allowing the
gearing ratio to rise. The unrecorded parts of the public sector's
balance sheet that are nevertheless known about, such as the value of
oil reserves and the pension liabilities to the currently working
population, are probably changing in such a way as to justify a
reduction in the gearing ratio. In this sense, there may be a case for
further fiscal tightening.
An alternative option under discussion at present is the possibility
of greater private sector participation in the financing of public
sector capital. Examples include the leasing of capital assets from the
private sector and joint ventures where the public and private sector
share the cost and the risks from a project. However it is by no means
clear that these types of schemes amount to more than creative
accounting. Initially the PSBR will be lower because of the smaller
contribution made by the public sector to the costs of particular
projects. However in later years, the PSBR will be higher than otherwise
because of increased payments to lessors or because the return from the
project is shared with the private sector. In stock terms, the amount of
public sector debt and public sector capital will both be lower as a
consequence of these types of schemes. This does not present a solution
to the problem of how to to reduce debt relative to capital.(7)
Table 6 compares the changes in the components of the PSBR/GDP ratio
in the recovery from 1993/4 with those in the recoveries from the
troughs of the recessions in TABULAR DATA OMITTED 1975/6 and 1982/3. In
each case we consider the change over the ensuing four year period. The
anticipated change in the PSBR to GDP ratio in the recovery from 1993/4
to 1996/7 is of a similar size to that achieved over the four years from
1975/6 to 1978/9 and greater than that achieved in the period from
1982/3. In part this reflects the unusual decline in the PSBR/GDP ratio
during the recession of the early-1980s. The change in public sector
current spending relative to GDP of 1 1/2 percentage points is fully in
line with that achieved before. However there is a large difference in
the anticipated change in tax revenue from the changes observed in
earlier periods, with tax revenues, particularly from income tax,
expected to rise as a share of GDP this time.
Other items affecting the PSBR also appear less propitious than
previously. In particular net capital spending is expected to rise as a
proportion of GDP this time as a consequence of lower asset sales. Net
income from assets is however expected to make a positive contribution
to public sector revenue as a consequence of increased oil revenue
following the changes to the structure of oil taxation announced in the
Budget.
It is of some interest to consider the extent to which the actions
announced in the 1992 Autumn Statement and the March Budget, along with
the further action we assume forthcoming in the November Budget, have
improved the prospective fiscal position of the public sector. The
decisions to restrain public sector pay and announce future tax
increases both appear justified given the need to restrain the current
expenditure of the public sector and raise tax revenues. There are a
number of other factors which can be expected to influence the fiscal
position in the medium term. Chief among these is our (implicit)
assumption that benefit payments and personal tax allowances will
continue to be uprated in line with prices rather than earnings,
although this may not be a realistic long-term policy since it implies a
continual erosion in the real living standards of benefit recipients.
To obtain an estimate of the importance of these assumptions, the
present forecast was re-run with each being relaxed in turn. The effect
of each change on the fiscal position of the public sector will not be
the same as the ex-ante size of the change since alterations in tax
rates can be expected to induce substantial second-round effects on the
economy, as the comparative model properties paper elsewhere in this
Review illustrates. The results are shown in Charts 5, 6 and 7, which
show the PSBR/GDP, debt/GDP and debt capital ratios in three cases, the
main forecast, the forecast without the announced tax increases and the
forecast without the tax rises and with uprating in line with earnings
rather than prices. Additional summary information is provided in Table
7.
On the basis of the trends in public debt and the present expenditure
plans of the government, it is possible to suggest that fiscal solvency
could be achieved in the medium term without the tax rises announced for
next year. However the PSBR/GDP ratio stabilises at around 3 3/4
percentage points, some 1 1/4 percentage points above the projection in
the main forecast. The ratio of gross general government debt to GDP by
1999 is correspondingly higher at 53 1/4 per cent, around 5 percentage
points above that in the central forecast. Table 7 indicates that the
gearing ratio also begins to stabilise in this variant, although the
level in 1999 is some 8 percentage points above that achieved with the
tax rises in place.
