Fiscal solvency in Europe: budget deficits and government debt under European Monetary Union.
Caporale, Guglielmo Maria
Introduction
The debate on European monetary union has brought the issue of
European fiscal policy into public scrutiny. This note discusses the
problems of fiscal policy coordination in Europe over the next decade,
and analyses the evolution of debt and deficits over the 1970s and
1980s. We then look more formally at the concept of a sustainable path
for public debt and report on some tests that investigate whether or not
debt paths in Europe have been on a stable trajectory. The note by
Barrell and In't Veld in this Review considers the importance of
fiscal solvency in constructing large scale macro models, and casts
further light on the issues discussed here.
Fiscal policy issues and EMU
The prospect of monetary union in Europe has led to an increase in
interest in the size and evolution of the government debt of the members
of the European Community. The Maastricht Treaty on Monetary Union has
laid down convergence criteria that potential members of the Union must
meet. The Treaty explicitly refers to the need to 'avoid excessive
public deficits', and sets the following thresholds which should
not be exceeded:
- public deficits as a share of GDP should not be higher than 3 per
cent;
- gross public debt should be contained within 60 per cent of GDP.
If these criteria were to be interpreted strictly it is very
unlikely that EMU could go ahead according to the prepared timetable
with all (or even most) of the member states of the EC as participants.
Thus the importance attached to the fiscal indicators may well determine
the whole shape of EMU at least in its early years. The EC Commission
has expressed repeatedly its concern that the process of formation of
the union should involve both keeping the evolution of debt stocks under
control and constructing a set of effective fiscal safeguards.
Divergent fiscal trajectories could make the transition to EMU more
difficult, because of their implications for exchange rate movements.
This can be seen clearly within a portfolio approach to the
determination of exchange rates. In such a theoretical framework, the
main determinant of the exchange rate is asset equilibrium. If a large
amount of public sector debt is issued denominated in one currency, this
will change its equilibrium nominal exchange rate, and put downward
pressure on it, which will have to be offset by market intervention or
higher interest rates. EC countries could find it difficult to resist
these pressures in the run-up to EMU. A budget deficit is commonly
associated with a current account deficit, and hence a decline in net
financial assets (the difference between gross assets and liabilities)
for the economy as a whole. Therefore large budget deficits will often
raise the risk premium on the currency of the country. If the nominal
exchange rate is fixed, this will mean a higher interest differential,
which conflicts with the objective of macroeconomic convergence.
However, with the establishment of a monetary union assets denominated
in different currencies will become perfect substitutes and risk premia
will be abolished, thereby eliminating the problems encountered in the
run-up to EMU.
Why then should the Community be concerned with the fiscal policies
adopted by the individual states once EMU has been created? Should there
be consistency between those policies and the common monetary policy at
the Community level? The Delors Report (1989) asserted that 'the
large and persistent budget deficit in certain countries has remained a
source of tensions and has put a disproportionate burden on monetary
policy' (paragraph 5), and voiced the concern that '...access
to a large capital market may... facilitate the financing of economic
imbalances' (paragraph 30). It also advocated 'binding
rules... (involving) effective upper limits on budget deficits of
individual countries' (paragraph 33).
Deficits have to be financed either by issuing debt or by creating
base money. Sargent and Wallace (1981)have argued that persistent budget
deficits will eventually result either in monetisation of the
outstanding stock of debt, thus depriving the monetary authorities of
their autonomy in setting policy targets, or in a repudiation of at
least part of the debt. Hence lack of fiscal discipline could undermine
the independence of a newly created European Central Bank, which might
come under potential pressure to loosen its policy stance if some member
states had serious budgetary problems. Its credibility could be affected
if agents thought that a softer stance would become inevitable to
alleviate the financial difficulties of highly indebted countries
running large deficits. One of the consequences would be an increase in
interest rates reflecting a revision in expectations incorporating
higher future inflation rates.
Fiscal discipline would still be a major concern in EMU even if the
European monetary authorities remained steadfast in their
anti-inflationary commitment, because those states with unsustainable
fiscal positions might have to pull out of EMU, whose irreversibility
would then be questioned. As a result, markets could take a different
view of the degree of substitutability of the assets issued by the
different countries. Furthermore, other externalities would be at work,
in the form of pressure on other member states to come to the rescue of
those with unsustainable debt/deficit paths. Another possibility is that
conflicts would arise 'on issues related to the distribution of ...
