Economic reform in Russia.
Oppenheimer, Peter M.
Little of what has been visibly happening in the former Soviet
economy over the past two years reflects the intentions of its
policymakers. Central planning has been abrogated and many prices freed,
but the Russian authorities are struggling to establish financial
stability and to create the legal and institutional framework for
extensive privatisation of large enterprises. National output has fallen
sharply (as elsewhere in Eastern Europe), because the disciplines and
incentives of central planning have been removed, while those of the
market are not yet in existence. The economy has been kept going at a
lower level with the help of a much expanded barter network among
enterprises. Prospects for avoiding economic collapse and anarchy are
reasonably good, but a fully-fledged market economy remains a long way
off.
The advent of the Yeltsin government in Russia in the aftermath of
the failed conservative coup of August 1991 and subsequent dismantling
of the Soviet Union marked a certain watershed in efforts towards
economic reform as well as in the purely political domain. Mr
Yeltsin's team of economic ministers headed by Yegor Gaidar has
made no bones about seeking to accelerate the introduction of market
mechanisms across the economy, and has been vigorous in its
confrontation of parliamentary and other critics. In important areas,
words (or plans on paper) have given way to deeds. Most retail price
controls have been removed, especially on foodstuffs. Motor fuel prices
have been adjusted to more realistic levels. New elements of taxation
have been introduced as part of an effort to bring the fiscal and
monetary situation under better control and to strengthen the ruble both
internally and externally. Recent months have also seen advances in
privatisation, notably the first auctions (in the city of
Nizhny-Novgorod) of state-owned small enterprises to private buyers.
While the economic landscape as well as the political has thus
altered radically in the past twelve months, one must beware of
exaggerating both the discontinuities and the accomplishments. Leaving
aside specific precedents such as the large price increases introduced
in the first half of 1991 (which itself recalled the monetary reform of
1947 - see Kaser (1963)), it is a fact that the erosion of centralised
state planning and control of production - the first phase of strategic
change on the road to market - had mostly occurred before the August
1991 coup. And while this was mainly a negative achievement, it stands
out as the only clear-cut achievement so far.
The position at present is that the disciplines and incentives of
the command economy have been removed, but have not yet been replaced by
those of the market. Such replacement requires far more extensive
privatisation of property than has so far been accomplished. Until this
happens, managers of large business units, whether industrial or
agricultural, have no clearly defined objectives. Under the old regime,
when all large enterprises belonged to the state, managers were charged
with obeying instructions and fulfilling (or over-fulfilling) production
targets. For the time being ownership is now in limbo and systematic
government instructions - and supplies - are no longer forthcoming.
Until productive assets are privatised and the new owners can make their
wishes felt, managers have no clear incentive to keep capital intact, to
earn a reasonable level of profits or indeed do anything beyond helping
to meet the day-to-day needs and requests of their workforce, and
otherwise defending their own management position and perquisites.
The disappearance of motivational guidelines for the organisation
of production is the universal factor which accounts for the big fall in
output experienced by all the former Communist countries of central and
eastern Europe. The decline may in particular instances be aggravated by
country-specific factors, such as the 1990 financial stabilisation
programme in Poland or the abrupt exposure of East Germany to West
German markets after re-unification. In the former Soviet Union
political fragmentation has played an important role. One may ask in
this light why the falls in output have not been still larger. Wholesale
collapse into anarchy and starvation has at times been feared both by
economists with a deep knowledge of the former communist countries (see
for example Nove 1991, Addendum) and by economists prodigal with advice
on how to put a market system in place (two categories with limited
overlap). A fully satisfactory answer to the conundrum is not possible.
What one can say for Russia and the CIS is that the network of interfirm
barter has been a key part of the institutional mechanics that have kept
the economy running, as it were, on air in its current transitional
state.
The remainder of this article falls into three sections. The first
sketches the main features of the reform process and of economic
developments up to 1992. The middle section outlines some key aspects of
the way in which the Russian economy has recently been operating, and
the final section looks at current problems and prospects, including the
possible contribution of assistance from Western governments and
enterprises. The discussion focuses mainly on Russia. Some other former
republics of the USSR are mentioned incidentally.
The abrogation of central planning
For the first two or three years after Mr Gorbachev's
appointment as Communist Party General Secretary in 1985 there was no
attempt to reform the then Soviet economic system in a fundamental
manner. Rather, the authorities (not unlike some of their predecessors)
sought improved performance from traditional structures by heightening
people's sense of participation and responsibility through
political liberalisation (glasnost), emphasis on quality control and the
drive against alcohol. Efforts were also made to increase fixed
investment, which was reported as declining by more than 1 per cent a
year in the first half of the decade.
Results were limited. The rate of decline of investment apparently
slowed somewhat, but total output growth showed no improvement - and is
in any case believed to have been overstated as a result of the
underestimation of price increases in Soviet statistical methodology.
The anti-alcohol campaign illustrated vividly the erratic nature of
policy and its impacts. Besides generating ill-will towards the
administration, it reduced fiscal revenues and led to widespread
destruction of established vineyards in southern areas of the country, a
piece of vandalism quite irrelevant to the availability of vodka which
provided the main form of excessive drinking.
Prospects were worsened by the 40 per cent drop in world oil prices
in 1986, which meant a cut of some 20 per cent in hard-currency export
receipts. The Soviet authorities responded in traditional conservative
fashion by reducing imports, thereby further handicapping efforts to
revive industrial investment. The export decline also lowered tax
revenues, contributing to a sharp increase in the fiscal deficit from
2-5 per cent of GDP in 1985 to 8.5 per cent in 1987. Any widening of the
fiscal deficit implies faster growth of the broad money stock since the
Russian economic system still lacks any other means of financing
government deficits (such as, for instance, the issue of government
bonds to pension funds or insurance companies). On the other hand, as is
emphasised below, there has not been a close linkage between monetary
aggregates and total expenditure.
In 1987-88 serious reform moves were initiated. The 1987 Law on
State Enterprises led to the replacement of the old Gosplan system of
output determination by the marginally more flexible system of state
orders (goszakazy). The Russian word means orders in the sense of order
books, not in the sense of instructions. The system involved compulsory
purchases by state authorities of specified quantities at officially
controlled prices, either for direct use (e.g. in defence) or for
re-sale to other establishments (usually through the state supply system
- Gossnab) in the case of machinery or intermediate products. State
orders typically absorbed 85-95 per cent of the output of large
enterprises. The remaining 5-15 per cent represented a margin of
manoeuvre for participating in market activities, in practice mostly
barter. Managers' aspirations to increase the freely disposable
output of their plants were curbed by the fact that the state system
furnished scarce inputs in amounts sufficient only for the fulfilment of
state orders.
Piecemeal easing of state control also occurred in pricing
(enterprises being permitted from 1988 onwards to negotiate contract
[dogovorniye] prices for a limited range of |new' products) and in
foreign trade (where any enterprise willing to register was authorised
to engage in trade, and experiments were conducted with foreign exchange
auctions and retention schemes. A large fraction (50 per cent or more)
of enterprises' foreign-exchange transactions continued, however,
to be directed through official channels, and there was a reversion to
differentiated exchange coefficients prescribed by the central
authorities, a central planner's form of multiple exchange rates.
