Properties of the fundamental equilibrium exchange rate in models of the UK economy.
Church, Keith B.
The Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange Rate (FEER) is that value of
the real exchange rate that is consistent with macroeconomic equilibrium. This article uses the long-run trade equation elasticities
from the models of Her Majesty's Treasury, the National Institute
of Economic and Social Research and the Bank of England to examine the
FEER calculation. The sensitivity of the results to changes in the key
elasticities and to the possibility of a recent improvement in UK
trading performance is considered. Historical comparisons are made
between the FEER and the actual real exchange rate. All the results
suggest that the real exchange rate was above the FEER at the time of
ERM entry. The fixing of the nominal exchange rate removes a possible
mechanism by which the economy might reach equilibrium and therefore
convergence requires a period where UK inflation is lower than that of
its trading partners.
Introduction
Assessments of national economic performance usually attempt to
examine a general picture that abstracts from the effects of the
business cycle. Economic commentators and politicians often refer to the
|true' or |underlying' position of the economy, usually during
the depths of recession, and it is always useful to judge current
economic performance against an equilibrium path. In this context an
indicator receiving much current attention is the Fundamental
Equilibrium Exchange Rate (FEER) of Williamson (1983), which is the
exchange rate which delivers a |sustainable' current account
balance while the economy is growing at its |natural' rate. The
purpose of this article is to examine the calculation of the FEER of the
UK economy as viewed by three of the large-scale macroeconomic models,
with particular attention being paid to the long-run trading performance
of the economy. The models in question are those of Her Majesty's
Treasury (HMT), the National Institute of Economic and Social Research
(NIESR) and the Bank of England (BE) as deposited with the ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau in Autumn 1991. The HMT model was also
publicly released at this time.
The method we choose for calculating the FEER is described and then
undertaken for each of the G7 countries in Barrell and Wren-Lewis
(1989)(1). We follow their approach closely and we use the stylised framework developed in that paper and, importantly, adopt their
treatment of the supply side. The calculation depends on internal and
external balance. Internal balance comes initially from the interaction
of wages and prices, which determines an equilibrium level of activity
in the domestic economy that is consistent with stable inflation. On the
supply side of the economy a higher real exchange rate lowers import
prices and hence reduces inflationary pressure in the domestic economy.
As a result the equilibrium level of activity consistent with stable
inflation rises. However any increase in equilibrium activity also tends
to lead to an increase in imports and a worsening of the current account
balance and as a result a lower real exchange rate is required to
achieve a sustainable current account. External balance is defined for
our purposes as occurring when the real exchange rate is such that the
current account of the balance of payments is offset by
|structural' capital flows, to which we return below. The FEER is
that value of the real exchange rate at which external balance holds
whilst simultaneously the equilibrium level of utilization of domestic
capacity exerts no pressure for change on the current account. This
unique value is the focus of attention of this article. Ideally it would
be extracted from the large-scale models by looking simultaneously at
the supply side and trading sector. Unfortunately of the three models
considered only that of the NIESR has a well defined supply-side
framework which allows this to be done. For this reason the
determination of equilibrium activity that we use reflects the treatment
of the supply side in National Institute models.
The FEER is a concept describing a possible medium-term equilibrium
real exchange rate. In equilibrium the current account balance can
deviate from zero if there are corresponding |structural' capital
flows into or out of the economy. By this we do not mean speculative
flows which move from country to country in search of high short-term
rates of return, but inflows or outflows which are likely to persist for
a sustained period of time. The investment of Japanese car manufacturers
in setting up operations in the UK would fall into this category.
Wren-Lewis (1992) suggests that structural flows could be treated as
endogenous, although they are exogenous in our model. In the long-run we
might expect |Purchasing Power Parity' to tell us what the
underlying exchange rate actually is. For the actual exchange rate to
approach that implied by PPP would require arbitrage by consumers, and
they would have to buy from countries whose products are cheaper than
home produce (once foreign currency prices have been converted into
domestic currency). Similarly producers should locate where the price of
inputs is lowest and hence the potential for high profits greatest.
