The world economy.
Barrell, R. Anderton ; Caporale, G.
The US, the UK and Canada all experienced recessions in 1991,
whilst in Germany and Japan activity began to slow markedly. Most
commentators, including the Institute, underestimated the length and
severity of the recessions being experienced by the UK and the US. Data
for the third and fourth quarters, along with recent information on
expectations and on consumer confidence, have caused us to revise down
both our estimate of growth experienced in 1991 and our forecast for
growth in 1992. The summary details of our forecast are given in table
1.
We are projecting that growth in the major four will average under
2 per cent in 1992, well below the average of around 3 per cent between
1982 and 1989. This rate of growth represents some recovery from 1991
but is well below capacity. Chart 1 plots past data and our forecast of
the quarterly path for the rate of change in output in the major
economies between 1988 and the end of 1993. The continued recession in
the US is likely to make the path of growth more sychronised over the
year ahead than it has been over the last two years.
We anticipate that capacity utilisation will continue to fall over
the next year, after peaking in recent years in all of the major
economies. Chart 2 plots survey based capacity utilisation indices for
the major four. The capacity ceiling was reached first in the US in late
1988, but utilisation has fallen sharply recently. The US monetary
authorities have responded very sharply to the fall in output, and the
discount rate was cut to 3/2 per cent in December 1991, its lowest rate
for some decades. Despite these strong moves we expect only a slow
recovery from the depths of the recession.
The sharp reduction in interest rates ill the US should help
recovery, but prospects for the world economy as a whole are somewhat
weakened by the Bundesbank decision to increase interest rates at the
end of 1991. The German authorities are seriously concerned about the
emergence of inflationary pressures as a consequence of the increase in
demand associated with the process of unification. Wage settlements have
risen to around 6 1/2 percent, and consumer price inflation in 1991 has
been almost 4 per cent. This does not seem high by international
standards, especially as indirect tax increases have added to inflation.
Chart 3 plots recent and prospective inflation in the major four
economies.
The increase in German interest rates has been slowing growth and
recovery in the rest of Europe. This is reflected in the low forecast
growth rate for the major seven economies in table 1. We argued in the
February 1991 Review that the expansion of demand as a consequence of
unification in Germany could lead to a slowdown of activity in the rest
of Europe. Box 1 sets out a simple analysis of the problem. If the
European economies are committed to the Exchange Rate Mechanism then
when German interest rates rise other countries have to react. Interest
rates have risen in France, italy, the Netherlands and Belgium, and
anticipated cuts have not materialised in the UK. The ERM is a coalition
with a leader, and the German authorities are still reacting to German
problems. In a monetary union the reaction to a German fiscal expansion
of this scale might not be so severe.
German inflation has been pushed up both by tax increases and a
high level of demand and we expect it to remain around 3Y2 per cent in
1992 before declining somewhat in the mid 1990s. Inflation elsewhere in
the ERM system is likely to moderate somewhat, although the recent and
anticipated (small) depreciation of the ECU may raise it by half a point
in 1992. In the longer term we forecast that French inflation will
remain slightly below that in Germany. Monetary Union in Europe is
likely to be in place by the end of the decade, and policy will be run
on the basis of Community wide targets. The Bundesbank will have lost
its control of the German inflation rate, and we expect that the new
European Central Bank will put a slightly greater weight on output. As a
result German inflation may settle at around 3 1/2 per cent a year,
which is around the average of the last 20 years.
World trade growth in 1991 and 1992 reflects the slowdown in
activity. Total world trade in all goods (but excluding trade between
the former centrally planned economies) grew by around 5/2per cent a
year between 1982 and 1989. It slowed a little in 1990, and we estimate
that it only grew by about 1 per cent in 1991. This partly reflects the
disruption caused by the war in the Gulf in the early part of the year,
but it is mainly the consequence of the decline in OECD industrial
production. Output growth in the major seven was probably less than 1
per cent in 1991, and although we are expecting it to rise somewhat in
1992 all of the major economies will be operating below capacity for
several years. We expect world trade growth to recover gradually in 1992
and 1993. There will be little support from imports into the formerly
centrally planned economies, at least in the near future.
Interest rates, exchange rates and commodity prices Interest rates
have risen in France and Germany in recent months whilst they have
fallen in the US and Japan. Chart 4 plots recent 3-month interest rates
on a weekly basis over the last year. The interest rate differential
between the US and the ERM countries is now very considerable,
reflecting the very different worries of the officials in the Federal
Reserve and the Bundesbank. The US authorities are concerned about a
continued recession, whilst the Bundesbank fears an acceleration in
inflation. German fears have led to interest rate increases throughout
Europe, despite the very poor prospects for output growth. These
different fears have influenced recent exchange rate developments.
Recent data and our forecast for exchange rates are set out in table 2.
The interest differential discussed above is also reflected in long
rates, and German long rates have risen sharply in the last two years,
whilst those in the US, and more recently japan, have been falling.
Chart 5 plots recent long rate developments. The sharp rise in German
long rates in 1990 was associated with the 8 per cent appreciation of
the D-Mark (and of the other ERM currencies) in that year. Chart 6 plots
recent exchange rate developments. The sharp appreciation of the D-Mark
has now been reversed a little, but we would judge that the US is now
undervalued in real terms. This belief is strengthened by the
implications of the rebased national accounts data in the US. This new
data, which is discussed in box 2 below, has led us to revise down our
estimate of US trade demand elasticities, and hence as shown in Barrell
and in't Veld (1991) our estimate of the US FEER will have been
revised.