Nove (1991, p. 86) points out that the partial loosening of
controls over enterprise behaviour unmatched by any tightening of
financial constraints encouraged both a sizable increase in money wages
and the initiation of an excessive number of enterprise-financed
investment projects which could not be brought to completion and which
thus merely aggravated shortages and resource misuse.
From 1987 onwards the government also pursued a programme of
|converting' military industrial production to civilian. The
potential importance of this cannot be overstated, since a huge
proportion of Soviet manufacturing had been devoted to defence or
quasi-defence (e.g. space research). At a guess, the proportion was
two-thirds for heavy industry and at least 40 per cent for Soviet
manufacturing as a whole. Concern about the burden of the arms race, and
about the impossibility of maintaining let alone increasing Soviet
living standards while retaining strategic parity with the United
States, was after all a key factor behind perestroika, antedating
Gorbachev. By the end of 1990 it was claimed that civilian goods
accounted for half the total output of defence enterprises. This
included a very high proportion of the country's output of
household durables such as refrigerators, washing machines, vacuum
cleaners, TV sets, and so on (Pockney, 1991, p.25). There was a major
question, however, about the amount of actual conversion as opposed to
diversification of output that was actually going on (Erickson, 1992).
Producers of high-technology defence equipment were understandably
reluctant to jettison existing expertise and lines of development.
Ballistic missile experts found it hard to be enthusiastic about turning
their hands to shower heads and mixer taps instead (an actual example
from Perm in the Urals). Managers therefore tended to seek additional
capital allocations in order to establish civilian goods production
alongside whatever they were otherwise turning out. Excessive capacity
in the defence sector was thus preserved.
More promising in principle was the encouragement given to the
development of private business by the 1988 Law on Co-operatives. These
were enterprises owned jointly by their staff, with the size of
individual shareholdings or proprietary rights subject to proportional
limitations. Some limitations of this kind continue to be enforced, even
though there is now more encouragement to simple one-person
proprietorship. By the autumn of 1990 it was estimated that over 200,000
non-agricultural co-operatives had been set up, employing more than 5
million people - between 3 and 4 per cent of the USSR labour force.
Here too qualifications are necessary. First, private ownership was
not extended to significant capital assets. Land, buildings and
machinery have had to be rented at arbitary prices from state
authorities. Secondly, the new enterprises have been subject to
capricious increases in tax rates determined partly by finance ministry
and partly by local government (ispolkom) decisions. In one way this
simply represents a carry-forward of a familiar feature of the old-style
command economy. High enterprise profits were always liable to be taxed
away, to help pay for subsidies to loss-making establishments under the
system of |soft' budget constraints (Kornai, 1992). In a market
context, however, such arbitrary and ad hoc tax adjustments (motivated
in part by resentment at individuals' commercial success) have
highly negative incentive effects. At best, they promote displacement of
activities to the black economy. At worst, they throttle private
enterprise altogether.
Thirdly, some of the co-operatives - how many is impossible to
estimate - are phoney, in that they consist of departments or sub-units
of large industrial establishments, with no genuine independence or
scope for commercial initiative outside the establishment of which they
are part. Such re-packaging of existing structures is a typical response
by old style managers or former party functionaries seeking to safeguard
their position and avoid substantive institutional change. Moreover,
even private enterprises that begin as genuinely independent concerns
are liable to be propelled by the difficulty of obtaining supplies into
partnership arrangements with powerful state enterprises, which on their
side employ private firms as a vehicle to safeguard or enhance
managerial remuneration and status in a more or less corrupt manner
(Glaziev, 1991).
A further aspect of the shift from central planning after 1988 was
a transfer of authority in economic matters away from all-union
ministries in Moscow to the separate republics, who were called upon to
strengthen links between their own finances and the operation of
enterprises located in their territory. As Nove (1991, p. 86) points
out, this move to so-called republican profit and loss accounting
reflected the mistaken notion that any weakening of central government
in the economic sphere would contribute to marketisation. In reality,
this change mainly served to encourage national separatism.
As the old command system began to unravel, all semblance of
economic growth disappeared, and during 1989 total output in the Soviet
Union entered on a declining trend which continued for the following
three years. Undue importance should not be attached to precise figures,
which arguably convey an exaggerated impression of the decline. Output
of |non-material' services omitted from the Marxist concept of net
material produce (NMP) has been increasing, and now absorbs almost
one-quarter of the Russian civilian labour force compared with 21.4 per
cent in 1980. Part of the fall in industrial output was in defence items
which make no direct contribution to economic well-being (and were
evidently not exportable). More generally, the absence of a rational
pricing system makes any aggregate output valuation open to dispute. For
what they are worth, year-on-year statistics (Table 1) show NMP in the
Russian Federation declining in real terms by 3-6 per cent in 1990 and
by 11 per cent in 1991. The first quarter of 1992 saw a further
year-on-year fall estimated at 14 per cent. Thus the decline in 1992 as
a whole seems likely to match that of 1991. Industrial output fell less
than agricultural in 1990 but considerably more in 1991-2. Fragmentary
data on other territories of the former USSR (Ukraine, Belarus, Moldova,
the Baltic states) point to output falls at least equal to those in
Russia. Falling output has not been accompanied by closure of any
state-owned enterprises, and open unemployment has shown in absolute
terms only a very modest increase, though proportionally large - in
Russia from 16,000 registered unemployed in mid-1991 to nearly 70,000 at
the beginning of 1992.
Table 1. Russian Federation: growth rates
(in comparable prices; percentages, year-on-year)
1989 1990 1991 1992(*)
Net material
product 1.9 -3.6 -11.0 -14.0
Industry 2.0 -2.2 -8.0 -13.0
Agriculture 2.8 -6.2 -4.7 N/A
Investment -6.1 -22.5 -11.0 -44.0
Consumption 5.4 2.0 N/A N/A
(*) First quarter compared with first quarter 1991.
The accelerated loss of industrial output was partly a result of
disruption caused by political and ethnic conflicts. This applies
especially in the Baltic states, Moldova, the southern republics of
Georgia, Armenia and Azerbaijan and sub-regions of Russia such as
Chechen-Ingushetia. The importance of such conflicts stems from the
structure of the country's industries, notably the preponderance of
large firms and the lack of alternative suppliers. Nearly three-quarters
of the former Soviet Union's 47,000 industrial establishments have
over 1,000 employees, compared with 25 per cent in the United States(1),
and a sizeable fraction of industrial output consists of items for which
there is only one supplier. Thus, to take only the most important single
example, disruption in the production of oil drilling and maintenance
equipment in Azerbaijan made a decline in oil production in western
Siberia impossible to avoid.
Soviet oil production peaked in 1987-88 at some 620 million tons
per year. Since then it has fallen, reportedly to about 515 million tons
in 1991, and a projected 470 million in 1992, a figure more than 25 per
cent below the peak. The Russian Federation accounts for almost 90 per
cent of these totals. The declining output figures are closely
parallelled by reported export totals, which came down from over 180
million tons in 1988 to barely 90 million in 1991. The decline is almost
certainly overstated, as oil-producing enterprises have contrived to
conceal a modest but increasing proportion of both production and export
earnings from the foreign-trade Ministry and Central Bank. The scope for
such activity was increased in 1991, when remaining trade between former
Comecon countries was put officially on to a world-market basis, i.e.
with prices at international levels in convertible currency. Like
smuggling and capital flight in western countries, such unauthorised
retention of foreign exchange earnings by particular exporters or
exporting organisations worsened the official balance-of-payments
picture.