Clearly these concepts are extremely long-run. It is also the case that
PPP might be considered an unreliable guide to the underlying exchange
rate because many goods are non-traded. In any case consumers rarely
have the information to arbitrage in this way and transaction costs are
high. Similarly, uncertainty about the future and the high cost of
moving an entire production process might deter producers from
relocating. Given that we wish to examine the position of the UK economy
over a relevant policy horizon it seems reasonable to concentrate on a
measure of the exchange rate that reflects medium-term considerations.
Williamson (1991) gives further reasons for doubting the suitability of
PPP as a macro equilibrium concept.
The article proceeds as follows. In the second section the
framework in which the FEER is determined is introduced. As our major
objective is to compare models of the UK economy the trading sectors of
the relevant models are then examined, with particular attention being
paid to the volume equations for imports and exports of manufactures and
services. Comparisons of the long-run competitiveness and activity
elasticities are made across the models and these estimates are used in
the third section to calculate the FEER for the three models. These are
then contrasted with the actual historical real exchange rate, also
trends are extrapolated in order to trace out the expected future path
of the FEER. Differences in these expected paths are explained in terms
of differing elasticities, and the most important factors in determining
the properties of the FEER are identified. The following section
examines the extent to which a possible recent improvement in the
trading performance of the UK might change the equilibrium position. The
penultimate section assesses the sensitivity of the FEER to increases in
competitiveness elasticities that might not be reflected in current
econometric estimates. Conclusions are drawn in the final section.
Calculating the FEER
The method for calculating the FEER is illustrated in the following
stylized framework. The first step is to calculate the structural or
trend balance for exports and imports of goods and services. This is
simply constructed by multiplying the steady state volumes of exports
and imports by the relevant prices and using the identity: -
BGS = XG.PXG + XS.PXS - MG.PMG - MS.PMS (1) where
BGS: Balance of trade on goods and services
XG: Volume of exports of goods
MG: Volume of imports of goods
XS: Volume of exports of services
MS: Volume of imports of services
PXG: Price of exports of goods
PMG: Price of imports of goods
PXS: Price of exports of services
PMS: Price of imports of services
In all the models trade volumes are explained by domestic and world
activity and price competitiveness, and prices by a combination of
domestic and world prices. By dividing the above identity by GDP and
rearranging it is possible to express each of the components in terms of
the real exchange rate and activity. When interest, profit and dividend
(IPD) flows and time trends are introduced the equilibrium current
account balance as a proportion of GDP can be expressed in the following
form:
CBT = f(R,Y,YW,IPD,TIME ...) (2) where
CBT: Trend current account balance
R: Real exchange rate index
IPD: Interest, profit and dividend flows
Y: Equilibrium domestic GDP
YW: Equilibrium world GDP
If in the above internal balance is already being achieved then the
FEER is the value of R which ensures that the current balance is equal
to structural capital flows. If it is assumed for simplicity that these
are zero then the FEER is obtained by solving the following:
O = f(FEER,Y,YW,IPD,TIME ...) (3)
The level of activity at any period in time is influenced by the
level of the real exchange rate and hence is affected by deviations of
the real exchange rate from its equilibrium value. Not only is it
possible to find historical values of the FEER it is also possible to
project exogenous variables into the future and solve the system for
possible future combinations of the FEER and equilibrium activity. As an
aid to examining the sensitivity of the FEER to different equilibrium
activity paths the model can also be solved assuming that GDP takes
actual values in the past and has different possible growth rates in the
future. If these paths are denoted by Y then the FEER is given by:
O = f(FEER,Y,YW,IPD,TIME ...) (4)
The balance of trade on goods and services is crucial in
determining the long-run prospects for the exchange rate, and we now
turn to its treatment in the models. The three models featured here
adopt a disaggregated approach to the explanation of the behaviour of
imports and exports, typically distinguishing manufactures, services,
oil and non-manufactures or |others'.