Our medium term forecast for exchange rates in table 2 is based on
the open arbitrage relationship. It is therefore dependent on our
interest rate forecast which is set out in table 3. Short rates are
eventually expected to converge in Europe, but they will remain higher
than in the US or Japan. In the longer term we believe that nominal
rates will be determined by the real return to capital and the inflation
objectives of the authorities. The real interest rate appears to have
risen, at least in Europe, as a consequence of developments in the east.
Inflation in Europe is forecast to settle down to around 3 1/2 per cent
a year by the end of the decade, and we are forecasting real interest
rates of around 3 1/4 per cent by then. The US and Japan are likely to
have lower real interest rates of around 2 1/2to 2 1/4 per cent in the
longer run, and we are therefore expecting their currencies to
appreciate in real terms.
The slow growth of demand in the industrialised countries has led
to rather weak commodity prices. Chart 7 plots recent commodity price
developments. Minerals and metals prices have been weak, with aluminium
and especially copper prices falling sharply in the last few months.
Less developed country food prices have also been weak, with falling
sugar prices more than offsetting the recent strength in the cocoa
market. Sharp declines in cotton prices have also influenced our
non-food index. The developed country food index has been supported by
very high wheat prices. These reflect anticipated falls in US output and
strong demand for exports to the former Soviet Union. Forward markets
are exhibiting larger than usual falls in wheat prices after the next
harvest, and these are built into our forecast. Past data and our
forecast for commodity prices is given in table 4. We expect real
commodity prices to remain generally weak, following the pattern of the
last decade plotted in chart 8.
Oil prices were weaker in the fourth quarter than forward markets
anticipated. This in part reflects the fact that oil exports from the
former Soviet Union have been maintained at relatively high levels. We
anticipate that oil prices will stay around $19 per barrel in 1992.
Demand is expected to be low, and although the Iraqis have not yet
resumed their exports they will eventually do so, and this will put
downward pressure on prices. In an attempt to prevent prices from
falling OPEC has recently agreed to cuts in production of just over 1
million barrels a day.
United States
The uncertainty dominating the world economy is particularly
apparent in the U.S. After showing signs of recovery in the middle of
last year, poor fourth quarter GDP growth renewed fears of a
'double-dip' recession. After having already reduced the
discount rate by 72 a per cent in November, the Federal Reserve
implemented a further 1 per cent cut to 31/2 per cent in December. This
prompt action was a direct response to the reversal of recovery signaled
by the fourth quarter figures. Real GDP only rose by 0.3 per cent (at an
annual rate) in the final quarter of 1991 compared to 1-4 per cent and
1.8 per cent in the second and third quarters respectively. The main
forces depressing growth were weak consumers' expenditure and
slower investment growth. Although real consumption began growing in the
second and third quarters, reversing the declines of late 1990 and early
1991, the trend of falling consumption resumed in the fourth quarter
despite a rise in personal disposable income. This probably accounts for
some of the rise in stockbuilding in the fourth quarter which is in
direct contrast to the destocking experienced in the first half of last
year. After rising by almost 20 per cent (at an annual rate) in the
third quarter, total investment growth slowed down to around 272 per
cent in the final quarter of 1991. Even so, this was largely accounted
for by house building whereas investment in producers' durable
equipment remained flat. Steady export growth provided some stimulus to
the economy but the fourth quarter fall in imports is consistent with a
further weakening of the economy.
Capacity utilisation in most sectors declined slightly in the
fourth quarter as industrial output fell by 0.2 per cent compared to a
1-7 per cent rise in the previous quarter. The degree of uncertainty
over future output growth is highlighted by the recent simultaneous
increase in the unemployment rate combined with an increase in the
number of overtime hours worked. It may be the case that firms are
increasing output by increasing working hours rather than employing more
workers because they are uncertain about the sustainability of the
current recovery.
Obviously the Federal Reserve was aware of the poor outturn during
the last quarter of 1991 and responded by reducing the discount rate by
1 per cent. The two most subdued categories of expenditure, business
investment and consumers' expenditure, should benefit as a
consequence. Economic activity could recover strongly. However,
confidence remains the key to recovery and this is difficult to gauge.
Obviously confidence is dependent upon expectations of the future. Given
that 1992 is a presidential election year, there remains some
uncertainty regarding both future economic strategy and the permanence of recent policy responses. As personal debt rose in response to
financial liberalisation consumers must now be acutely aware that the
costs of borrowing are both volatile and unpredictable. This should act
as a restraint upon further borrowing especially as long- term interest
rates suggest that the discount rate will begin rising again in the
future. The persistent and growing US public sector deficit, the need to
increase US savings in the medium term and the historically low current
level of the discount rate all suggest that the recent fall in real
interest rates will not be permanent. Furthermore, it should be
emphasised that recent spending was probably undertaken when
expectations about the future were more optimistic. Therefore, it is
highly possible that consumers now perceive debt/income ratios as too
high and the timing and magnitude of their response to cheaper credit is
uncertain.
Our forecast for US GNP and its components is set out in Table 5.