The Soviet authorities in 1990 and early 1991 once again responded
to shortfalls of export revenue by drastically cutting import
authorisations. The import bill in dollars fell by some 45 per cent in
1991, against a 30 per cent fall in recorded exports. While this
involved cancellation of investment plans and aggravated the decline in
national output, the current-account deficit was all but eliminated, and
net inflows of medium- and long-term capital were sufficient to finance
a modest reduction in the country's short-term indebtedness. (Table
2). Even so, this still left external debts of the former USSR totalling
around $55 billion,(2) some 80 per cent above the total outstanding at
the end of 1987. The Russian government has provisionally assumed
responsibility for the whole of this foreign debt, pending an agreed
settlement or division. In the first quarter of 1992 import values
recovered sharply (by 15 per cent year-on-year) but exports declined
further, so the current balance of payments swung back into sizable
deficit.
Table 2. USSR territory balance of payments 1990-1
(US $ billion)
1990 1991
1. Merchandise exports 103.8 70.2
of which:
oil 27.1 11.1
natural gas 11.1 11.8
other 65.6 47.3
2. Merchandise imports -120.7 -68.2
3. Invisibles, net -6.6 -7.8
of which:
interest payments,
net -3.5 -3.8
4. Gold sales (excluding
swaps) 2.5 3.4
5. Current account
(=1+2+3+4) -21.0 -2.4
6. Capital account, net 2.3 5.3
(including errors and
omissions)
7. Overall balance (5+6) -18.7 2.9
The decline in national output was accompanied by further
deterioration in the budgetary and monetary situation. The Soviet
government budget deficit widened again in 1988-90 to around 10 per cent
of GNP, as fiscal receipts lagged behind rising outlays on consumer
subsidies, which swamped any cuts in defence expenditures. The deficit
continued to be financed with bank credit, increasing the money stock by
some 15 per cent a year - this with output on a downward trend and the
official price index rising by 5 per cent a year.
As a deflator for calculating the real purchasing power of money
incomes the official price index was increasingly useless, as more and
more goods became less and less available at official prices. At the
same time, consumers were disinclined to engage in a wholehearted scramble for goods on free markets. For many items these markets were
still illegal; search costs were often high (e.g. travelling 30 miles or
more in quest of car parts on the basis of hearsay or vague assurances)
and vendors would often want other goods in exchange rather than cash.
In addition, fear of possible unemployment and general uncertainty may
have strengthened the wish to cling even to depreciating precautionary
balances.
The net result was a growing monetary |overhang', i.e. an
abnormal and ultimately unsustainable rise in the ratio of cash balances
to income. By the end of 1990 the overhang was estimated at 250 billion
rubles (about one-third of the stock of financial assets) for households
and enterprises combined, with two-thirds of it comprising
households' cash and bank deposits. A two-pronged assault on the
overhang was mounted by Finance Minister Pavlov early in 1991. First,
high-denomination banknotes (at that time 50 and 100 rubles) were
declared no longer legal tender; and a sizeable fraction of household
savings deposits was blocked. Then, a few weeks later official prices of
basic foodstuffs and certain other essentials were raised by up to 200
per cent. Success was very short-lived. Attempts to ration the exchange
of cancelled 50-ruble notes into smaller denominations proved
unenforceable, and money wages were soon raised to compensate for the
price increases. Payment of higher salaries into partially blocked
savings accounts provided no more than a temporary mode of non-monetary
finance for the government deficit. Above all, the deficit itself, the
root of the problem, continued unabated and indeed widened to something
nearer 20 per cent of GNP in 1991 as the general economic and political
situation deteriorated.
Some domestic prices, notably of air and rail transport, were
heavily increased in the summer of 1991 from the absurdly low levels
previously charged, but most official prices were held steady until the
end of the year. On the other hand, shortages in the shops were
aggravated, as goods were increasingly withheld for diversion into
unofficial markets and the barter network. And the free exchange rate at
which foreign currency was transacted for certain purposes (for example,
tourists' cash outlays) shot up by a factor of five, to about 100
rubles to the dollar, in the fourth quarter of 1991.
On balance the monetary overhang continued to expand, and at the
end of 1991 the new Russian government decided to cut subsidies and to
permit a corresponding fivefold increase in prices of numerous goods and
services, excluding, for the time being, only certain basic foodstuffs
(vodka among them), fuel and housing. Petrol prices and remaining food
prices were similarly raised in April/May 1992. Money wages and other
incomes were also substantially increased, but not enough to give full
compensation. Pensioners were particularly hard hit.
The freeing of many prices was accompanied by a corresponding
shrinkage of the system of State orders. Although there is a dearth of
official statements and the present position is somewhat obscure, it
would appear that goszakazy remain an important mechanism in the major
sectors of agriculture, energy and defence, but are now of slight
significance elsewhere.
The need for a drastic narrowing of the budget deficit was
emphasised - by the International Monetary Fund as well as the Russian
authorities themselves. Besides cutting subsidies and enforcing a
measure of restraint on money incomes, the government introduced new
taxes: a value-added tax from the beginning of 1992 (at a rate of 28 per
cent) and a system of oil and gas taxes, on both domestic consumption
and exports, a few months later. These taxes represent a substantial
step towards western-style fiscal systems and away from dependence for
fiscal receipts on enterprise profits (whether state-owned or private).
Oil and gas taxes also constitute a revenue source payable to the
Russian exchequer by other component states of the former USSR. In
principle these new instruments are capable of making a major
contribution to eliminating the excessive budget deficit in the Russian
federation, and initial results in the spring of 1992 were encouraging.
VAT collections in the first (Jan-Mar) quarter came to 100 billion
rubles, equal to more than 20 per cent of total budgetary outlay. The
budget deficit for the quarter came to a mere Rbls 25 billion (1 1/2 per
cent of GNP).
Subsequently, however, parliamentary opposition to the economic
reform programme, including the enforcement of financial discipline,
strengthened, reflecting a mixture of genuine popular discontent and
opportunistic behaviour by former Communists endeavouring to retain or
regain positions of influence under a variety of political labels. In
mid-July parliament voted to reduce the general rate of VAT to 20 per
cent from 1 January 1993, and to 15 per cent immediately on certain
essentials, mainly basic foods. Massive upward amendments to the
government's expenditure proposals were also voted. Although the
government warned that other taxes would have to rise, the threat lacked
credibility, both because of the need to obtain parliamentary support
and because adequate machinery for extensive alternative tax collection,
notably personal income tax, does not yet exist. The likely result is
that the budget deficit will revert to the region of 15-20 per cent of
GNP (annual rate of Rbls. 1,000 billion), instead of coming down to 5 or
6 per cent as the government had pledged to the IMF.
At the same time parliament and the government accepted the
resignation (mooted at earlier junctures) of Mr. Georgy Matyukhin as
head of the Russian Central Bank. His replacement by Mr. Victor
Gerashchenko, former chairman of the Gosbank (the central bank of the
USSR) was likewise seen as confirming earlier moves to ease somewhat the
attempted credit squeeze on industry.