Table 7. Public sector finances in the medium term
all figures per cent
Case A. The main forecast
Case B. The main forecast without future tax rises
Case C. Case B plus uprating with wages rather than prices
1992/3 1995/6 1997/8 1999/2000
PSBR/GDP ratio
Case A. 6.0 3.9 2.8 2.5
Case B. 6.0 5.4 4.1 3.8
Case C. 6.0 5.9 5.2 5.0
Debt/GDP ratio
Case A. 40.4 47.7 47.8 48.6
Case B. 40.4 50.3 51.7 53.3
Case C. 40.4 51.5 53.8 56.9
Debt/Capital Stock Ratio
Case A. 43.0 59.0 57.0 55.0
Case B. 43.0 62.0 63.0 63.0
Case C. 43.0 64.0 67.0 70.0
The second variant illustrates that the fiscal gains from uprating
allowances by prices are equally important in maintaining the
prospective future solvency of the public sector. Whilst the PSBR/GDP
ratio again stabilises by 1999, albeit at the higher level of 5
percentage points, it would be much harder to claim that the public
sector was solvent, with little sign of any end to the trend in the
gearing ratio. Moreover, the public sector would be in a position from
which it could be extremely difficult to adjust policy in the face of an
unexpected shock. A constant PSBR/GDP ratio of 5 per cent will
eventually generate a steady state debt/GDP ratio of 88 per cent (given
nominal growth of 6 per cent), implying the existence of a sizable primary surplus to ensure that solvency is maintained.
Conclusions
The current fiscal position appears serious when judged by the
current PSBR to GDP ratio of 7 per cent. Indeed, the position would be
unsustainable if recent trends in spending and taxation were maintained,
because then the accumulation of debt and the corresponding interest
liabilities would lead to an eventual debt explosion. Even if the
present level of the PSBR/GDP ratio could be kept constant (by a primary
surplus to offset debt interest) and the long-term growth of nominal
income settled down at the rate of 6 per cent as in our forecast then
the debt to GDP ratio would approach 125 per cent of GDP. However this
is not the outcome we expect. Instead we envisage that the policies that
the Government has set in hand will lead to a much lower level of the
PSBR to GDP ratio of about 2 1/2 per cent of GDP which will lead to a
stabilisation of the ratio of net financial debt to GDP at about 45 per
cent. The corresponding figure for the general government gross debt to
GDP ratio (the criterion used in the Maastricht treaty) is about 50 per
cent.
Even so, the amount of public sector debt is expected to increase in
relation to the stock of publicly owned capital. Whilst the debt to GDP
ratio is likely to return to a similar level to that pertaining in the
late-1970s and early-1980s, the public sector capital stock is likely to
be at a much lower level. Since the public sector debt to capital ratio
has been fairly constant since the beginning of the 1970s it is not
clear what justifies such an increase.
Although an increase might have been appropriate prior to the
exploitation of assets such as North Sea oil, it is less so now, given
what is known about future trends in the age structure of the
population. Ultimately it is not possible to state an optimum level for
the net worth of the public sector; in contrast to private companies the
government can allow debt to exceed its assets by simply raising the
burden faced by future taxpayers. Nonetheless, reforming the present
basis of the public sector accounts so as to include a complete balance
sheet of known assets and liabilities would provide a better basis on
which to judge the present stance of fiscal policy.
The future improvement in the public finances that we expect is shown
to come about in a fairly smooth manner without dramatic cuts in
spending or substantial increases in taxation. Current spending and tax
revenue are expected to return to quite normal levels in relation to
GDP, with net capital spending by the public sector rising a little from
its current level. However this pattern is not the familiar one that
follows the recovery from recessions. In particular, it has been the
case in the last two recoveries that income tax receipts have fallen in
the recovery rather than increasing as we expect them to do now. Thus
the Government will need to restore control over the public finances by
raising taxes at a time when previous governments have been able to be
slightly more relaxed.
REFERENCES
Davies, S. (1990), 'Fiscal developments and the role of the
cycle', Treasury Bulletin, Winter, 1990-91.
Odling-Smee, J. and Riley, C. (1985), 'Approaches to the
PSBR', National Institute Economic Review, No. 113, August.
NOTES
(1) Some privatisations such as council house sales are recorded as
negative fixed capital formation in the public accounts. The proceeds
raised from the sale of former public corporations are shown separately
as 'cash expenditure on company securities'.
(2) There are a number of other possible definitions of net capital
expenditure. The public expenditure supplement to the Autumn Statement
provides figures for 'public sector asset creation'. This is
equivalent to our net capital expenditure plus capital grants and
defence investment spending (which we include in current expenditure),
less the proceeds from privatisations. In 1992/3 public sector asset
creation is estimated at 5 per cent of GDP. In principle, investment
expenditures could be wider still, including other current expenditures
such as education expenditure, see Odling-Smee and Riley (1985).