Our model of the US economy has been re-estimated on the rebased
national accounts data, and the major revisions are set out in Box 2. We
expect a rather muted recovery in the US this year with GNP growth of
around 1.8 per cent. This is largely accounted for by increased
consumers' expenditure combined with a small increase in net
exports. Although confidence among US consumers has been subdued in
recent months we believe that the obvious determination of the monetary
authorities to prevent the recovery from faltering, apparent from
official statements and recent substantial easing of monetary conditions
in the US, should gradually engender more consumer optimism and prevent
the savings ratio from rising further. Rising real incomes and upward
revaluations of net financial wealth should provide the impetus for a
significant increase in consumption this year. Real disposable incomes
should benefit from both the rise in nominal incomes caused by the
recovery in activity and a further fall in inflation. Subdued import
prices, low levels of capacity utilisation and decelerating unit labour
costs growth should all contribute to continued downward pressure on
prices in 1992. Depressed activity in the US should encourage importers
to restrain prices, and hence squeeze profit margins in order to
maintain market share, while US unit labour costs will also be
restrained as employment growth usually lags output at this stage of the
cycle.
Although we do not forecast any significant growth in either US
housing or business investment this year, the interest rate declines of
last year should prevent these expenditure categories from falling any
further in 1992. In fact, given our inflation and interest rate profile,
expost real interest rates will be approximately zero in the US this
year. Next year we predict that GNP will grow by around 2-5 per cent as
the full impact of lower real interest rates feeds through to all the
expenditure categories.
The US balance of payments forecast is given in Table 6. The
visible trade balance deteriorates in line with the increase in US
demand this year and next but remains fairly stable as a per cent of
GDP. However, the current account will register a more severe
deterioration over this period as the Gulf War transfers of 1991 drop
out of the surplus on invisibles. In the medium-term we expect the
current account deficit to stabilise at around 1 per cent of GDP. This
is somewhat more optimistic than previous forecasts. The depressed level
of activity in the US, combined with the one-off Gulf War payments, have
reduced the decline in US net overseas assets which, in turn, has
decelerated the deterioration in US net revenue from interest, profits
and dividends. As box 2 shows, the new national accounts data have
caused us to revise our estimates of demand elasticities downward. This
revision implies that for any given US GNP growth rate the current
balance deficit will be lower than previously anticipated. This also
partly explains our less optimistic forecast for world trade growth.
In his state of the Union address to Congress, President Bush
outlined plans for a small short-term fiscal stimulus comprising
temporary tax credits for first time homebuyers, increases in personal
allowances for each child and a cut in capital gains tax. Given the
current depressed state of the US economy and the expectation of a
stronger fiscal expansion these measures were perceived as somewhat
disappointing. But the government view seems to be that the discount
rate cuts are sufficient to promote recovery and adding a substantial
fiscal stimulus on top of these expansionary forces would be unwise.
Furthermore, an expansionary fiscal package of tax cuts could drive the
deteriorating public sector deficit to levels beyond the tolerance of
the financial markets, perhaps prompting a reversal of the recent easing
of monetary conditions.
In the medium-term, President Bush has stated his intention of
further increasing the "peace-dividend". An extra $50 bn of
defence cuts are now projected in addition to the current plans to
reduce the US armed forces by 25 per cent over the next five years.
Nevertheless, even after accounting for these expenditure reductions, in
contrast to previous forecasts, the administration is not projecting a
balanced budget in the medium-term. It is the expected growth of
mandatory expenditure on pensions, welfare payments and other social
entitlements which sustains a large federal deficit into the
longer-term. Our US public sector forecast is given in table 7. Our
figures for the deficit use equations based on data from the national
income and product accounts. The projected deficit therefore excludes
any temporary or permanent additional borrowing directly related to the
collapse of the Savings and Loans institutions. This would add $115
billion to our deficit projection in fiscal 1992 and $58 billion in
1993. We have, however, made an allowance for increased interest
payments on this stock of debt.
We expect the recent recession and subdued growth in 1992 to cause
a deterioration in the deficit as tax revenues will be lower and
expenditure on unemployment insurance benefit will remain at a high
level.
Consequently we are forecasting that the Federal and total Public
Sector deficit on a NIPA basis will worsen in 1992 to $231 billion and
$204 billion respectively. Renewed trend GDP growth after 1993 should
create the conditions for a sustained downward trajectory for the
deficit/GDP ratio to around 1 per cent by the end of the decade. Our
medium-term projection of substantially lower nominal interest rates
compared to the 1980s will expedite the process of deficit reduction by
lowering debt interest payments.
Japan
The Bank of Japan has followed a tight monetary policy in recent
years in response to inflationary pressures. A discount rate of 2.5 per
cent in early 1989 was successively increased to 6-0 per cent by the
second half of 1990 and, as money supply growth decelerated, the rate
was gradually reduced to 4.5 per cent with the latest V2 per cent cut in
December of last year. This recent cut was in response to both
decelerating inflation (accompanied by weak monetary growth) and a
slowing economy. Although labour market pressures have eased in recent
months the underlying rate of inflation is still high by Japanese
standards particularly now that import prices are not failing so rapidly
in response to a stronger Yen.
GNP growth reached 5.3 per cent in 1990 but decelerated to
approximately 4.5 per cent in 1991 as both consumer spending and
particularly investment reacted to higher interest rates. Real GNP
growth fell successively in the first three quarters of last year with
the result that unplanned stockbuilding occurred. Figures for the 4th
quarter suggest that housing starts may now be responding to lower
interest rates (although they are 20 per cent lower than a year ago) but
business investment is still subdued. The outlook for the latter
category for 1992 is poor. A MITI survey reveals that for this fiscal
year manufacturers expect to reduce investment by 7-5 per cent although
some growth is expected in non-manufacturing investment. This recent,
and expected future, poor performance in business investment is due to
weak demand and poor company profits combined with high interest rates.