Transition and the barter network
In theory one might expect a close connection between the
dismantling of Russia's state planning apparatus and reform of the
pricing system. Both are steps towards establishment of a market
economy. Prices are meant to become guidelines for producers as well as
consumers, replacing the quantitative commands previously emanating from
the central planning authorities. But prices can perform this function
only in the presence of well-defined managerial objectives - profit
maximisation, sales maximisation or whatever - and clearly enforced
constraints both on access to finance and on exploitable market power.
These conditions are far from being fulfilled in the State-owned sector
which still constitutes the overwhelming bulk of Russia's
productive apparatus; and it is widely accepted - although not logically
demonstrable - that they will in practice not come to be fulfilled
without extensive transfer of ownership of productive assets into
private hands. Be that as it may, price reform has for the time being
had little effect on managers' response to the demise of central
planning. How, then, has the economy operated?
The decline in output of the past three years and the disruption of
even the erratic and unreliable distribution systems which existed
before has led to a massive enlargement of inter-firm networks for both
barter trading and cross-firm investments linked to subsequent
deliveries of goods. For example, mining enterprises and engineering
firms have purchased equipment or greenhouses for collective farms
(sometimes nearby, sometimes hundreds or even thousands of miles away)
in order to secure supplies of particular foodstuffs for their own
employees.
What is new is not the concept of the barter system but its extent.
There has always been a need for informal producer networks inside the
country, supplementing official organisations such as the now defunct
state supply agency (Gossnab) in enabling firms to acquire the materials
and equipment needed for the fulfilment of production targets. As part
of these networks firms have been accustomed to holding excessive
inventories of anything storable, in order to maximise their prospects
of obtaining necessary supplies by barter when needed. (Analogously,
households have habitually kept inventories of consumables, because of
the unreliability of supply.)
The range of items traded through barter networks has now been
greatly extended, covering not only raw materials, semi-manufactures,
machinery and spare parts but also consumer goods for employees. A
textile plant, for example, may persuade its staff to work overtime only
by offering them the chance to purchase washing machines, obtained by
bartering the firm's output. The machines themselves, in this
example, are imported. For western trading partners barter deals have
always been a feature of east-west trade, handled in western countries
by specialised agencies. The difference now is that western
organisations are liable to deal directly with a Russian enterprise and
not or not habitually) through ministry channels in Moscow. Trade
between Russia and former Comecon countries has been conducted on the
same basis, since the former clearing arrangements ceased to operate in
1990.
In short, it is the inter-firm barter network - coupled with a
widespread instinct for self-preservation on the part of managers and
employees alike - that has for the time being replaced central direction
in the organisation of production. Two additional factors have also
encouraged the process. One, applying both to large enterprises and to
the non-agricultural private business (|co-operative') sector whose
emergence was noted above, is the nature of financial regulation. Firms
complain that success in establishing new export markets has in the past
been rewarded with quasi-confiscatory foreign-exchange and tax
regulations which removed up to 80 per cent of hard-currency earnings
from the control of the enterprise, mostly at unfavourable exchange
rates. Reported alleviations of these rules were quite frequent(3), but
were ad hoc and unpredictable. A general alleviation was, however,
introduced in June/July 1992, with the abrogation of |official'
exchange rates and the application of a uniform market rate to foreign
exchange surrender requirements.
Ruble profits from domestic business are, however, likewise subject
to arbitrary increases in the tax rate. This is a matter partly of
Finance Ministry and partly of local government decision. For example,
the local authority rules on whether social expenditure by a
co-operative enterprise does or does not entitle the enterprise to
alleviation of profits tax (which is also an obvious source of
corruption). Recourse to barter can diminish recorded profits and hence
vulnerability to these various regulations.
The other factor is the social responsibility falling on large
enterprises in particular - again a familiar feature of the Communist
system in its heyday, but intensified in the transitional circumstances
of the present. Absence of a proper fiscal system and especially the
lack of adequate budgets for regional and sub-regional governments means
that basic social facilities such as housing, hospitals, creches and
leisure amenities have had to be organised and constructed by
enterprises. This, besides representing a diversion of managerial time
and effort from the task of running the enterprise itself, widens the
range of expertise and products which the enterprise needs to buy in,
thus again reinforcing the incentive to barter wher such items are in
short supply.
In the past informal barter relations were organised or facilitated
by |fixers' (tolkachi). These persons were normally on an
establishment payroll and indeed originated as a type of purchasing
agent whose job was to make up for deficiencies in the quantity, quality
or detailed composition of inputs (e.g. sizes of screws) supplied
through official channels. Their status was always ambiguous. They were
tolerated in practice because they were necessary to the achievement of
industry's production targets, even though in principle their
activities represented an abuse. Direct contacts between firms were
supposed to be discouraged, lest they undermine the completeness and
effectiveness of central control. And, of course, where a fixer's
activity developed into a conspicuous source of personal wealth or
influence, he risked criminal prosecution for |speculation'. In
to-day's very different circumstances not only have firms built up
their direct network of contacts (albeit still hampered by patchy
telecommunications), but official bodies such as the regional offices of
the former Gosplan - renamed the Ministry of Economics and Forecasting -
themselves act as intermediaries and information channels between firms.
Not surprisingly there have been calls for the release of people - up to
127,000 of them - still serving prison sentences for |economic
crimes' committed under the Soviet regime.(4)
Probably more important than the intermediary activities of
ministries are the widely publicised commodity exchanges that have been
set up in many Russian cities with direct telephone and other links
between them. These are not primary commodity markets as observed in
London, New York or Chicago. Rather, they are elaborate brokerage
institutions to facilitate direct and indirect bartering of all sorts of
products between firms, mostly in quite small quantities and sub-divided
into various qualities, sizes, etc. The defence industries have
participated actively. A Military-Industrial Exchange was established in
1991 as an offshoot of the Russian Commodities and Raw Materials
Exchange in Moscow, and the military also has at least one brokerage
firm of its own, called Oborona (Defence) (Erickson, 1992, pp. 11-12).
The enlargement of inter-firm relations and barter is of course
part of an improvised reaction to shortages and disruptions and not a
considered strategy of economic reform. It is welcome in that it
involves the bulk of the business sector - not merely enthusiasts for
marketisation but also the more reluctant managers, for instance in
parts of the military-industrial complex - learning to conduct its own
deals and production arrangements in detail and to abandon reliance on
the old channels of ministerial direction and ministerial privilege
guaranteeing orders and correct materials to favoured producers.
Further possible benefits can be specified. Opportunities for
indirect barter should encourage a more sophisticated approach to
inventory management. To the extent that barter networks succeed in
easing supply bottlenecks for Russian enterprises, they may do something
to cure factory managers of their penchant for autarky. Unlike western
firms, Soviet factories have not normally been able to choose amongst
competing suppliers for their inputs, and have therefore had no leverage
against unreliable deliveries, poor quality or wrong sizes and types.
Tolkachi might engage in ad hoc searches for particular components, but
in the end the only general backstop remedy has been to improvise and
|make it onself'. The result has been excessive diversification of
output and small-scale production of semi-finished items and components.
In other words, inside the huge enterprises that characterise the
Russian economy is a great deal of inefficient small-scale output which
needs to be eliminated through the development of competing suppliers.
Until this comes about, the barter network can serve as a makeshift
device for keeping industrial production going.