(seigniorage) among member countries' (Padoa-Schioppa, 1990). Other
consequences for the Community as a whole of the lack of fiscal
discipline would be a general rise in interest rates and an external
deficit for Europe vis-a-vis the rest of the world, with adverse effects
on the ECU exchange rate.(1) As to the introduction of binding fiscal
constraints, the argument is often put forward in the literature that
they may appear to improve welfare, but only if the existence of a
trade-off between fiscal and monetary policy is ignored (see
Padoa-Schioppa, 1990).
The creation of a monetary union will inevitably affect the setting
of fiscal policy. Even if only monetary policy becomes the
responsibility of the new Community institutions, with fiscal policy
remaining in the domain of national governments, the fact that they will
no longer be able to monetise debt has implications for policy choices.
Fiscal policy may play a more important role as a stabilisation tool in
EMU. In the standard Mundell-Fleming framework, in which sticky prices
are assumed (see Frankel and Razin, 1987, for a discussion of later
modifications to the Mundell-Fleming model, concerning in particular
price determination) fiscal policy is most effective when exchange rates
are fixed and there are free capital movements, conditions which will be
fulfilled in EMU. Because in a fixed rate system a fiscal expansion does
not lead to a rise in interest rates and to an appreciation of the
exchange rate, some countries might resort more frequently to fiscal
measures to respond to shocks, especially if they are country-specific.
Such budgetary policies could result in a looser overall fiscal stance,
especially if the fiscal authorities failed to distinguish between
temporary and permanent shocks. It is often claimed that fiscal policy
is the appropriate policy response only to the former, whereas the
latter require factor price adjustment, either on its own or in
combination with migration (see Bayoumi and Masson, 1992).
In a recession the ability of national governments to conduct
countercyclical macroeconomic policies will be limited by the fact that
they can not print money to finance their fiscal deficits and meet their
maturing obligations. A well-functioning EMU may require a centralised
mechanism to at least coordinate fiscal policy across member states.
Previous experiences of international coordination suggest that such
arrangements are rather ineffectual as a means of counteracting cyclical
fluctuations, mainly because the time lags normally associated with
fiscal policy become even longer when agreement has to be reached at a
supra-national level before national governments can carry out the
agreed policies. While fiscal coordination may be apt in the case of a
prolonged recession, the arguments for centralised decision-making are
less convincing when fiscal tightening is called for, because national
governments are not likely to be willing to adopt unpopular policies to
follow the directives of the central EC authorities. On these grounds,
therefore, it is difficult to argue in favour of a permanent EC body
exercising control over national fiscal policies.
There is, nevertheless, a rationale for some degree of control by
the central EC authorities. As already pointed out, market discipline
might become weaker and national governments might be tempted to resort
to borrowing to a larger extent if the possibility existed that the
European System of Central Banks (ESCB) would intervene in the case of a
financial crisis and bail them out. Although the ESCB may claim that it
would not intervene in such a case, such a possibility cannot entirely
be ruled out in the face of an imminent threat of default. This, in
turn, would make it easier for governments to finance rising budget
deficits, and would result in fiscal policies more expansionary than
compatible with the monetary stance set by the ESCB, and consequently in
undesirably high real interest rates and exchange rate for the Community
as a whole. It is also to be noticed that the EC authorities will not be
able to offset excessive spending by national governments by tightening
their fiscal stance, in the way central authorities at a national level
normally do in the presence of out-of-target spending by the local
authorities, as their fiscal powers will remain limited (see the fiscal
federalism literature, e.g. Sachs and Sala-i-Martin, 1991). Furthermore,
the adoption of a single currency will mean that currency risks will
disappear, with potentially lower real interest rates reflecting only
the concern that the government might default. This will mean a
weakening of market discipline, as small increases in real bond yields
will be sufficient to bring about huge inflows of international capital.