Furthermore, difficulties with equity financing resulting from both the
fall in the stock market in 1991 and new rules concerning banks'
reserve ratios will not make raising capital any easier.
Consumers' expenditure in Japan was temporarily boosted by a
decrease in foreign travel by Japanese tourists during the Gulf war
period. Nevertheless, the weakening of demand and a higher rate of price
inflation depressed real incomes and resulted in a slightly smaller rise
in consumers' expenditure last year. The fall in the stock market
will also have reduced consumers' wealth and this in turn should
reduce consumption growth. But inflationary pressures are now easing as
the labour market has become weaker. The unemployment rate rose to 2.2
per cent in December of last year and labour shortages decreased. In
particular, the ratio of unfilled vacancies to job seekers fell from a
peak of 1.47 in March 1991 to 1-30 in December. Although inflation will
not benefit so much from lower import prices as in 1991 the general
inflationary trend should be downward this year as activity slows and
wage increases become more subdued. The introduction of a land tax to
dampen land and property prices should also add to this deflationary tendency. Fears of trade policy friction between the US and Japan were
renewed as the Japanese current account surplus increased to $77 bn in
1991 from $36 bn in 1990. This is particularly surprising given the fall
in demand due to the US recession. However, the surplus with SE Asia and
the EEC rose faster than with the US. This is partly explained by the
fact that many Japanese multinational companies export to the US via
overseas production in the EEC. The trade surplus has benefitted from
higher export growth due to strong demand growth in SE Asia slightly
offset by weaker demand in the US, but import volume growth has recently
turned negative due to the weaker activity in Japan. The invisibles
deficit was also slightly lower in 1991 as Japanese tourism abroad was
subdued due to the Gulf War.
Table 8 shows our GNP forecast for Japan. We expect GNP to grow by
only 2 1/4 per cent this year which is virtually a recession in Japanese
terms (by Japanese definitions this means growth below 2 per cent). Most
of this slow-down in demand will probably originate from a deceleration in both consumption and business investment. Our global econometric
model (NIGEM) now contains net financial wealth as a determinant of
consumption. A persistent decline in Japanese equity prices has
contributed to falls in real net financial wealth over the past two
years. Consequently, a desire on the part of consumers to rebuild wealth
stocks underlies much of our projected increase in the savings ratio
this year. This is consistent with consumer surveys such as the Nikkel
consumption forecast index which recently registered the largest fall
since 1980 when the index first began. Business sentiment has also
deteriorated and, its combination with falling capacity utilisation,
will discourage capital expenditure in industry. We therefore expect
business investment to grow at a rate of only 3 per cent this year. In
contrast, housing investment has already shown signs of a recovery and
will strengthen further during 1992 in response to the recent declines
in the cost of borrowing. However, although NIGEM predicts that the
Japanese economy responds strongly to an easing of monetary conditions
it does take some time for the effects to work through completely. Most
of the benefits from the recent loosening of monetary policy are more
likely to occur in 1993. We therefore expect an expansion in most
expenditure categories, particularly consumption, to push GNP growth
towards 3-5 per cent next year.
Until recently the Japanese authorities have conducted a tight
fiscal and monetary policy with the objective of dampening underlying
inflationary pressure. Plans for a looser fiscal stance in 1992 and the
recent easing of monetary conditions suggest that the official view is
that inflationary tendencies are now weaker. We believe that this is
indeed the case and expect the short, but sharp, slowdown in growth to
bring the consumers' expenditure deflator down to a 2 per cent
increase this year. Both the strength of the Yen (by suppressing import
price growth) and the easing of labour market pressures should be major
factors behind this projected fall in inflation. However, further
significant reductions in the discount rate are unlikely this year.
Renewed GNP growth next year will probably be associated with a small
rise in inflation to around 2 1/4 per cent.
Although we foresee Japan's exports growing rapidly in 1992
this is again largely due to strong demand growth in markets such as the
Far East rather than the US. In the longer term, we expect Japan's
share of world trade to decline. This is partly due to Japanese
companies locating production abroad and the growth of intra-European
trade as integration within Europe progresses. Similarly, import
penetration will increase as the Japanese economy continues to open up.
Table 9 shows that in the medium term we are projecting that import
volume growth will exceed that of exports. Consequently, we do not see
the Japanese surplus as a medium term problem. We are projecting a trend
decline in Japan's current account surplus to around 1 per cent of
GDP in the latter half of this decade. In the short term, we expect the
current account surplus to benefit from subdued domestic demand and
probably expand to around $90 bn this year and to show only a marginal
reduction in 1993.
Germany
The reunification boom of 1990 in Germany has been followed by a
considerable downturn in economic activity in the second half of 1991.
Real GNP was still rising strongly in the first quarter of last year but
both the second and third quarters witnessed declines and preliminary
figures indicate that real GDP only grew by 3-2 per cent in 1991
compared to 4-5 per cent in 1990. Declines in investment and exports
were to blame for the initial fall but these have recovered slightly
since then. However, the unification' indirect tax of 7-5 per cent
implemented in July appears to have triggered the downturn in the third
quarter as consumer spending fell by 1-9 per cent.
Industrial production began to fall rapidly in December after
previous increases, but capacity utilisation in manufacturing has been
declining since the second quarter of 1991 (reaching 86.8 per cent in
the fourth quarter of 1991 compared to 90 per cent a year earlier).