We concentrate on the manufacturing sector but also look at
services, as these are the two most important components of the current
account balance. Oil trade volumes are important during the early part
of the 1980s but then decline. While the actual trend of the FEER does
depend on the oil sector, cross-model differences between the estimates
do not, and so our treatment reflects that of the NIESR model
throughout. We first have to describe the long-run behaviour of these
sectors. There is broad agreement between the modelling teams on the
determinants of the quantities of exports and imports and this allows
simple cross-model comparison in the framework set out below.
The main determinants of exports and imports are changes in
competitiveness and activity although the measures used across the
models vary slightly. In the framework used below competitiveness is
defined in terms of the movement of domestic wholesale prices relative
to world export prices. However in the three models the competitiveness
term is sometimes defined as the ratio of import to export prices in a
specific sector, but this can be converted to our definition by using
further equations in the models which determine for example the price of
exports and imports of services as a function of world and domestic
prices. These equations allow the calculation of the elasticity given
our definition of competitiveness. In certain cases the key domestic
price variable is not wholesale prices but we assume that other price
measures are related to this central index by a constant and time trend
factor. For simplicity all different measures of world trade and
domestic activity across the models are assumed to move together and are
treated equivalently.
These models differ in their description of the current account.
Two of the models (HMT and NIESR) have an explicit trend specialisation
term which measures the additional propensity for the UK to import
manufactures over time as the ratio of world trade to world GDP
increases, whilst BE model the same effect as a simple time trend. In
order to ensure comparability we calculate the equivalent coefficient on
a specialisation term. For all the models the appropriate long-run
competitiveness and activity elasticities are taken from econometrically
mated equations in the models. These are used in the construction of
long-run relationships that describe the data. The residual part of the
behaviour of each of the trade volumes which is not explained by the
long-run competitiveness and activity effects is absorbed by a constant
and time trend. Further differences between the models involve services,
where HMT are alone in having a feedback from service imports into
exports and vice versa. We can describe the final model as:
Volume equations
XMF = [gamma.sub.0][RX.sup.gamma1][S.sup.gamma2][e.sup.gamma3T]
Manufacturing
exports
XS = [theta.sub.0][RS.sup.theta1][YW.sup.theta2][MS.sup.theta3][e.sup.theta4
T] Service
exports
MMF = [delta.sub.0][R.sup.-delta1][Y.sup.delta2][SPEC.sup.delta3][e.sup.delta
4T] Manufacturing
imports
MS = [omega.sub.0][R.sup.-omega1][Y.sup.omega2][XS.sup.omega3][e.sup.omega4T
] Service
imports
where
RX = WPXG/rPXG: Export competitiveness
WPXG: World export price of manufactures
r: Nominal exchange rate
PXG: Price of domestic exports
S: World trade weighted by importance of markets
RS: Real exchange rate for services
R = WPXG/rPD Real exchange rate
PD: Domestic prices
SPEC: Trend specialisation
Multiplication of each of these volumes by the appropriate price
term expressed in domestic and world prices and division by nominal GDP enables a reparameterisation to take place, with prices being translated
into terms of the real exchange rate, R. The definition of R used here
means that a rise is a depreciation of the exchange rate in the
conventional sense. The results presented in this paper reverse the
definition above to ensure that a fall in R or the FEER is a
depreciation. Having constructed the balance on goods and services the
introduction of IPD flows gives the expression for the current account
as a proportion of GDP shown by relationship (2).
Disparities between the results across the models are clearly going
to arise from differences in the long-run elasticities in the volume
equations, shown in Table 1.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
Taking the treatment of manufactures first we can see a degree of
consensus across the models, particularly with respect to activity. The
NIESR export activity elasticity of 1.02 is in fact the only departure
from unity. The spread of competitiveness elasticities is greater, more
so for imports than exports, with the NIESR estimate being considerably
larger than the view taken by both HMT and BE. The disagreements across
the service sector are far greater. HMT are alone in having a feedback
from imports of services into exports and vice-versa. The NIESR model
has the lowest activity elasticity on exports and the highest on
imports. The BE model has a competitiveness elasticity on exports which
is considerably lower than the other models and a higher value on
imports. Differences in these key elasticities affect the implied
long-run position of the current account and hence the value of the FEER
consistent with external balance.