In other respects, however, the inter-business network is
retrograde, representing a retreat both from money as a means of
exchange and from an efficient division of labour. Not surprisingly,
therefore, it has been unable to compensate fully for the dislocations
caused by removal of the old channels of command, clumsy, rigid and
incomplete though they were. Besides the shrinkage of industrial and
agricultural production, wholesale and retail distribution in particular
has been shifted into everybody's workplace, while many shops are
empty. Apart from the special hardship thus caused to retired persons,
it is no less absurd for a textile manufacturer to spend time searching
out washing machines than it is for the manager of a petrochemical plant
to be directing hospital or apartment construction. The uncertain
availability of consumer goods also adds to negative effects on work
incentives.
As it happens, the retreat from money has brought the incidental
benefit of helping to fend off, at least temporarily, the threat of
uncontrolled inflation inherent in the shortage of goods and the
overhang of purchasing power. There has been little tendency for money
to chase after goods, because the prospects of acquiring goods by this
route are seen as unreliable: better to use employer networks, personal
contacts, brokering services and so forth. Commodity exchanges among
households have also greatly expanded. In the past year the established
second-hand goods (kommissioniy) shops have been overshadowed by mass
street markets in which householders sell and buy all sorts of
miscellaneous items from knitted socks to bottles of vodka. A comparison
with car-boot sales in Britain suggests itself (with the proportion of
stolen goods probably lower in Russia). In short, unorthodox
transactions mechanisms have functioned in the ex-Soviet economy as a
partial barrier to hyperinflation and have not arisen simply as a
consequence of it.
The same phenomenon is illustrated by the elements of
|dollarisation' that have occurred. Russian citizens able to
acquire hard currency have access to a range of durable goods at present
hardly obtainable for rubles. The emergent markets for apartments in
major cities have so far operated almost exclusively in foreign
exchange, because the vendors have usually been emigrants who need hard
currency in their new country of residence. And the tourist hotels and
other facilities run as joint ventures with western companies form a
kind of enclave economy, in which foreign customers, so far from
enjoying the benefits of an under-valued ruble, are charged hefty prices
in western currency.
To be sure, there have been massive increases in the price level
and in money incomes in both 1991 and 1992. The timing of these
increases, however, was determined by government policy. There has been
no sign as yet of western style wage-wage or wage-price spirals.
Widespread strikes by coal miners in 1991 achieved exceptional pay
rises, but this did not turn out to herald any general wave of
industrial unrest or stronger trade-union pressures. People appear
inured to hardships and arbitrary measures of policy, and evidently feel
that public expressions of indignation against particular decisions
serve little purpose. Many probably also believe that alternatives to
the present regime in Russia would turn out to be worse rather than
better.
Even so, the monetary situation remains fragile. As observed above,
Russian government finances are not yet under control. In addition,
relations between the Russian budget and those of other republics in the
CIS have still to be clarified and stabilised - for instance in relation
to taxes levied on oil or oil products. Similar considerations apply to
the control of money and credit. The Moscow authorities have been
endeavouring to contain growth of the money supply not only through
fiscal restraint (though that is clearly of primary importance), but
also by discouraging bank lending to the business and household sectors.
The main approach has been to impose stiffer terms on commercial banks
for recourse to the central bank. At the beginning of 1992 central-bank
rediscount rates were raised from 2-9 per cent to 20-35 per cent, and
efforts were made to enforce quantitative limits on the growth of
central-bank lending to the banks. The commercial banks' own
interest rates on both loans and deposits were simultaneously freed from
all restraints. In April 1992 bank reserve requirements were raised to
20 per cent.
It is impossible as yet to discern positive results from these
efforts. |Distress borrowing' is familiar to western banking
systems as a factor magnifying the growth of monetary aggregates at
times of economic downturn. In the former Soviet Union (and other East
European countries) the problem is compounded by absence of operational
criteria for insolvency and by lack of experience of bankers and
managers alike in handling market-style relations between business
enterprises and financial institutions.
Increased costs and attempted rationing of bank credit have
stimulated a large expansion of inter-enterprise debts. The total in
Russia and the CIS was estimated to have reached at least Rbls. 1,000
billion (20 per cent of Russia's GNP) by mid-1992. Here too Russian
and CIS experience is similar to that of other former Comecon countries.
The phenomenon may be viewed as a natural concomitant of the growth of
inter-firm barter, a view supported by the observation that inter-firm
indebtedness under former command-economy regimes appears to have been
unusually low by western standards (Begg and Portes, 1992). There is
also a more narrowly political dimension. The authorities in the
non-Russian territories of the former USSR, notably the Ukraine, have
not supported Russian efforts to contain credit, but have rather run up
vast ruble debts to finance government outlays and support loss-making
industrial producers. This has not inhibited the Ukrainian government,
incidentally, from experimenting with transferable coupons as a means of
reserving Ukrainian farm produce for residents of the Ukraine and
preventing its export to Russia.
The way ahead
Little of what has been visibly happening in the former Soviet
economy over the past two years reflects the intentions of its
policymakers. On the microeconomic side, the notion of comprehensive
central planning of the economy's output has been renounced. But
over 80 per cent of the workforce (both in Russia and in other former
republics of the USSR) is still employed in state-owned enterprises, and
this percentage is likely to fall only slowly in the next few years.
Many prices have been freed from central control and left to vendors and
purchasers to negotiate. But some of the most important prices in the
economy - farmgate prices of foodstuffs, energy prices, housing costs
and public utility and transport rates - continue to be set by
government and the products in question purchased by the state machine.
Ironically, many of these items are subject to a large measure of
government price-determination in western industrial countries too; but
the overall context there is very different. Western government
influence in specific sectors operates against a background of most
market prices roughly reflecting opportunity costs, and is not a remnant
of a command-administrative structure with near-universal state
ownership and extravagant subsidisation of basic goods. As for
inter-company relations and marketing procedures, the present situation
in the ex-Soviet economy is one of improvisation through the barter
network and ad hoc trading.
On the macroeconomic side, neither the government budget nor the
credit system is under adequate control. The ruble remains for the time
being the currency of (pretty much) the whole of the former USSR. The
non-Russian republics find it an advantageous source of (purchasing)
power without (economic) responsibility. It also parallels the
structural interdependence of the republican economies, as is
re-emphasised below. Frequently there is a measure of conflict between
nationalistic pride and perceived economic self-interest. The Baltic
states in particular would have been quicker to introduce their own
currencies were it not for their industrial and commercial
inter-relationship with the former USSR economy. Estonia took the plunge
on midsummer day 1992, replacing the ruble with the kroon as legal
tender.
In short, having set aside the command-administrative system, the
Russian (and other republic) authorities are struggling to establish a
coherent market alternative, and in the meantime exercise very limited
influence over the march of economic developments. In one sense, of
course, this was precisely the purpose. But in another sense, one would
have preferred a postponement of the loss of control until something
more like a fully-fledged market system was in place, including both
microeconomic structures (competitive markets, wide-ranging private
ownership of productive assets and opportunity cost pricing) and
macroeconomic policy weapons.
The dilemma is analogous to that of the Walrasian auctioneer. His
only means of ensuring general economic equilibrium is to identify the
equilibrium set of prices before permitting any transactions. Otherwise,
there is liable to be trading at |false prices', and equilibrium
becomes a goal of uncertain attainability, because equilibrium values
are subject to continuous alteration by the process of searching for
them.