Although investment in plant and machinery rose ill the third quarter
this followed a substantial decline in the second quarter. After rising
by 9-3 per cent in 1990, capital expenditure growth will probably
decelerate to around 7 per cent in 1991 with a further slowdown in 1992
to around 3 per cent. Total orders (for the whole economy) in November
and December were 11 per cent lower than the previous two months. This
not only reflected a lower growth of domestic orders but indicated a
substantial fall in export orders as recession overseas subdued foreign
demand.
In this environment of rapidly declining demand and output the
Bundesbank decided to increase the discount rate by 0.5 per cent on 19th
December. The discount rate had previously been increased by 1 per cent
and 0.5 per cent in August and February 1991 respectively, and a further
rise came as a surprise. However, the Bundesbank was well aware that its
anti-inflation resolve was under scrutiny given developments in the
labour market and the increasing budget deficit. The weakening of the
D-Mark and the breaking of the monetary growth target in December and
November i.e. 5-7 per cent and 5.1 per cent respectively compared to
the already downward revised target of 3-5 per cent) put further
pressure on the authorities. Inflation reached 3.5 per cent at the end
of 1991, the highest since 1982 and a substantial increase on 2-7 per
cent of 1990. In contrast hourly wage rates increases were on a downward
path; rising by 7-2 per cent in the summer, 6.9 per cent in October and
6-7 per cent in November. This reflected slower activity and a severe
weakening of the labour market. The unemployment rate rose to 7-0 per
cent in January 1992 from 6.5 per cent in December 1991. During 1991 the
combination of a slowdown in the second half and an influx of East
Europeans increased the unemployment rate. Given these factors, and the
increased competition for jobs in West Germany from 1/2 million
commuting East Germans, it seems that wage growth should continue to
decline. However, the recent steelworkers' settlement of 6.4 per
cent may provide a benchmark for other groups in more successful
industries. Future settlements by public sector workers and others will
determine whether the Bundesbank will find it necessary to increase
interest rates further.
Reunification resulted in additional costs for the West German
government in terms of unemployment and other social benefits. In
addition, the cost of the Gulf war has added to the public debt. The
original target for the total public sector deficit for 1991 was D-Mark
140 bn. But it is now generally expected to be considerably above this
figure, but below the worst projections. Spending has been lower than
expected and the strength of demand in West Germany has boosted tax
revenues. Also taxes have been increased in 1991 in addition to the July
indirect tax increase. Oil and petrol along with other consumer taxes
have risen and an increase in unemployment benefit contributions is
expected to raise D-Mark 18 bn.
GDP is expected to grow by 10 per cent in East Germany in 1992
after two successive years of decline. The volume of industrial output
began growing in September 1991 of last year. But output is at a very
low level; in September of last year it was 28 per cent below that of a
year earlier. At one stage output had contracted by 40 per cent.
Unemployment in East Germany has risen substantially. Low productivity
and the removal of subsidies has resulted in the closing down of many
firms. July saw a large increase in unemployment as the one year ban on
redundancies in the engineering industry ended. However, up to 1/2 a
million workers have found jobs in the west. job creation schemes and
training programmes also helped alleviate unemployment by around 400,000
at the end of 1991. Consequently, the unemployment rate was roughly 11.8
per cent in December 1991 after peaking at 12-1 per cent in August 1991.
The number of employees on shorttime working has also been reduced to
just over 1 million at the end of 1991 compared with 2-0 million in
April.
Table 10 contains our forecast for German national income. We
expect a considerable slowdown in GNP growth this year to around 1 1/4
per cent followed by a sharp recovery in growth to around 3 per cent in
1993. Our projected interest rate profile and the downturn in consumer
and producer confidence are the key factors influencing this projected
path for GNP. We assume that the Bundesbank is worried about sustained
wage inflation and will not reduce interest rates until the third
quarter of this year. This also coincides with the expiry of the
indirect tax levy. These two factors are likely to restrain
consumers' expenditure in the first half of the year, outweighing
the expenditure-inducing rise in real disposable income produced by
robust wage inflation. We expect a considerable upturn in consumption
from the second half of the year driven by falling interest rates.
Business investment growth is expected to slow down to around 2 per
cent this year but housing investment will be fairly strong as East
Germans who currently commute to work buy homes in the West. A sustained
recovery in business investment next year, in response to continued
declines in the discount rate and a return to a high level of capacity
utilisation, will add to the recovery in 1993.
Table 11 gives our German balance of payments forecast and shows
that we expect the German current account to move back into surplus this
year. The severity of our projected shock to demand will considerably
subdue import volume growth, whereas the output that was temporarily
diverted to satisfy domestic demand during the unification boom will
return to the overseas market and boost export growth. The invisibles
balance will also improve this year as external transfers were
temporarily boosted by Gulf War payments in 1991. In the medium term we
expect the current balance surplus to increase gradually as a percentage
of GDP.
High wage inflation this year will increase government tax revenue
considerably in 1992. Combined with the extra indirect tax income, this
will offset the increased government outlays on job creation schemes and
unemployment benefit and the public sector deficit as a percent of GDP
should fall this year. We expect this deficit to dwindle to a
sustainable 1 1/2 per cent of GDP by 1995. Our forecast for the public
sector is given in table 12.
