European integration and external constraints on social policy: is a social charter necessary?
Ermisch, John
EUROPEAN INTEGRATION AND EXTERNAL CONSTRAINTS ON SOCIAL POLICY: IS A
SOCIAL CHARTER NECESSARY?
The completion of the single European market after 1992 could have
implications for the conduct of social policy in member countries of the
European Community (EC). In particular, more integrated capital and
labour markets could limit member countries' freedom of action in
social policy.
Limitations could arise because businesses are mobile in the longer
term, and an integrated European market will increase their mobility.
The European Commission has expressed concern that industries in
countries with the least social protection would have a competitive
edge, thereby attracting more businesses to these countries and
eventually reducing social protection in other member countries, as a
consequence of economic competition. The European Commission has called
this |social dumping', which creates a tendency for a |levelling
down' of social protection in member countries. Operating in the
opposite direction would be a tendency for workers to leave countries
with poor social protection.
The European Commission's concern with this social dimension
of economic integration, particulary the danger of social dumping, has
been recognised by the European Commission in the |Community Charter of
the Fundamential Social Rights of Workers', or |Social
Charter' for short. In the preamble of the final draft (14
September 1989), the Charter states that |...the completion of the
internal market must offer improvements in the social field for workers
of the European Community, especially in terms of freedom of movement,
living and working conditions, health and safety at work, social
protection, education and training;....' The Social Charter can be
viewed as an attempt to |level up' social protection, assuring that
there is no |retrogression compared with the situation currently
existing in each member state' (as the preamble of the Charter puts
it). The Social Charter's freedom of movement principles also
attempt to improve labour mobility within the EC.
All EC governments other than the UK endorsed the Social Charter in
a |solemn declaration' (on 9 December 1989). The UK government is
concerned that the Social Charter would increase unemployment, and this
concern is examined in the paper.
In order to implement the principles contained in the Charter, the
Commission adopted a |social action programme' in November 1989.
The programme adopts the |principle of subsidiarity', according to which the Community acts where the objectives to be reached can be
achieved more effectively at Community level rather than at national
level. It is, however, possible that the Social Charter itself violates
the principle of subsidiarity.
The purpose of this paper is to examine the conditions under which
social policy would be constrained by European economic integration and
to assess whether a Social Charter is needed. The first section
discusses some principles to follow in deciding whether the EC or a
member state should have the power to make decisions in particular areas
of policy. It provides a framework for interpreting the |principle of
subsidiarity'. The second section examines the potential for a
direct effect of social benefits on the movement of people within the
EC. In the third section, the impact of the taxes used to finance social
policy on the location of businesses and people and the incidence of
these taxes are investigated. The degree of labour mobility in response
to differences in real wages between EC countries is demonstrated to be
crucial in deciding whether a Social Charter is necessary. Thus, a
substantial fourth section of the paper examines the evidence on the
responsiveness of labour mobility, and it suggests little need for a
Social Charter.
1. What level of government for which
functions?
Decisions about government functions, such as the provision of
education or social security, could be made at a number of different
levels of government (for example, at the local council level, at the
national level or by the EC). What is the best level of decision-making
for each function? In order to answer we need a framework for evaluating
what level would be best. It is assumed that collective decisions at
each level are made by majority rule.
The minority on a particular issue or policy suffer a welfare loss
because the majority decision goes against their wishes. Such welfare
losses are reduced by delegating decision-making (power) to communities
that are relatively homogeneous regarding preferences in a particular
policy area. (1) Homogeneity is most nearly approximated at the extreme
local level; that is, |home rule'. Thus, maximum political
consensus requires small political jurisdictions.
Consensus is not, however, the only consideration. If the
population affected by the policy is larger than that
jurisdiction's constituency, its decisions will affect the welfare
of others. Similarly, its population's welfare will be affected by
decisions made in other jurisdictions. Failure to take these effects
into account will result in inefficient decisions (i.e. some people can
be made better off while not making others worse off). Air pollution
control is a clear example. It may improve the air of neighbouring
communities as well as the jurisdiction deciding about it. Ignoring
these benefits results in under-provision of air pollution control. In
economists' jargon, their are |external effects' of community
decisions.
In policy areas in which collective decisions result in benefits or
costs for neighbouring communities, the jurisdiction for decisions
should be large enough to include the total population affected by its
policies. Thus, for some government functions, a jurisdiction much
larger than that justified by |home rule' is required.
Fiscal equivalence
For most goods provided by government it is not feasible to exclude
people who do not pay for the good from consuming it. Air pollution
control is a good example. The trade-off between consensus and external
effects for collective goods such as these can be balanced by defining
political jurisdictions for each collective good so that there is a
match between those who receive the benefits of that good and those who
pay for it. This match has been called the principle of |fiscal
equivalence' (Olson, 1969).
Thus, this principle entails a separate jurisdiction for every
collective good with a unique |catchment area' for its benefits.