These considerations suggest that some degree of coordination of fiscal
policy would not be inappropriate. From a purely political perspective,
however, intervention by the EC central authorities could be
ineffective, if member states do not have the political will to cede
substantial fiscal powers, and the budgetary resources of the EC
authorities remain small.(2)
The European experience
Our discussion so far has shown that government solvency is a
crucial issue for Europe. In order to establish the extent to which
fiscal retrenchment is needed in the European countries wishing to join
the monetary union, and to give a realistic assessment of the prospects
for EMU, we first examine the evolution of public finances in the
Community over the last two decades, and then discuss a formal test of
the sustainability of present fiscal policies. Some broad tendencies are
discernible for the EC as a whole. In the 1970s, despite the fact that
total revenues as a share of GDP rose substantially, there was a marked
widening of public deficits brought about by a sharp increase in total
government spending. In the following decade, especially in the second
half, the tendency of public spending to grow as a share of GDP was
restrained and even reversed in some countries. At the same time,
revenues increased. As a result, the 1980s witnessed a significant
reduction in budget deficits. Charts 1 and 2 plot debt to income ratios
for seven of the major European economies, and Charts 3 and 4 plot the
deficit/income ratios.
The emergence of sustained budgetary disequilibria in the 1970s was
mainly a consequence of the two oil shocks and of the inadequate policy
response adopted by most governments. Monetary policy accommodated the
inflationary pressures rather than trying to moderate the increase in
labour costs, and the unemployment rate kept growing. Consequently,
social security spending and current expenditure in general rose
sharply, whereas capital expenditure was hit. The increase in the burden
of taxation was not sufficient to offset the explosion in expenditure.
The deficit/GDP ratios rose rapidly, and so did interest payments. High
inflation meant higher effective interest rates on public debt but a
fail in the value of outstanding debt relative to GDP at current prices.
Conversely, the 1980s saw a widespread process of budgetary
stabilisation, which owed much to cyclical factors as well as increased
revenues and slower growth in spending. Swelling budget deficits were
increasingly perceived as a severe constraint on growth, as an
exceedingly high percentage of domestic saving went to finance them
rather than private investment. Hence a reduction in borrowing became
the main objective of fiscal policy. The slowdown in the growth of
public expenditure was obtained mainly by keeping the public sector wage
bill under control, and reducing public investment and subsidies. Major
reforms to tax systems were introduced with the aim of achieving
medium-term targets such as higher productivity and growth. They
included a reduction of personal income tax rates, and a broadening of
the corporate and consumption tax base, which for many countries meant a
switch to VAT. The improvement in net positions was reflected in a
slight fall in the burden of interest payments and in the ratio of
public debt to GDP. Obviously, fiscal retrenchment was not pursued with
the same intensity in all countries. But the Community average net
borrowing, after reaching a peak of 5.5 per cent of GDP, had declined to
2-9 per cent by 1989 (source: Commission of the European Communities,
1991).
The trend in EC public finances appears to have changed again in
the present decade. The average budget deficit has increased to 4.1 per
cent of GDP in 1990, and 4.4 per cent in 1991 (source: Commission of the
European Communities, 1991). Recent macroeconomic developments are
partly responsible for this budgetary situation. A noticeably weaker
growth performance has had adverse effects on current expenditure and
receipts, and a generalized increase in long-term interest rates,
resulting from the deterioration in inflationary expectations and the
excess of demand over supply of funds, has affected charges on public
debt. However, it is also clear that fiscal stance is now looser in most
EC countries, obviously so in the case of Germany, which is incurring
the cost of German unification. As a result, general government
contribution to national saving has turned negative (- O. 1 per cent of
GDP in 1990, - 0.6 per cent in 1991. Source: Commission of the European
Communities, 1991).
We now turn to country-specific developments in the 1980s. In order
to see what the main factors were determining the evolution of debt in
individual countries we decompose the change in the stock of outstanding
debt as a ratio to GDP, db, in the following way:
db = dB/YP - (B/YP)*(PdY/YP) - (BlYP)*(YdP/YP) =
= dn/YP - (BlYP)*(dY/Y) - (BlYP)*(dPlP)=
= d - by - bp (1)
where B is gross debt, Y stands for real GDP, P is the GDP
deflator, b and d represent outstanding debt and deficit as a ratio to
GDP, and y and p the growth rate of GDP and of prices respectively. We
have assumed that the whole of the defidt d flows onto the bond stock.
This inevitably makes our calculations imprecise. Our decomposition enables us to establish to what extent a fail in the debt income ratio
reflects low deficits or rapid real income growth, or whether it is the
consequence of inflationary policies. The results are reported in table
1 (see also Charts 1 to 4).