Because the NIESR is the only one of the three models used that has
the necessary well defined supply side our treatment is to use the NIESR
approach and model domestic GDP as a function of the real exchange rate,
world prices and a time trend. We utilise the NIESR elasticity
estimates, the most important of which is the elasticity of supply with
respect to the real exchange rate of 0.20.
Results and findings
Any projected path for the FEER depends on a number of assumptions
about the behaviour of the relevant exogenous variables. It is assumed
that there are no structural flows which might allow the equilibrium
current account to deviate from zero. Over the historical part of the
analysis, exogenous variables are set to their actual values, partly to
aid interpretation of the results, partly because of the difficulty in
deciding the equilibrium path of variables such as world oil prices.
Over the forecast period we assume future growth rates of 3 per cent for
world GNP, 4 per cent for world trade and a constant real oil price.
Large current account deficits in the; early-1990s have led to a fall in
net overseas assets and hence we project that net IPD receipts will
fall, but the decline in domestic interest rates assumed to follow ERM
entry is expected to reduce the payments on deposits made in the UK and
hence improve net IPD flows.
Chart 1 shows the actual and trend current accounts for the three
models, the trend current account being the value that emerges from
equation (2). In this partial equilibrium the real exchange rate is set
equal to its actual and forecast values and consequently the trend
current account balance differs from zero. The general path is agreed
upon by all three models. The actual current account lies above the
trend at the start of the 1980s and by a lesser amount from the
beginning of the 1990s. The general path is downwards reflecting the
trend increase in manufacturing imports that is a feature of all three
models.
To consider the full equilibrium, the trend current account is set
equal to zero. Chart 2 shows the resulting path of the FEER for each of
the three models. The differences between these paths may be explained
in terms of the different model elasticities. Over the historical period
of the exercise, comparisons can be drawn between the actual and
fundamental exchange rate. One striking feature is the similarity of
their relative positions at the start and end of the 1980s. The actual
real exchange rate is above the FEER in both cases. Both periods are
associated with a tight monetary policy with a high nominal exchange
rate and high interest rates being used to try to reduce demand and
hence inflation. These policies improve the current account position by
reducing imports. During the mid-1980s the actual real exchange rate is
below the FEER, but both are fairly stable. The actual real exchange
rate falls from its level at the start of the decade through a
combination of a depreciation in the nominal exchange rate and an
improvement in UK inflation relative to its competitors. The FEER is
stable during the first half of the 1980s as the positive balance from
oil trade and the high propensity to import offset one another. As the
former effect becomes less important in the later years of the decade,
so the FEER declines.
It is noted that for each model the actual rate is some 5 to 10 per
cent above the equilibrium rate at the time of the UK's entry into
the ERM. Subsequently this gap widened in the first quarter of 1991 due
to an appreciation in the UK effective exchange rate, especially against
the dollar. If in the long-run it is argued that large current account
deficits are in fact unsustainable then the actual value must converge
to the equilibrium. Barrell, Gurney and In't Veld (1992) argue that
a current account disequilibrium leads to changes in real wealth which
impact on output through consumption so that departures from current
account equilibrium are self-correcting. The policies needed to reach
equilibrium and their associated costs are not discussed in the present
paper but are assessed in the discussion of optimal entry rates for ERM
in Wren-Lewis et al. (1991).
The steady downward trend in the forecast is partly due to
assumptions on the speed of adjustment of the economy to equilibrium. If
the UK continues to have large current account deficits into the future
then foreign acquisition of claims on the economy leads to a further
downward pressure on the current account through IPD flows, and hence a
larger depreciation in the FEER is needed to achieve external balance.
By contrast, if the actual real exchange rate converges rapidly to
equillibrium then this deterioration of IPD flows does not occur and the
decline in the FEER is less pronounced.