France
French GDP rose 0.7 per cent in the third quarter of 1991, the same
growth rate as in the second quarter and well above the 0.2 per cent
rate recorded in the first quarter. Despite signs that an upturn has
been under way for some time, however, the official forecast for 1991
has been revised downwards, from 2.8 to 1.4 per cent, mainly reflecting
the adverse effects of the Gulf war on foreign trade. The outlook for
1992 is slightly brighter, as most components of GDP are expected to
pick up, especially exports. Households' consumption of
manufactured products (excluding food) in the last quarter of 1991 was
up 0.8 per cent on the previous quarter and the year-on year increase
was 0.4 per cent. After strong growth in October, there was a fall in
November and December. Total consumption of manufactured goods fell 0.3
per cent in 1991, compared with an increase of 3.4 in 1990 and 4.5 in
1989. Sales of consumer durables also fell in December, but the January
survey of retail trade by INSEE shows that non-food sales rose slightly
in November/December.
Investment picked up 0.1 per cent in the third quarter of 1991,
following a fall of 0.4 per cent in the second and first quarters of the
same year and a sharper fall of 1.6 per cent in the last quarter of
1990. The recovery was mainly driven by household investment, which rose
by 0.7 per cent in the third quarter, whereas business investment
dropped by 0.4 per cent and government investment grew by a sluggish 0.4
per cent compared with 1.8 per cent in the previous quarter. For 1991
as a whole, a 0.9 per cent rise in investment is expected by INSEE. The
official government forecast is that business investment will grow at a
rate of 3.5 per cent in 1992. Industrial production fell by 0.6 per cent
in November, with manufacturing output declining further as a result of
a reduction in the production of capital goods and intermediate goods.
There are, however, signs of a rebound, especially in construction
activity, which should strengthen in the second half of this year.
Capacity utilisation, which had fallen to its lowest level for four
years in the third quarter, picked up in the final quarter of 1991 to
reach 82.1 per cent. Gains in competitiveness resulting from lower
inflation and a weakening of the French Franc on the foreign exchange
markets have boosted exports since March 1991. In particular, exports to
Germany have increased since unification. The trade account showed a Fr
2.6 billion surplus in the three months to December, as exports rose by
0.3 per cent and imports fell by 4.0 per cent on the previous quarter.
As for the current account, the surplus in the same period was Fr 6.9
bn. Price inflation increased by 0.1 per cent in December, down from 0.3
in November and 0.4 in October. The annual rate, which was 2-9 per cent
in the last quarter of 1991, is running considerably below the German
level. Wage inflation is also slowing down, as unemployment remains high
(9-8 per cent in December) and vacancies are still lower than a year
ago. The government's commitment to the ERM has resulted in tough
anti-inflation policies and high real interest rates. Monetary policy
remains tight: the target range for M3 growth, which was 5.7 per cent
for 1991, has been lowered to 4.6 per cent for 1992, and the
intervention rate of the Bank of France, after a cut in October by 0.25
per cent, was raised by 0.5 in November and then again in December by
0.35 per cent in response to the Bundesbank's decision to raise
German official rates by 0.5 per cent. As a result, French short-rates
and the three-month Euro-franc deposit rates have increased slightly.
The future trend is, however, downward and interest rate spreads over
Germany have been virtually eliminated, as foreign investors have
confidence in the French government's resolve to pursue policies
compatible with the ERM exchange rate constraint.
Fiscal consolidation is still being pursued, even though the 1991
central-government budget deficit is estimated to have reached Fr 100
billion, well above the target of Fr 81 billion. This is partly due to
lower tax receipts, as the shifting of a number of products from a lower
to a higher VAT rate has only partially offset the lower than expected
corporation and income tax receipts which the slackening in activity has
caused. The projected deficit for 1992 is Fr 89 billion, with overall
spending growing by 3.1 per cent to Fr 1,330 billion, about the same as
the forecast rate of inflation for this year. The tax burden is set to
remain unchanged, the reduction in the rate of corporation tax being
balanced by an Increase from 25 to 34 per cent in the tax on financial
capital gains. Some revenue will accrue from the selling to the private
sector of a minority stake in some state-controlled companies. The main
worry continues to be the deficit on health and social security, set to
widen in 1992, and the government is determined to come to grips with it
by setting binding limits as well as increasing health-insurance and
unemployment contributions. Overall, there is likely to be a slight rise
in the ratio of government gross debt to GDP, especially when the top
rate of VAT is abolished on the way to harmonising tax systems across
Europe.
With inflation and public finances under control, the high rate of
unemployment is now the foremost concern. The French government takes
the view that supply-side policies are more appropriate to deal with
increasing joblessness, because cyclical factors account for only a
small percentage of the unemployed. More flexibility in the labour
market, re-training schemes and lower taxation to reduce the tax wedge
are deemed much more effective methods than a loosening of the fiscal or
monetary stance. The latest measures adopted by the government include
tax exemptions for firms employing young unqualified people and 18-month
subsidised training programmes for youths who have been unemployed for
over six months.
We are forecasting that economic growth in 1992 will not be much
stronger than in 1991 (see table 13). Activity is expected to pick up
only gradually, to approach potential growth not earlier than 1993, when
GDP is forecast to grow by 2 1/2 per cent. One important factor
accounting for the modest rate of output growth is the persistence of
high real interest rates resulting from the commitment to the ERM and
the stability of the exchange rate. Despite the increase in credibility,
real rates are still above the German ones, and the present weakness of
the Franc makes it unlikely that French rates will fall much before the
end of the year. The trade balance is not expected to give a strong
boost to growth either, as a slightly more buoyant demand starts feeding
into imports, and exports do not grow at a brisk pace because of a
weakening in the German growth rate. However, some small improvement in
the current account balance is forecast for 1992 and 1993. Our forecast
for the current account is contained in table 14.