The country which appears to have been most successful in reducing
its debt burden is the UK, whose gross debt declined from 54.5 to 35-8
per cent of GDP. Most of the reduction seems to be due to rising prices,
but real GDP growth also contributed to improving the British financial
position. Other important factors were a fall, by considerably more than
the OECD average, in subsidies, social security and capital transfers
(see Oxley and Martin, 1991). Public sector relative wages also
declined, as did debt interest payments, the only case in the OECD area
apart from Switzerland. In the other major European economies (Germany,
France and Italy) and in three other countries which already had severe
debt problems (the Netherlands, Belgium, Ireland) the debt/GDP ratio
rose in the 1980s. The increase was slight in Germany and France, more
pronounced in the Netherlands, even more so in Italy, Belgium and
Ireland. Our decomposition reveals that the effect of inflation on the
debt stock was less in Germany than in France. In Germany there was a
considerable reduction in government consumption and investment, and
capital transfers were also cut.
Besides, the second half of the 1980s saw a fail in average
relative wages of government employees. As for France, a small cut in
subsidies and a sluggish growth in public sector wages were more than
offset by increases in social security spending well above the OECD
average.
In a number of countries the change in the debt stock was driven
mainly by accumulating deficits. In the Netherlands developments on the
revenue side resulting from GDP growth, deep cuts in government
consumption and restraint on public sector pay were not sufficient to
prevent persistent huge deficits. As a result, the stock of debt and
debt interest payments grew by substantially more than the OECD average.
Accumulated debt was even higher in Belgium at the beginning of the
decade, and kept growing rapidly before declining slightly towards the
end of the eighties. GDP growth did not make a substantial contribution
to improving the Belgian financial position. All categories of current
and capital disbursements were cut, and public sector wages declined
relative to the public sector, but public deficits remained very high as
a percentage of GDP, and the cost of servicing the debt grew
considerably. The commitment to a strong D-Mark link kept Dutch, and to
a lesser extent, Belgian inflation rather low, and hence these countries
were unable to inflate away their debt stocks. Italy had the largest
deficits in the 1980s, and the debt/GDP ratio shot up, but by less than
it would have had it not been for the effects on the government finances
of high inflation. GDP growth accounted for much less of the evolution
of debt. A look at the structure of government outlays by economic
category shows that, with the exception of subsidies, there was no
restraint in the rise of both current and capital disbursements.
Government salaries also grew by more than in any other EC country.
Finally, Ireland relied to some extent on the effects of inflation to
make progress towards fiscal consolidation, but the breakdown of
expenditures also indicates that cut-backs in government consumption and
investment were essential part of the package of measures adopted (see
Oxley and Martin, 1991). Moreover, wage developments in the public
sector were rather subdued. Deficits over the whole period were large
but gradually declining. Hence the debt burden was falling slightly by
the end of the decade.
Commenting on the most recent developments, in its latest Annual
Economic Report (May 1991) the EC Commission underlines that 'half
of the member states show discouraging public accounts, which will
require the activation of significant adjustment measures in order to
preserve the credibility of the commitment towards monetary
stability'. If the convergence criteria of the Maastricht Treaty
were to be interpreted in rigid terms, countries like Italy would not be
able to participate in EMU. As noted in the Forecasting and Planning
Report published by the Italian authorities in September 1991, even if
the deficit was reduced to 3 per cent of GDP, the debt/GDP ratio would
still reach 94.7 per cent by the end of 1996. In order to fulfill the EC
60 per cent requirement, a surplus of more than 9 per cent of GDP should
be achieved by that time, which would require such severe budgetary
policies as can not be envisaged. However, it should be said that the
Treaty, notwithstanding its aim to avoid excessive government deficits,
allows some flexibility. In examining compliance with the budgetary
discipline criteria, the Commission is asked to consider not only
whether the reference values for public deficits and debt stocks have
been exceeded, but also whether the excesses are exceptional and
temporary, and whether they have been diminishing and approaching the
reference values at a satisfactory pace. On the other hand, the
Commission may prepare a report to the European Council even for those
countries who fulfil the debt/deficits requirements if it envisages a
risk of an excessive deficit. The adoption of thresholds in the protocol
which complements the Treaty should play a useful role by inducing
potential members of EMU to undertake a more rapid stabilisation of the
debt/GDP ratio in order to attain a sounder financial position more
compatible with the commitments deriving from the participation in EMU.