The search for a viable - one hardly dare say |optimum' -
policy path for an economy in process of marketisation is known as the
sequencing problem.(5) The problem was initially formulated in terms of
the temporal priority to be accorded to the three elements of pricing
reform, privatisation and de-monopolisation respectively.
De-monopolisation involves some mixture of reorganisation of domestic
productive structures, regulation of the economic conduct of large
enterprises and import competition. At least two other components were
latterly added, namely financial stabilisation and external
liberalisation in its own right, including both trade and inward
investment.
General rules about sequencing are few. Much depends on the
circumstances of each case. The acceptability of rapid de-monopolisation
may depend on how much unemployment results, or on the efficiency of
social security arrangements. Financial stabilisation becomes pressing
only if monetary aggregates get out of hand or serious fluctuations in
the value of financial assets are in prospect. Attempts to draw lessons
from the experience of other types of economy - for instance, less
developed countries which switched from |inward-' to
|outward-looking' development strategies - must fail because these
economies already possessed the legal and institutional infrastructure
of the market system.
Two general points may be made. First, there is no reason why
identical sequencing should apply to the whole of an economy. Good
policy may vary from sector to sector. For example, in the case of small
businesses (on any reasonable definition of |small') privatisation
is the only goal to pursue, since they will anyhow search out their own
prices and assortments of goods, and monopoly is not an issue. Secondly,
the urgency of pricing reform must depend on the scope for responding to
price incentives, both on the supply side and on the demand side.
In this respect, the Russian government's price reforms face
problems. Take as a crucial example the case of foodstuffs, where
supply-side incentives are of the greatest importance in both production
and distribution. Economic relations between town and country, and
especially the terms and conditions on which farmers supply food to the
towns, have been a key theme in Russian economic history of the past
century. (See for example Nove (1980).) The recent raising of food
prices has been mainly a matter of eliminating subsidies. It has not (so
far) been accompanied by major privatisation of farming, land ownership
or food distribution. Nor, obviously, has it involved any comparable
increase in farmgate prices, which remain for the most part a matter of
government determination. Thus there is deep uncertainty about the
supply response to higher prices and by the same token, about the future
course of prices themselves. To be sure, the private plots of collective
farmers, amounting to at most 10 per cent of the cultivated land, and
the associated free market in food products have long accounted for a
quite disproportionate share of agricultural and especially
horticultural output; but even they have not been significantly
enlarged, and in any case the composition of food output could become
seriously unbalanced if large areas of farmland were left in collective
hands but deprived of labour and capital inputs.
In the case of energy resources and minerals supplyside incentives
are less controversial. For oil, gas, diamonds and other products it is
a relatively simple matter to negotiate a share-out of earnings between
the central government and regional authorities or producing
enterprises, analogous to the taxation arrangements applied to oil
production in western countries. Major technical tasks remain, for
instance to reduce oil and gas transmission leakages, to improve oil
reservoir management and to curb or reverse massive environmental
damage.
In these cases, however, problems arise on the demand side, and for
technical reasons as well as lack of individual responsibility and
property rights. Energy-intensive equipment in factories will take
years, sometimes decades, to replace. In domestic or commercial
buildings the individual householder or office user has at present no
means of controlling his heating bill because there are no meters,
radiator valves or thermostats. It is relevant to recall that in western
economies, where such technical handicaps are much less extensive,
market responses to the jump in oil prices of 1973-74 took the better
part of a decade to bear much fruit. In addition, the idea of relative
price change as an incentive to economise is totally unfamiliar to the
Russian population and is unlearnable in present circumstances. The
entire pricing system is in a state of upheaval. Many goods whose
relative prices ought to be falling (such as household durables, tools,
paint, bicycles, sewing machines) are typically not available, while
some key items whose cost must sooner or later rise - housing above all
- have not yet been touched.
To amplify somewhat on the housing point, what is at issue here is
the basic cost of urban housing for the ordinary citizen. Summer
cottages in the country (dachy) have long been open to private
ownership, albeit in principle without the ground on which they stand,
and have been an important repository of household savings and
investment. Mention has been made of the emerging market for city flats
priced in foreign currency. The principle residence of the average
citizen, however, is an urban flat (sometimes still shared between more
than one family) for which the rent is not merely uneconomically low but
includes the main public services (heating, electricity and water) at no
extra charge. Some of these flats are now being privatised like UK
council housing, i.e. sold to their occupants at a modest price. Besides
transferring ownership of the apartments, such sales help to absorb
household savings deposits. They need to be followed, however, by a
system of metering and charging economic prices for utilities (which
again will take years to introduce), as well as encouragement for
residents to organise the maintenance of apartment buildings. This too
is likely to be slow to catch on, because of materials shortages as well
as scepticism among the population as to the economic worthwhileness of
this kind of self-help.
Optimists may point to the impressive list of further measures
promised by the government for the foreseeable future. These do include,
in no very clear order, gradual approximation of crude oil and other
energy prices to world levels; privatisation of land ownership and the
food sector; de-monopolisation and privatisation of larger enterprises;
drastically improved unemployment benefit and other social security
arrangements (at what cost to the budget position?); and wide-ranging
liberalisation of external trade and payments, including current-account
convertibility of the ruble for residents as well as non-residents at an
exchange rate significantly higher, at any rate in real terms, than the
quasi-free-market rate of 100-120 rubles to the dollar obtaining in the
first half of 1992. At the beginning of July a unified exchange rate of
about 135 to the dollar was established. Resident nationals remained
subject to stringent exchange control, but at the end of July were given
the right to purchase amounts of up to $500 per head for foreign travel.
The exchange rate fell to 160 following Georgy Matyukhin's
resignation from the central bank.
Sceptics will recall that in the latter stages of the Gorbachev era
programmes of this sort were announced, debated and rejected or
abandoned in a more or less continuous procession. The |500 days'
plan of Professor Shatalin and colleagues in 1990 was the fullest and
most celebrated of them. It in turn was modified by Aganbegyan to try to
meet conservative criticisms, and then replaced by the Ryzhkov-Abalkin
plan which envisaged a more centralised Moscow-based system. Admittedly,
the Yeltsin government has adopted bolder measures than its predecessor
in the pricing sphere; but these do not involve the major institutional
change implied by general privatisation of agriculture and of large
industrial establishments. Such privatisation, if it is to be truly
successful, sooner or later requires the creation of a capital market;
and this in turn depends in practice upon the formation of appropriate
financial intermediaries - universal banks and possibly investment
funds. The fact that not one East European country has yet made really
significant headway in this area may be taken as an indication of the
difficulty of the task.
A number of observers have argued that privatisation programmes
should in fact begin with banks, and should involve as a necessary
preliminary a general |clean up' of balance sheets both of banks
themselves and of their debtor companies in the non-financial sectors
(Rybczynski, 1991; Begg and Portes, 1992). The point is that under the
old regime a large amount of bank credit was simply a form of open-ended
subsidy to loss-making enterprises, part of the system of soft budget
constraints which happened to take monetary rather than fiscal form, and
was not intended to be repaid except by chance good fortune. Such
claims, whose identification should not for the most part prove too
difficult, ought simply, it is argued, to be cancelled, and the gap in
bank assets plugged initially with some form of government obligation.
The banks can then begin market-style operations with a clean slate. Any
transitional or continuing subsidies to industry should be channelled
strictly through the government budget.