With sterling entering the ERM it is no longer possible for the
actual to converge to the equilibrium rate by adjustment of the nominal
exchange rate. Instead, all the movement has to occur through relative
prices. This implies that if the FEER were a constant rate somewhere
below the current effective rate then British inflation would have to be
held below that of competitors until the FEER is achieved, and from that
point onwards be at the same level as those nations. This would seem to
be the path that France and the Netherlands are currently following in
relation to Germany, with UK inflation also forecast by many to fall
below that in Germany in the coming months. Even after the initial
misalignment is corrected the trend of the FEER is still downwards, so a
continued inflation differential is necessary. Barrell and In't
Veld (1991) estimate that the UK inflation rate must be 1.54 percentage
points below that in Germany in order to maintain equilibrium. When the
UK came out of recession in the early 1980s much of the convergence of
actual real exchange rate to equilibrium levels was brought about by a
large fall in the nominal exchange rate. With this option seemingly
ruled out a prolonged bout of sub-German inflation is required by the UK
in order to reach the FEER, and this has to be sustained if the economy
is to remain in equilibrium.
Cross-model differences in the FEERs shown in Chart 2 are the
consequence of the differing long-run elasticities in the trade volume
equations. The sensitivity of the results to changes in these
elasticities can be examined by substituting parameter values from one
model into the FEER calculation from another and observing the
difference this makes. The first exercise takes the most optimistic FEER, that of the NIESR, and replaces the service elasticities with
those of the BE. Despite a considerable disagreement over the effects of
activity, particularly on exports of services, it is found that changing
these elasticities makes little difference to the path of the FEER.
Competitiveness elasticities do however have an important effect as
shown in Chart 3. The FEER falls when the lower BE export
competitiveness value is substituted in, as a greater depreciation in
the rate is needed in order to maintain current account balance.
Conversely when the higher import competitiveness elasticity is
substituted the exchange rate need do less to discourage imports, and
the FEER appreciates. The combination of both changes leads to a
virtually unchanged FEER.
In 1989 exports of services accounted for approximately 25 per cent
of the value of all exports and imports of services 18 per cent of the
value of all imports. The corresponding manufacturing shares were 65 per
cent and 68 per cent respectively. This would indicate that the
UK's long-run performance in manufacturing trade is by far the most
important determinant of the trend current account position and hence
the FEER. Chart 4 decomposes the variation between the HMT and NIESR
FEERs which is due to the manufacturing volume elasticities. There is
virtual agreement on activity elasticities (NIESR differ from unity with
1.02 for exports) so no difference in the calculation emerges from this
source. Small differences to the FEER path result from replacing the HMT
estimate of the manufacturing exports competitiveness elasticity with
the slightly larger NIESR value. The combination of this and the lower
trend specialisation response in the NIESR import equation leads to a
FEER that depreciates less to achieve current account balance. However
the most important determinant of differences between estimates is the
import competitiveness elasticity for manufactures. Comparison of Charts
2 and 4 suggests that the difference in this elasticity accounts for
virtually all the difference between the HMT and NIESR FEERs. The same
elasticity also explains why the projected path of the BE FEER is lower
than that for the NIESR.
The current account constraint on economic growth
One of the frequent debates conducted between different schools of
economic thought has been that of the effect on the UK economy of
|Thatcherism'. Did the 1980s herald a new era of fitter more
competitive industry or were the relatively prosperous times of the
mid-1980s merely a short-term |blip' before the economy returned to
|normal'?
Some evidence has been produced to suggest that there has been a
halt in the long-run decline of the UK's share of world exports.
Landesmann and Snell (1989) argue that the income elasticity of demand for UK manufacturing exports rose during the 1980s to a value higher
than that characteristic of the 1970s after a huge fall at the start of
the decade. However our results seem robust to changes in this
elasticity. By way of contrast a London Business School study (Holly and
Wade, 1989) does not find an increase in this parameter in a recursive estimation exercise. On the other hand they conclude that an improvement
has taken place on the supply side, so that when faced with an expansion
of demand there is now a tendency for UK firms to increase output,
whereas previously most of the increase might have been in prices.
We consider the possibility of a structural break in the 1980s by
examining whether the residual part of the behaviour of imports and
exports of manufactures which is not explained by the long-run
elasticities has changed. Instead of fitting the trend part of the
volume equations over the period 1975-91 they are fitted over 1983-91.