For instance, the Italian authorities are now aiming at attaining a
primary surplus, which would result in a5.5 per cent deficit/GDP ratio
by the end of 1994. The fact that some countries fail the rather
stringent criteria on debt laid down in the Maastricht Treaty should not
necessarily be used as a barrier to entry to EMU, especially if there is
evidence that they are attempting to stabilise their position. Hence it
is essential to determine whether they would become insolvent if the
present fiscal stance remained the same in the future. If they appeared
to be on an explosive path, a change either in policy or in some
structural features of the economy would be necessary.
Testing for sustainability
We now briefly discuss the theory of sustainability and its
testable implications, and present some empirical results for the four
major EC countries (Germany, France, Italy, UK), and the three other
countries whose fiscal position we have already considered (the
Netherlands, Belgium, Ireland). There are three ways of assessing the
sustainability of a government's fiscal policy. The first (see
Blanchard, 1990) amounts to asking the following question: given current
and expected spending and taxation, will it become necessary at some
stage to change policies to avoid a debt crisis? The second relies on
forecast paths that take account of expected changes in policy (see,
e.g., Anderton et al., 1991). The third is based on analysing the past
behaviour of the time series involved. Under the assumption that there
is no regime shift in the future and hence that the statistical
properties remain the same, the absence of stationarity in the time
series for the debt stock as a proportion of inccome(3) implies that a
country's fiscal position is not sustainable. A non-stationary debt
series indicates that there will be a debt explosion unless policies are
changed. We adopt the last approach below where we analyse the
statistical properties of historical debt series.
We need a slightly more rigorous definition of sustainability in
order to undertake statistical analysis. Following Blanchard (1990), we
can start from the government's dynamic budget constraint, which
simply says that in each period the change in the stock of public debt
is equal to non-interest spending minus receipts plus interest charges
on the debt. It can be formulated as follows:
db/dt = g + h - tx + (r-y)b = d +(r-y)b (2)
where b is public debt, g government spending on goods and
services, h transfers, tx is taxation, r the real interest rate, y the
growth rate of real GDP, and d is the primary deficit, equal by
definition to g + h - tx. All the variables are in ratio to GDP. From
(2) we can derive the government intertemporal budget constraint, also
known as the condition of sustainability of its fiscal policy, which can
be expressed as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (3)
where s is the primary surplus, equal to tx - g - b.
According to (3), the present value of taxes must be equal to the
present value of spending, including interest on the public debt, plus
repayment of the outstanding debt (we are assuming that r-y > 0).
Hence debt can not be serviced indefinitely by issuing new debt, and if
(3) does not hold a change in budgetary policies will necessarily occur
in the future if a debt crisis is to be prevented.
Given the intertemporal nature of the constraint for the
government, it is not obvious what the solvency limits are in any one
period. Blanchard (1990) develops a new set of sustainability
indicators. Let b be the current level of debt. Remembering that the
primary surplus s is by definition equal to ix-b-g, where tx is taxes, b
transfers and g government spending on goods and services (all as ratios
to GDP), we can solve for the sustainable tax rate tx * which satisfies
equation (3), which yields:
[Mathmatical Expression Omitted] (4)
The index of sustainability is then given by (tx*-tx), i.e. the
difference between the sustainable and the current tax rate; it is
simply the size of the adjustment required for the ratio of debt to GDP
eventually to return to its initial level. This condition will hold as
long as the ratio converges to any constant, not necessarily [b.sub.o.]
Blanchard then goes on to consider three different time horizons,
respectively one, five and forty years,. and calculates short-, medium-
and long-term gaps. The short-term indicator does not require forecasts,
and can be constructed using the available data on government finances.
The five-year horizon is the appropriate one to take into account
cyclical factors which affect the general government financial balances.
It requires projections of spending and transfers, and hence it is only
as good as the forecasts on which it is based. Finally, to construct the
long-term indicator the share of government spending in GDP is adjusted
to take into account changes in the age structure of the population and
their effects on social security and public health spending. The
underlying rough assumption is that spending grows in line with
variations in the old-age dependency ratio.
All these indices, however, are derived on the assumption that the
difference between the interest rate and the growth rate is positive(4).
From (2), it is clear that public debt as a percentage of GDP could grow
without bounds if the growth rate of GDP were higher than the real
interest rate. This case, known as 'dynamic inefficiency'(5)
in the literature, can not be ruled out a priori, as in the 1970s the
growth rate was above real interest rates, and even in the 1980s, when
interest rates were rather high, the difference between the two was of
the order of 1 per cent. However, there is a general consensus that in
the medium and long run interest rates exceed the growth rate of GDP.