The blueprint is impeccable. Putting it into practice is another
matter. Begg and Portes emphasise that such recapitalisation must be
seen as a once-for-all operation, not a government pledge to underwrite
banks in quasi-perpetuity. Noting that most of the 60-odd Polish banks
founded after the start of Poland's economic reforms have already
been bankrupted by inept management, they underline the need for much
more effective banking supervision. Considering the mixed record of
western central banks in the area of banking supervision over the past
two decades, this seems rather a tall order to the new central banks of
eastern Europe.
Apart, however, from the restoration of private ownership of the
means of production, it would be valuable if any renewed monetary
overhang in the next few years could be absorbed by asset transactions -
in land, housing or newly issued securities, and compulsorily if need be
- rather than by further inflation of the price level.
Pessimists, alas, could make a case that all such goals are pie in
the sky and that the economy is heading in the foreseeable future for
total collapse and political anarchy. Such prognoses and talk of the
economy being |in free fall' have become familiar in the last few
years. The cumulative decline in GNP during 1989-92, possibly totalling
as much as 20 per cent, is admittedly a serious matter, even if a
significant fraction of the decline is in defence- or defence-related
activities whose economic value is doubtful. It is difficult to say how
great a decline would be needed to generate serious and widespread
suffering and/or a fundamental breakdown of law and order (as opposed to
the merely unaccustomed level of street crime which urban authorities
are currently facing). It is somewhat easier to give a definition in
terms of activity in vital sectors. The Russians have long been
accustomed to intermittent shortages or even prolonged unavailability of
|essential' items ranging from light bulbs to basic medicines, and
an intensification of such routine privations is unlikely to bring the
country to a halt. This is also true of monetary and financial disorder.
What is necessary for the avoidance of economic collapse and anarchy is
the maintenance of a satisfactory level of output in three key
interdependent sectors: food, transport (which is necessary for food
distribution) and energy (particularly oil and gas, which is necessary
for transport as well as for heating and power). Should collapse in
these sectors occur, it is unlikely that Western aid could do much to
retrieve the situation, mainly because of the problem of transport and
distribution within Russia but also because the quantities available
from western sources would be too limited. Humanitarian aid (food,
medicines) given by the European Community and others over the past two
years has been a nice gesture of support but economically insignificant.
Between successful acceleration of reform and total collapse lies a
broad range of economic paths involving a blend of muddling through,
institutional innovation, corruption and entrepreneurship. A key
question is the relation between economic prospects and the
country's fragile political structure, with the Baltic states and
Georgia already acknowledged as independent, the non-Russian members of
the CIS displaying varying degrees of attachment and of assertiveness
and a number of Russia's constituent republics and regions likewise
jockeying for status and power. The fear has been expressed that wildcat assertion of sovereignty by former republics or autonomous regions could
bring the economy to a halt by interfering with inter-regional trade in
vital components. To some extent, however, the boot is on the other
foot: the dominance of large firms and single producers in formerly
Soviet industry means that interdependence between regions will for the
time being limit the aggressive exercise of sovereignty in the economic
sphere.
The point is reinforced by the high cost of physical re-structuring
and re-location of giant plants, most of them in the defence sector. For
the time being the authorities must seek as far as possible to turn over
military facilities and outputs directly to civilian ends without having
to engage in major investment first. In some areas, such as goods
transport and telecommunications, this is basically uncontroversial. In
others, such as the promotion of arms exports to gain urgently needed
foreign exchange, it may be viewed as destabilising internationally even
if indispensable for Russia. Reports in late July spoke of an imminent
$2 billion arms deal with Iran, including large numbers of Tupolev TU-22
|Backfire' bombers.
Nonetheless, thoroughgoing marketisation of the economy - as
opposed to improvised barter networks - requires a coherent system of
property rights, contract and commercial law, as well as financial
institutions. Legislation on these matters is being delayed by the
fragmented state of political power across Russia and the often subtle
obstructionism of those in positions of influence who feel their status
and livelihood to be under threat. After legislation is in place, many
years of operational experience and case law will be needed to develop a
fully satisfactory system.
In the short run one of the major costs of political uncertainty
and inaction is the discouragement to foreign firms from investing in
the country either on their own or in joint ventures. Foreign firms need
an assured legal and contractual basis for their operations, and this is
impossible to achieve where there are disputes within the host country
about sovereignty and the entitlement to make laws, issue licences and
enter into agreements for the use of local resources.
So long as these matters remain unsettled, low-cost firm-to-firm
co-operation would seem to be the only basis on which western
enterprises can prudently involve themselves in the Russian economy and
its transformation. This need not, however, be a negligible matter. Such
co-operation can bring a great deal to Russia's economic reform
process by showing how product design, delivery and marketing, including
the sourcing of appropriate inputs, are in practice handled by firms
with long experience of the market economy. Even if the socioeconomic
opinions and values of Russian citizens are not as different as is often
supposed from those in the west (see Shiller et al, 1991), they still
have little concrete notion about the work habits and procedures induced
by the competitive system. Western technology may also have important
contributions to make, for example in tackling the problem of safety of
Russia's nuclear power stations and in reducing leakages in gas and
oil transmission.
Co-operation with western firms carries the additional merit of
setting up at least a potential vested interest in the west against the
maintenance of market barriers towards Soviet manufacturers. The
combination of low-cost labour and high technical skill - albeit
hitherto poorly harnessed towards meeting ordinary consumer choices -
offers the possibility of very competitive supply sources in future.
Co-operation with western firms is also promoted through technical
or micro-economic assistance such as the UK Know-How Fund and similar
sources available from the European Commission and elsewhere. The only
disadvantage of such assistance is that it is mostly allocated in
response to bids by western organisations. This can encourage
opportunism on the part of such organisations, which would not
necessarily benefit Russia's reform process.
At macro-economic level the G7 announced a commitment in April 1992
to a $24 billion aid package for Russia and the CIS, of which $6 billion
was intended for a |ruble stabilisation fund'. $4 billion of the
overall total was to come from the IMF, of which Russia and other
republics of the former USSR are now members and whose support was made
a condition by G7 governments of their own contributions. All this was
another useful gesture of support for Mr. Yeltsin; but its technical
rationale was not evident. For one thing, the market exchange rate for
the ruble has not been particularly unstable during 1992. And for
another, no timetable for disbursing the money has been agreed. In July
1992 the IMF promised an initial payment of $1 billion at the beginning
of August, on the usual IMF conditions of a short-term financial
stabilisation programme involving restrictive targets for the
government's fiscal deficit (5-6 per cent of GDP by the end of the
year) and for credit growth. As observed above, there is now slight
prospect of these targets being met, and the G7 package is therefore in
jeopardy.
For political reasons the IMF is bound to impose on East European
clients the same sort of conditions as are applied to any other
borrower. However, the economies in transition from command to market
systems are a new category of which neither policymakers nor outside
analysts have previous experience. Given the difficulty of meeting IMF
criteria in Russia's case (for both political and institutional
reasons), it might have been wiser to detach early economic assistance
from the IMF approach and instead (a) avoid suggesting official
|aid' in the form of loans, and (b) seek ways of furthering the
reform process which themselves might make it easier to fulfill IMF or
other loan criteria at a later stage. An obvious use for a genuine $24
billion of aid would be to forgive a corresponding amount of the
country's external debt. Deferment of scheduled debt repayments is
saving the Russian authorities $11 billion in 1992 (out of $21 billion
falling due); a long-term postponement or write-off would translate this
temporary lump sum into a modest permanent gain for the country's
balance of payments. It would also imply a reasonably just distribution
of the gain within the former Soviet Union, given that the Russian
authorities have taken on the full external debt of the USSR, some of
which was certainly incurred on projects in the other republics.