The recalculated coefficients show that the trend tendency for UK
exports to decrease over time has turned into a small increase when the
models are fitted over the later sample period. A small reduction in the
import trend is also found, improving the future trend current account
balance further. Under the |old regime', UK growth rates in excess
of 1 per cent per annum would have had to have been associated with
inflation rates significantly below those in competing economies. Models
fitted over the more recent period would suggest that the key growth
rate for triggering deflationary pressures is around 2 per cent. With
changes in long-run parameters being picked up by a single trend term no
conclusion can be drawn about whether it is a greater responsiveness to
increases in world trade or to relative movements in world and domestic
prices which has led to the improved export performance. If the
improvement is in the competitiveness elasticities then the real
exchange rate would have to do less work in order to make a given trend
current account balance |sustainable'. Obviously for completeness
it would be necessary to re-estimate the model equations over the new
sample period, as any recent change in the structure of the economy
cannot be reflected in estimates made over previous regimes. The trend
current accounts from the |old' and |new' regimes are shown in
Chart 5. The improved trading performance is reflected in a current
account that still declines, but at a much slower rate.
As might be expected this improvement in the current account is
reflected by a similar strengthening in the FEER, as shown in Chart 6.
Over the historical part of the exercise the FEER is lower than in the
original estimate, giving an overvaluation of the actual real exchange
rate of nearly 20 per cent at the start of the 1980s. The FEER
appreciated gradually until the end of the decade, when a gradual
decline commenced. This would seem to be in line with the findings of
Barrell and In't Veld (1991).
Sensitivity to competitiveness
One of the problems in predicting the future development of the
economy is that the way the economy behaves is subject to change. Indeed
there is usually more than one explanation proposed for that which has
already occurred which shows the difficulty in stating what is about to
arise. In passing comment on the present state of the economy and the
prospects for the future it is assumed that the model which describes
the recent past still holds and will continue to hold. In the previous
section it was found that the trend export of manufactures increased
when the analysis was carried out over a more recent sub-sample of the
data. This trend increase might however merely reflect changes in other
elasticities which, because of a lack of data from the |new
regime', econometric estimates cannot show.
If it is believed that the UK economy has undergone a change in its
structure then it might be expected that the competitiveness
elasticities are now higher than those given by the econometric
estimates of the modelling teams. There are various reasons why these
elasticities might be higher than current estimates in the future. The
first of these reflects continuing increases in world trade. It would be
expected that, as barriers to trade are removed, given relative price
movements across countries will generate greater trade volumes. The
advent of a single European market in 1993 should ensure that
competitiveness elasticities are indeed higher in the future. Part of
the single market programme is the laying down of common standards for
goods. This will lead to a more homogeneous product, a greater degree of
substitutability and again higher competitiveness elasticities. Another
distinction that can be made between the present and past is the
UK's membership of ERM. The consequence of this is the removal of
some of the uncertainty associated with movements of the nominal
exchange rate which might discourage trade. Previously, changes in
competitiveness might be hidden by movements in the exchange rate. In
cases where ordering and payment for goods were some distance apart the
possibility existed that a decision made on the grounds of a relative
price comparison might prove to be the wrong one by the subsequent
movement of the nominal exchange rate. With the UK now in ERM it might
be expected that any improvement in UK price competitiveness will be
reflected by a greater change in trade volumes because of the reduction
in uncertainty.
All the results seem to demonstrate that there is a tendency for
the FEER to fall over time. Given the possibility of alteration to the
structure of the economy as described above, and the small changes to
the FEER that occur through cross-model differences, the effects of more
radical changes to competitiveness elasticities are shown in Chart 7.
The two variants show the effect of first an increase in the export
competitiveness elasticity ([NI.sup.*]) and then the additional benefit
from raising the import competitiveness estimate ([NI.sup.**]). The
downward drift of the FEER is still present but the rate of decline is
slightly slower with the higher elasticities. This result is consistent
with the sensitivity analysis presented in Barrell and In't Veld
(1991). Tle major divergence between the paths starts in the mid-1980s
with the decline in North Sea oil revenues, as already explained. The
chart indicates the degree to which substantially higher elasticities
prevent such a large fall in the FEER over the latter part of the
decade. The implications of this are that if competitiveness
elasticities are higher than current econometric estimates then
convergence of the real exchange rate to the FEER will not require such
a severe reduction in UK inflation relative to that of competitors as
that implied by estimates in the current models. However even the
substantial changes shown here do not alter the need for UK inflation to
be lower than that of countries such as Germany for a period of time to
facilitate this convergence.