The EC Commission, in its report 'One market, one money',
takes the view that debt/GDP ratios above 100 per cent should definitely
be stabilised, since debt stabilisation at such a level already requires
tax receipts equivalent to 9 per cent of GDP. It is convenient,
therefore, to distinguish between a 'weak' solvency condition,
given by (3), and a 'practical (or strict)' condition which
assumes that only some fixed level of debt/GDP ratio is feasible (for
this distinction, see Buiter and Patel, 1992). To satisfy this
condition, fiscal discipline is required from individual governments,
ruling out some debt/deficit trajectories.
We have shown that, in a dynamically efficient economy, public debt
as a percentage of GDP can not grow indefinitely if the government
intertemporal budget constraint is to be satisfied. Hence a testable
implication of the theory sketched above is that, depending on which
solvency condition is to be met, either discounted debt or the debt/GDP
ratio should be a stationary series (see Hamilton and Flavin, 1986, and
Wilcox, 1989). Therefore, in order to investigate the potential solvency
of governments and evaluate the fiscal picture in the EC countries, we
use some stationarity tests recently developed by Phillips and Perron (1988). Their Z statistics permit tests of joint hypotheses and are
valid under very general assumptions about the process generating the
errors. The testing sequence is the following. We first test for the
presence of unit roots, and then for a positive drift or time trend. The
presence of either a stochastic or a deterministic trend implies that if
the present stance of fiscal policy remained the same in the future
insolvency would follow. Solvency then requires a change either in
policy or in some structural features of the economy directly impinging
on the evolution of public deficits.
The statistical evidence161 appears to be broadly consistent with
the conclusions reached by the EC Commission in various studies on the
compatibility of budgetary policies in the individual countries with the
requirements of EMU, even though such studies take a less rigorous
approach, being based on inspection of general trends in public
finances. Our results are reported in table 2, which shows whether or
not the past behaviour of discounted debt and debt/GDP ratios is
consistent with sustainability. A country is deemed to be on a
sustainable path if the Z tests indicate that both the unit root
hypothesis and the presence of a deterministic trend or positive drift
can be rejected. Not all the seven countries being considered satisfy
the intertemporal budget constraint. Solvency is not an issue at all in
the UK and France. In both countries macroeconomic policy was radically
different in the 1980s. In the UK expansionary fiscal policy was
abandoned and inflation kept under control by devising a Medium Term
Financial Strategy (MTFS). The public sector borrowing requirement moved
from a deficit to a surplus, and was renamed public sector debt
repayment (PSDR). In France the 'Mitterand experiment' was
followed by the adoption of a much tighter fiscal and monetary stance.
In 1982 wages and prices were frozen and exchange controls became more
stringent. In Germany only the 'weak' condition is satisfied,
probably reflecting the budgetary impact of German unification. Ireland
also appears to be on a non-explosive path. There the adjustment process
started in 1982 under the new Fine Gael-led government, and was based on
a strong commitment to a stable exchange rate within the ERM. The
countries most in need of fiscal adjustment are Italy, Belgium and the
Netherlands. The Italian case is probably the most worrying, because the
structure of its political system is such that the necessary reforms,
e.g. the overdue overhaul of public pension schemes, are difficult to
implement. Even the celebrated 'divorce' between the Bank of
Italy and the Treasury, which since the second half of 19 81 has put an
end to the obligation for the Central Bank to buy government debt not
purchased by the private sector, does not seem to have affected budget
dynamics significantly. As noted above, Belgium and the Netherlands have
tackled the debt problem more decisively, but fiscal discipline remains
an issue there. In the former, an austerity package improving its fiscal
position, a devaluation of the Belgian Franc, the introduction of income
policies, and the suspension of the widespread indexation provisions was
adopted in the early 1980s by the centre-right coalition, but with
limited success. In the latter, the devaluation option was not used, the
Dutch Guilder being anchored to the D-Mark, and the attempted reduction
of the public sector deficit took the form of cuts in expenditure, but
again was not incisive enough.
On the whole, it appears that, as regards government balances, some
progress has been made towards convergence, as is necessary for a
monetary union to be sustainable once it has been formed. However,
corrective fiscal action is still required in some countries for them to
be allowed to join EMU under the conditions set out in the Maastricht
Treaty. The EC's adoption of quantitative criteria to determine the
admission to EMU should be seen as a spur towards achieving better
balanced public finances. The underlying issue is one of sustainability
and we have shown that this requires changes in the conduct of fiscal
policy in several member states. If there is evidence that such a change
is under way, and that governments are trying to stabilise debt relative
to GDP, this would be very encouraging in assessing their commitment to
a low inflation union.