The consumer' expenditure deflator will keep rising at a rate
below that of France's European trading partners (we forecast 3-4
per cent for 1992), and unit labour costs will grow only moderately, as
high and rising unemployment has its impact on wage claims and the new
measures to increase labour demand will take time to come into
operation. We expect the unemployment rate to stabilise next year. A
reduction in the number of unemployed in the short run will not result
from the expected modest growth in industrial production and investment
of 1.4 per cent and 1/2 per cent respectively in 1992. The combination
of all the factors mentioned above, in particular a weak external demand
and subdued investment and real disposable income growth, underlies our
projection of only a modest pick-up in the current year.
Italy
The latest available data show that GDP growth in Italy is still
sluggish and inflation is not yet fully under control. The year-on year
fall in industrial production in October was 2.4 per cent, and in the
first ten months of 1991 it equaled 2-3 per cent. The fall was
particularly sharp for investment goods (-5.9 per cent) and intermediate
goods (-2.4 per cent). In the final quarter of 1991 production was 0.9
per cent below its year-earlier level, although 1.4 per cent above its
level in the previous quarter.
Despite the slowdown in activity in 1991, there has been no
improvement in Italy's external position. The trade balance showed
a deficit of Lit 1,393 billion in October, bringing the total deficit
from the beginning of the year to Lit 15,519 billion (Lit 3,000 billion
more than in 1990). Imports rose by 4-6 per cent in the same period,
while exports grew by 3.1 per cent. The widening external deficit is
primarily a consequence of lower exports to the US. More encouragingly,
imports to, and exports from, the other EC countries have been growing
at the same rate (5 per cent). However, the demand surge associated with
German unification might have been expected to have been associated with
an improvement in the trade account, and the fact that this has not
happened suggests that deteriorating competitiveness is having an
effect.
In spite of a deceleration from 6.2 to 6.0 per cent in December,
the annual rate of inflation was 6-4 per cent in 1991, slightly up from
1990, and above the official target forth year. In January, the index
picked up a little to 6-1 per cent. More marked is the deceleration in
producer prices, which by the end of October were growing at an annual
rate of 2.1 per cent. Labour cost developments are still a major
concern. Despite the slackening in the industrial sector and the fact
that the rate of decline of employment has reached 3-2 per cent in
October, average earnings rose by 12-8 per cent in the first nine months
of the year. No swift action is, however, going to be taken, as the
government, employers and unions agreed in December not to tackle the
renewal of the 'scala mobile' wage indexation system, due to
expire at the end of the current year, until after the next general
election. Wage settlements outstripping the rate of inflation partly
explain why consumption is the most buoyant component of aggregate
demand. The high level of public sector debt held by private households
and the interest payments they receive have also contributed to
moderating the slowdown in the growth in real personable disposable
income and therefore consumption. Fixed investment is still stagnating
as business confidence has yet to make a full recovery.
Last December Italy increased the official discount rate from 11.5
per cent to 12 per cent in response to the Bundesbank's decision to
tighten its monetary policy. This rise in the cost of borrowing could
lead to a further slowdown of the economy and renewed calls for a `final
realignment' of the ERM currencies before they are irrevocably locked. The more immediate impact of this measure will be on the
projected budget deficit for 1992, which fails to take into account the
additional cost of servicing the debt, expected to be approximately Lit
6500 billion, and the lower tax receipts resulting from GDP growth in
the current fiscal year likely to be below the 2.3 per cent originally
forecast by the government. The budget finally approved alms for a
public sector deficit of Lit 128,000 billion, equivalent to 10.5 per
cent of GDP. To achieve this target, both spending cuts and new receipts
are envisaged. New receipts accruing from privatisation are expected to
be of the order of Lit 6000 billion, despite the fact that the necessary
legislation has not been included in the budget and has yet to be
approved by Parliament. Other measures include a tax amnesty allowing
evaders to pay only 15-20 per cent of the unpaid taxes back to 1986, and
an increase in income taxes by 1 per cent for incomes above Lit 14
million a year. Recently, there have been some signs that, at long last,
Italy is trying to come to grips with some of its longstanding
structural problems, which are a serious obstacle to meeting the targets
for economic convergence on the way to EMU. Of particular significance
is a new law passed in January which officially sanctions the divorce
between the Treasury and the Bank of Italy in the setting of the
discount rate, giving full independence, in this respect, to the Central
Bank which in the past could only give advice to the Treasury who had
final responsibility for the interest rate policy. The latter, however,
is still entitled to overdrafts with the Central Bank. A stronger will
to tackle the budget deficit appears to be behind the concomitant decision to reorganise the Treasury by creating a council of independent
advisers on the conduct of fiscal policy. An additional measure adopted
to bring Italy in line with its European partners is the abolition of
the 30 per cent withholding tax on interest for interbank deposits, with
the aim of liberalising capital markets.
As regards fiscal consolidation, however, progress to date has been
minimal and Italy's public finance problems continue unabated (the
stock of outstanding gross debt has now reached 103 per cent of GDP).
Notwithstanding the approval of the EC Commission for this budget, the
first they have monitored, it is far from certain that Italy will be
able to meet the debt/deficits criteria of the Maastricht treaty. In the
short run, the implementation of spending cuts has been made even more
difficult by the forthcoming general election, announced for April 5, as
a plethora of new spending bills have been rushed through Parliament
before its formal dissolution. The outcome of the elections looks highly
uncertain, at least by the standards of a political system where
electoral swings of 1 or 2 per cent are regarded as a major shake-up.