Conclusion
This paper has shown that there is a high level of cross-model
agreement on the long-run position of the current account and hence on
the FEER. The result is a reflection of the similarity in the key
elasticities which itself is symbolic of a general convergence in the
approach to modelling these areas. The differences that do exist between
the FEERs presented here come from the manufacturing imports equation.
The methodology is the same, with imports being determined along with
domestic production and domestic demand but different competitiveness
elasticities result, with that of NIESR being slightly higher than those
of BE and HMT. These differences do not alter the overall picture that
emerges from the exercise. The FEER is projected to depreciate in the
forecast. This particular feature depends on the speed of convergence of
the real exchange rate to the equilibrium rate. If convergence is rapid
the trend depreciation will be lower. However if it is believed that
current account deficits will persist for some time into the future,
this worsens the position of the UK IPD flows and hence the FEER must
depreciate by more to achieve balance.
The results are also sensitive to the period over which the trade
equations are fitted. Recent experience has shown that export equations
in the large-scale models tend to underpredict and require residual
adjustments in forecasting (see Bray et al., 1992). Fitting the
equations over a more recent sample improves the trend estimates and
prevents much of the decline in the forecast of the FEER. Even with this
improved performance the actual real exchange rate was about 5 per cent
above the FEER in September 1990 when sterling entered the ERM. This
does not imply that the rate at which the UK joined was too high but
adjustment of actual to the FEER must take place through movements in
relative prices because the nominal exchange rate is fixed. Barrell,
Gurney and In't Veld (1992) estimate that to eliminate
three-quarters of a 10 per cent overvaluation of sterling might require
up to five years of lower UK inflation relative to competitors. All the
results presented in this article suggest that the UK FEER is
depreciating, which in turn means that the gap between actual and
equilibrium actually widens if UK inflation is not below that of
competitor countries. The implications are that the longer the period
before adjustment commences, the longer the time that UK inflation will
have to be below that of other countries to achieve equilibrium.
NOTES
(1) We are grateful to these authors for providing us with the data
and a computer program for the calculation of the FEER. The forecast
data is taken from the May 1992 National Institute Economic Review.
REFERENCES
Barrell, R. and Wren-Lewis, S. (1989), |Fundamental equilibrium
exchange rates for the G7', Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper No.323. Barrell, R. and In't Veld, J.W. (1991),
|FEERS and the path to EMU', National Institute Economic Review,
No.137, 51-58. Barrell, R, Gurney, A. and In't Veld, J.W. (1992),
|The real exchange rate, fiscal policy and the role of wealth: an
analysis of equilibrium in the monetary union', Journal of
Forecasting, forthcoming. Bray, J., Hall, S., Meen, G., Westaway, P. and
Whitley, J.D. (1992), |UK policies, non-price competitiveness, and
convergence to an EMU', ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau
Discussion Paper No.28. Holly, S, and Wade, W. (1989), |Focus:
Supply-side improvements in UK exporting of manufactures', Economic
Outlook 14, 35-37. Landesmann, M. and Snell, A. (1989), |The
consequences of Mrs Thatcher for UK manufacturing exports',
Economic Journal, 99, 1-27. Williamson, J. (1983), The Exchange Rate
System, Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press. Williamson, J. (1991), |FEERs and
the ERM', National Institute Economic Review, No.137,45-50.
Wren-Lewis, S. (1992), |On the analytical foundations of the Fundamental
Equilibrium Exchange Rate', In C.P. Hargreaves (ed), Macroeconomic
Modelling of the Long Run, pp.323-338, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
Wren-Lewis, S., Westaway, P., Soteri, S. and Barrell, R. (1991),
|Evaluating the UK's choice of entry rate into the ERM',
Manchester School, 5 9, 1-22.