There may also be a case for using western aid to establish an
EPU-style settlements mechanism among former Comecon countries and (if
the ruble ceases to be in general circulation in the CIS) among the CIS
States as well. The collapse of Communism in Eastern Europe was followed
by an abrupt 60 per cent shrinkage (aptly termed an implosion) in the
region's international trade, as countries sought vainly to
re-orient their external trade to western markets. (For discussion see
UN Economic Commission for Europe, 1991). This represents the
international dimension of the fall in output which has everywhere
accompanied the dismantling of the command-administrative system.
Russia's raw-material exports to Eastern Europe were effected from
the beginning of 1991 at world-market prices and with (in principle)
hard-currency settlement. All countries of the region sought where
possible to reject each other's manufactures as inferior in quality
to western goods. By the same token, however, few east European
manufactures were competitive in western markets; and those that were
faced quotas and other trade barriers, as did exports of agricultural
products in particular. A temporary mechanism of international
settlement which provided for a systematic element of credits between
participating countries along EPU lines, thereby relieving pressure on
convertible currency resources, could help to revive trade among Eastern
European countries and to wean interrepublic trade within the CIS away
from the barter network on which much of it currently rests. Needless to
say, any such payments scheme should not become a pretext for western,
especially west European countries, to further delay widening market
access for Russian and other east European exports.
Conclusion
The Yeltsin government has moved with more vigour and determination
than its predecessor down the path to market. But it has still covered
only a limited distance. Many prices have been freed, but some of the
most important remain subject to government control. The Russian pricing
system as a whole is still far from being aligned with opportunity
costs. Availability of many simple goods is still patchy and consumer
opportunities to respond to price incentives very limited.
Perhaps more important, the processes of privatisation and
commercialisation of enterprises are still in their extreme infancy.
Without much further advance in this direction managers in large
enterprises will have no satisfactory objectives or criteria to work to.
The establishment of appropriate legal, banking, auditor, shareholder
and customer relationships requires much legislation to begin with and
many years of operational experience and experimentation thereafter.
There are no adequate historical precedents for industrial command
economies undergoing such a process, and no well established theoretical
analysis either. Western economic advisors, both official and
non-official, are well able to specify textbook end-states which it is
desirable to reach; but their ideas on the adjustment or transition path
are necessarily ad hoc and improvised.
Meanwhile in Russia and the other former Soviet republics managers
and consumers are engaging in improvisation on the ground. Barter
networks are helping to keep economic activity at a reasonable level,
limiting the fall in output brought about by the removal of most of the
command-administrative structure which previously directed industry.
National output has nonetheless continued to fall; and the uncertain and
fragmented nature of sovereign authority in the CIS at large and within
the Russian Federations itself is delaying legislative moves towards the
extension of private ownership. Even the really pessimistic scenarios
for the Russian economy, of mounting anarchy and serious hardship,
cannot therefore be wholly discounted.
They are, however, improbable. In the past two winters (1990-1 and
1991-2) critical food shortages feared by some observers failed to
materialise. And in the spring and summer of 1992 earlier reports that
economic uncertainty and dislocation were leading to a drastic shortfall
of crop sowing for the coming year on state and collective farms were
declared to be baseless. Admittedly the prices to be paid for this
output by the government remain a matter of uncertainty and anxiety, not
least because of the implications for the budget deficit and inflation.
At the same time liberalisation was leading not merely to chaotic street
trading but to occasional signs of household goods and clothing
returning to ordinary shops. Examples of consumer resilience in trying
circumstances could be multiplied - for example, motorists continuing to
keep their engines tuned and their petrol tanks full despite long queues
at petrol pumps and an apparent total absence of service stations and
spare parts.
Perhaps most important of all, there has been no renewed
disposition in political circles, whether of government or of
parliamentary opposition, to seek a return to authoritarian government
or to reimpose curbs on the press. Anxieties are occasionally voiced
about the danger of another attempted coup. Serious political
differences and even conflicts remain, notably over the status and
treatment of minority Russian populations in other republics, such as
Estonia and Moldova. The Russian parliament has reacted to
discriminatory measures in Estonia by calling for sanctions and
threatening to raise the matter in the United Nations (Press reports, 19
July 1992). But compared with the sabre rattling which would have been
standard practice a year or so ago, this is, in its limited and
ambiguous fashion, a distinct mark of progress.
NOTES
(1) Data from Stanley Fischer, |Stabilisation and economic reform in
Russia', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1992, cited in
Financial Times, 13 May 1992. (2) Source: OECD and BIS Statistics on
External Indebtedness, July 1992. (3) For example, in December
1991/January 1992 Karelia and the Komi Autonomous Republic were
permitted to retain 75 per cent of hard currency earnings of enterprises
on their territory. In March 1992 Kolmorogovsky Colliery was allowed to
retain hard currency from the export of 140,000 tonnes of coal in order
to build apartment houses. (Russian press reports.) (4) Reported in
Financial Times, 17 July 1992. (5) Recent contributions to the
literature include Kaser (1990), McKinnon (1991), Rybczynski (1991),
Journal of Economic Perspectives (1991) and Centre for Economic Policy
Research (1992).)
REFERENCES
Begg, D., and Portes, R. (1992), |Enterprise Debt and Economic
Transformation: Financial Restructuring of the State Sector in Central
and Eastern Europe', CEPR Discussion Paper No. 695. Centre for
Economic Policy Research (1992), The Economic Consequences of the East,
London. Erickson, J., (1992), |The cost of the peace dividend',
Royal Bank of Scotland Review, No. 173, March. Glaziev, S., (1991),
|Transformation of the Soviet Economy: Economic Reforms and Structural
Crisis', National Institute Economic Review, No. 138, November.
Journal of Economic Perspectives (1991), Symposium on Economic
Transition in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe, Vol. 5, Vol. 4.
Kaser, M.C., (1963), |Monetary Reforms in the Soviet Union',
Bankers Magazine, Vol. cxcvi. Kaser, M.C., (1990), |The technology of
decontrol: some macroeconomic issues', Economic Journal, June.
Katsenelinboigen, A., (1977), |Coloured markets in the USSR',
Soviet Studies, Vol. xxix. Kornai, J. (1992), The Socialist System,
Oxford. McKinnon, R.I., (1991), The Order of Economic Liberalization:
Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy, Baltimore and
London. Nove, A., (1980), An Economic History of the USSR, 6th Edn.,
Harmondsworth. Nove, A., (1991), |The Soviet Economic Crisis',
National Institute Economic Review, No. 138, November. Pockney, B.P.,
(1991), |Comment', ibid. Rybczynski, T.M., (1991), |The sequencing
of reform', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 7, No. 4.
Shiller, R.J., Boycko, M. and Korobov, V., (1991) |Popular attitudes
towards free markets: The Soviet Union and the United States
compared', American Economic Review, June. United Nations Economic
Commission for Europe (1991), Reforms in Foreign Economic Relations of
Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union, (Ed. Michael Kaser and Aleksandar
M. Vacic), New York.