Most analysts expect a further fragmentation of the vote and a decline
of the traditional parties, which could mean that electoral support for
the present four-party coalition government could fall below the
necessary 50 per cent level. In that case, the Republican party, who
withdrew from the coalition last year because of disagreements over the
conduct of economic policy, would probably be invited to rejoin its
former government partners. This is likely to be the last general
election to be held under the present political rules, as virtually all
parties have put forward proposals for radical reforms which are deemed
necessary for Italy to be able to make any further moves towards
economic and monetary integration. Presidential elections are also to be
held when Cossiga's term in office ends next july.
Our forecast is set out in table 15, and shows only a small
improvement in Italy's economic performance in 1992. We expect
output growth to be around 2 per cent in the current year, reflecting
the weak growth of the last quarter of 1991 and the downward revision in
expectations which is apparent from most recent surveys. A rebound is,
however, likely in the second half of the year, fueled by stronger
demand in world export markets and a pick-up in consumption. Capital
spending will remain sluggish, as profit margins are still small due to
the fact that wage claims are still buoyant. The rate of price inflation
should ease to 4 3/4 per cent this year, but only if wage inflation
slows as a result of the introduction of a new indexation system
combined with restraint in the public sector. More significant should be
the deceleration in producer price rises, though their rate of increase
will remain above the German one. As the inflation outlook is relatively
unfavourable convergence of interest rates in the short term to German
levels will be slow, with short rates declining to around 10 1/2 per
cent by the end of 1993.
Canada
Although it seemed that Canada was experiencing a strong recovery
when real GDP increased 5.7 per cent in the 2nd quarter of 1991 this was
followed by a much smaller 0.9 per cent increase in the following
quarter. This faltering recovery was largely due to a small increase of
0.8 per cent in consumer spending compared to 8-0 per cent in the
previous quarter. But a continuing decline in business investment also
added to the deceleration in growth. A small fall in real personal
disposable income accompanied by a slight deterioration in consumer
confidence (according to the Conference Board of Canada Index of
Consumer Attitudes) accounts for this slowdown in consumer spending.
This means that the savings ratio has remained stable for over a year,
even though factors which caused a decline in the 1979-81 recession,
declining interest rates and lower inflation, have already improved for
some time. Furthermore, the net wealth/income ratio has reached a record
level which should stimulate spending. However, unemployment has still
to recover and may be one factor behind continued poor confidence. More
worrying is the continued decline in business investment. Low capacity
utilisation makes further investment inappropriate at this stage but
profits have recovered somewhat and the outlook for growth is the
strongest of the G7. Nevertheless profits are only 50 per cent of the
level of a year ago and are largely responsible for the very poor
corporate financial position which must be a major factor inhibiting
investment. A more optimistic development in the third quarter was the
continued strong growth of residential investment.
Exports also added some growth last year but were less strong than
was hoped largely because the US, Canada's largest trading partner,
was in the midst of recession. Unfortunately, imports surged in the
third quarter resulting in the largest current account deficit ever
($28-8 bn at an annual rate). This may signal that the recovery in
output is far more considerable than the official figures suggest.
Secondly, it indicates that the previous deterioration in Canadian unit
labour costs is now affecting the trade deficit. Another factor may be
the effects of the Canada-USA free trade agreement which may encourage
US multinational corporations to relocate back in the US thus increasing
Canadian imports and subduing exports. However, unit labour costs may
now be improving as price and wage inflation seem to be moderating.
Underlying consumer price inflation is better represented by the three
month annualised rate, as it avoids the distortion of the Goods and
Sales Tax introduced in january 1991, which only grew by 1 per cent in
the three months to November 1991. Private sector wage settlements have
been falling for at least a year as wage negotiations respond to poor
output expectations and lower expected future inflation. Wage restraint
in the public sector has reduced settlements in this sector to around 2
per cent in October. If wage inflation can be contained in the future
then international competitiveness may improve.
Our forecast for Canadian GDP and trade is given in Table 16. After
falling by almost 1 per cent last year we expect that GDP growth will
show a marked recovery to just above 3 per cent this year. Both
consumers' expenditure and housing investment should respond to the
easing of monetary conditions and provide the major stimulus to growth.
But business investment will take longer to recover and will probably
remain flat for most of this year and then grow again in 1993. In
addition, a further rise in consumption should push GDP growth towards
its trend rate of 3.5 to 4 per cent next year and continue into the
medium-term. In our short-term forecast, the improved consumption
growth is largely due to rising real disposable income as price
inflation decelerates. This, in turn, is due in part to the GST falling
out of the annual rate calculation, but continued wage moderation is
also an important factor. The persistence of an unemployment rate around
10 per cent for this year and next indicates the weakness of the labour
market.
Another factor generating future likely improvement in the growth
in Canada is the performance of exports. Although partly due to a less
rapid deterioration in relative unit labour costs, renewed growth in the
US accounts for much of the improvement. Import penetration is high in
Canada and may be further increased by the removal of trade restrictions
with the US. Given the erosion of overseas net assets due to the
cumulative effects of a persistent current account deficit, the balance
on IPD will also prevent the trade deficit from improving substantially.
Therefore, it is difficult to see a sustained reduction in the Canadian
current balance deficit in the short or medium term.