REFERENCES
Anderton, R, Barrell R and in't Veld JW (1991 ),
'Macroeconomic convergence in Europe', National Institute
Economic Review, no. 13 8, November.
Bayoumi, T and Masson, PR (1992), 'Fiscal flows in the United
States and Canada: lessons for Monetary Union in Europe', paper
presented at the SPES Conference on 'Macroeconomic Policy
Coordination in Europe: the ERM and Monetary Union', Warwick
University, March 1992.
Blanchard, OJ (1990), 'Suggestions for a new set of fiscal
indicators', OECD/DES Working Paper no.79.
Buiter, WH and Patel, UR (1992), 'Debt, deficits, and
inflation: an application to the public finances of India', Journal
of Public Economics, 47, 171-205.
Canzoneri, MB and Diba, BT (1991), 'Fiscal deficits, financial
integration and a Central Bank for Europe', Journal o f the
Japanese and International Economies, 5, 381-403.
Caporale, GM (1992), 'Debt sustainability and monetary
union', National Institute of Economic and Social Research, mimeo.
Commission of the European Communities (1990), 'One market,
one money: an evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming
an economic and monetary union', European Economy, 44, October.
Commission of the European Communities (1991), 'Budgetary
policies in the Community: developments and perspectives with a view to
fiscal discipline', European Economy, 50, 161-176.
Currie, D and Levine, P (1991), 'The solvency constraint and
fiscal policy in an open economy', in 'External constraints on
macroeconomic policy. The European experience', G Alogoskoufis, L
Papademos and R Portes eds., Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Delors, Jet al (1989), 'Report on Economic and Monetary Union
in the European Community', Committee for the Study of Economic and
Monetary Union.
European Council of Maastricht (1991), 'Amendments to the EEC treaty-- Economic and Monetary Union'.
Frankel, J and Razin, A (1987), 'The Mundell-Fleming model: a
quarter of a century later', IMF Staff Papers, 34, 4.
Hamilton, JD and Flavin, MA (1986), 'On the limitations of
government borrowing: a framework for empirical testing', American
Economic Review, 76, 4, 808-819.
Oxley, H and Martin, JP (1991), 'Controlling government
spending and deficits: trends in the 1980s and prospects for the
1990s', OECD Economic Studies, no. 17.
Padoa-Schioppa, T (1990), 'Fiscal prerequisites of a European
monetary union', Conference on Aspects of Central Bank
Policymaking, organized by the Bank of Israel and the David Horowitz Institute, Tel Aviv, January.
Phillips, PCB and Perron, P (1988), 'Testing for a unit root
in time series regression', Biometrika, 75, 2, 335-346.
Sachs, J and Sala-i-Martin, X (1991), 'Fiscal policies and
optimum currency areas: evidence from Europe and the United
States', Economic Growth Centre, Yale University, Discussion Paper
no. 638.
Sargent, T and Wallace, N (1981), 'Some unpleasant monetarist arithmetic', Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review,
5, 1-17.
Wilcox, DW (1989), 'The sustainability of government deficits:
implications of the present-value borrowing constraint',Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, 21, 3,291-306.
NOTES
(1) For a theoretical model analysing the implications for fiscal
policy oi economic and monetary union see Canzoneri and Diba, 1991. They
find that discipline can be imposed upon the national governments only
ii the European Central Bank is run by a monetary policy rule; in any
other scenario, individual governments would be able to exert pressure
on the Central Bank, causing more inflation.
(2) Note also that, as a result oi the move to EMU and the
elimination of risk premia, differentials between real rates of return
on government bonds will narrow. Consequently, there will be a
redistribution of income from countries with low public borrowing to
highly indebted countries, where the cost of servicing the debt will
decrease and holders of long maturity fixed
interest bonds will make capital gains. This could cause serious
political frictions among the member states. (3) Or/or discounted debt;
see below for a definition of the two solvency criteria.
(4) On this point, see the discussion in Currie and Levine, 1991.
(5) In such an economy the capital stock exceeds the so-called
golden rule level, which maximises steady state consumption per capita,
and hence the allocation of resources is not Pareto optimal.
(6) For further details see Caporale, 1992.