(3) See Table 11.8 of Inland Revenue Statistics, 1993.
(4) Similar conclusions would emerge if 1990/1, a year in which the
public accounts were in balance, is taken as the basis for comparison
with 1992/3.
(5) It is possible to envisage situations where privatisation could
result in higher net income from public sector assets if the privatised
assets are ones from which the government did not obtain any revenue.
(6) With the rapid rate of inflation of most tangible asset prices in
the latter half of the 1980s, revaluations are likely to have exceeded
the losses due to sales and privatisations. In the 1990s, however, asset
prices have declined, accentuating the losses from asset sales. These
changes may affect the extent to which assets valued on a replacement
cost basis are good approximations to those assets valued at market
prices. There is, however, no particular reason to expect this
fluctuation in prices to be repeated during the rest of the decade.
(7) A more extensive discussion of these issues is contained in the
Institute for Fiscal Studies Green Budget, 1993.
Box A. The PSBR and the Economic and Electoral Cycles
In order to guide our assessment of the effects of the economic cycle
on the public finances, we estimated a regression equation which
explains the behaviour of an adjusted PSBR to GDP ratio in terms of a
measure of the cycle and some other key variables. A related approach is
adopted in Davies (1990).
It is important to recognise that the overall effects of the cycle on
the PSBR depend to a large extent on whether the authorities are
prepared to allow the automatic stabilisers to operate fully or whether
they take discretionary action to offset their effect. The equation
presented here indicates the typical response of the PSBR to GDP ratio
over the cycle and hence includes the effects of discretionary changes
in taxation. The equation also allows for the effects of elections which
might be expected to increase public borrowing and net financial
liabilities of the public sector which will tend to have a negative
effect on borrowing. Finally, we also include a term in inflation which
might be expected to raise borrowing as it acts to reduce the real value
of the outstanding debt stock. The equation is:
|Mathematical Expression Omitted~
(White heteroscedasticity corrected t statistics in parentheses)
Sample: 1971/72-1992/93. |R.sup.2~ = 0.75 DW = 1.52 LM(1) = 1.07
RESET(1) = 0.003 NORM(2) = 4.58 HET (1)= 0.11
The variables are defined as follows: APSBR is the PSBR excluding the
revenue from oil and asset sales, CYCLE is capacity utilisation in
manufacturing, DEBT is the net financial liabilities of the public
sector, INFLATION is the rate of growth in the consumers'
expenditure deflator and ELECTION is an average of DUM and DUM(-1) where
DUM is equal to unity when an election occurs within the financial year
and zero otherwise. (Hence DUM is equal to unity in 1973, 1974, 1979,
1983, 1987 and 1992.) The choice of dependent variable was guided by the
empirical evidence, but to the extent that the estimated equation
accurately reflects the authorities' preferences, it suggests that
oil revenues and asset sales have been used to reduce the PSBR rather
than to finance tax cuts or expenditure increases. The contribution of
these various influences to the annual change in the adjusted PSBR is
shown below for the period from 1980/81:
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
This shows that the largest influences on the adjusted PSBR to GDP
ratio are the electoral and business cycles. The effect of the debt
stock on the PSBR although significant, is not quantitatively important
and inflation only has a large effect when it is itself high.
The fit of the equation over the past few years is not particularly
good with a string of four positive residuals: most (4.9 percentage
points) of the 7.8 percentage point change in the adjusted PSBR to GDP
ratio since 1988/89 is unexplained by the equation. This bears out the
discussion in the text that the deterioration in the public finances
over this period is not easily explained in terms of the economic cycle.
It is interesting to note that the largest error over this period is
in explaining the change in the adjusted PSBR to GDP ratio between
1988/9 and 1989/90. On the basis of past experience, the state of the
economic cycle and the absence of an election, it would have been
reasonable to have expected a reduction in the adjusted PSBR to GDP
ratio of 2 1/2 percentage points rather than the 0.6 percentage point
increase that actually occurred. It is not immediately obvious to what
this error can be attributed except perhaps that it would have been
natural to anticipate a tightening of fiscal policy at this stage of the
electoral cycle which did not occur and has not been made up since.
It is relatively easy to explain the subsequent deterioration in the
public finances since 1990/91 in terms of the economic and electoral
cycles. The difficulty is in explaining why the deterioration began from
a higher level of the PSBR to GDP ratio than past experience would have
indicated.