(2) When there are decreasing costs per head of providing the particular
collective good, decisions would be made in a jurisdiction consistent
with the principle, but the provision would be contracted out to more
efficient productive units, either public or private. Even in the
absence of contracting-out, the fact that a larger population could
provide the collective good at a lower cost per head is irrelevant if
the benefits of the good do not extend to a larger population. (3)
If, however, there are increasing costs of production, then
provision should be organised in smaller, minimum cost per head
jurisdictions, and, in addition, a system of grants from a larger
jurisdiction, encompassing all beneficiaries of the collective good, to
the smaller government units should be set up. These inter-governmental
grants would be just large enough to compensate the smaller unit for the
external benefits produced by the collective good. Education may be
example of such a good. A very large school system may be too
bureaucratic and cumbersome, but because of migration the benefits of
education extend beyond jurisdictions of a size that would minimise cost
per student.
Redistribution
Social policy is often concerned with redistribution of resources.
Redistribution raises an additional criterion for the best
jurisdictional boundaries: these should contain the appropriate donors
and beneficiaries. Whereas maximal consensus requires population
homogeneity, redistribution requires population heterogeneity,
particularly regarding income.
Mobility of donors and beneficiaries makes it difficult to maintain
the desired population mix for redistribution purposes. This suggests
that jurisdictions for redistributive policies should be defined to
minimise mobility across the boundaries, implying a large jurisdiction
in terms of population covered, perhaps as large as the EC if migration
between member states is responsive to taxes and benefits.
But how are the redistributive goals decided upon? Preferences
concerning these are likely to vary with national/regional
|culture', and average income is also likely to affect these
decisions. For instance, altruism (caring about the living standards of
the less well-off) suggests that higher income regions would want to
redistribute more (the |marginal utility' of a person's own
income declines with income). On the other hand, voters may be more
inclined to vote for more redistribution if they feel they may need it
some day, due to uncertainty about their own income, so that poorer
regions may vote for more redistribution. (4)
Whatever the reason that different regions/countries choose
different amounts of redistribution, welfare losses would result if
redistribution policies are decided (by majority rule) at a broader
level of government, like the EC, rather than in jurisdictions more
homogeneous in terms of cultural background and living standards. (5)
Within Europe there are many distinctive cultures and a wide range of
living standards. Consensus on redistributive aims would favour each of
these setting up a regional or national government for redistribution
purposes.
There is a conflict between |home rule' and achieving a given
region's or nation's redistributional goals if there is
mobility across jurisdictional boundaries in response to the taxes and
benefits used to carry out the redistribution. Such mobility would need
to be taken into account by jurisdictions in deciding the levels of
social benefits and taxes (for example, see Rothenberg, 1970). If,
therefore, we wish to determine whether the current member countries of
the EC will be constrained in their redistribution policies,
international mobility within the EC after 1992 is a crucial issue.
The next section examines the extent to which European people may
move across national borders in response to differences in social
benefits. This discussion ignores the impacts of the method of financing
these benefits on mobility and social policy constraints, but that is
taken up in the third section.
2. Impact of social benefits on migration
There are no studies of migration within Europe which measure the
impact of social benefits on migration flows, and in any case the
responsiveness of migration to economic variables may change after 1992.
It is, however, possible to use studies of migration between states of
the United States to infer the maximum responsiveness that can be
expected in Europe after 1992.
The measured response of inter-state migration in the USA to social
benefits is likely to provide a maximum for Europe because America is
much more homogeneous than Europe, with a common language and culture
throughout the states, and it has had a more mobile population than most
European countries. Coupled with the factors favouring mobility is a
large variation in social benefits among states. For instance, payments
under the main welfare benefits programme, Aid to Families with
Dependent Children (AFDC), which primarily helps one parent families,
vary enormously among states. In 1979, the state maximum monthly AFDC
benefit payment for a family of one needy adult and three dependent
children varied from $120 in Mississipi to $524 in Vermont (Blank, 1988,
Appendix I). Even in neighboring states like Wisconsin and Illinois, the
difference in the maximum payment was $195 in 1979.
This wide variation in AFDC benefits certainly provides large
incentives for the population of one parent families to move between
states. Other than education, it is the largest social expenditure
programme in states and the benefits to recipients are transparent
compared to the benefits of many other social programmes. These
considerations suggest that we are more likely to find migration in
response to AFDC benefits than to any other social policy. On the other
hand, one parent families are less mobile than many other groups, such
as young men prone to unemployment. Nevertheless, it appears likely that
the geographic mobility response to inter-state differences in AFDC
benefits is likely to be the higher than the mobility response to any
social policy difference found between countries in Europe.
One attempt to measure this response studied the movement of
families receiving AFDC between three groups of states: high, medium and
low AFDC benefit states (Gramlich and Laren, 1984, table 4). The rates
of migration (|transition rates') between these groups of states
over a five-year period are shown in table 1. It indicates that while
inter-state migration is a rare event (less than 10 per cent moved
between the groups of states in the five-year period), when AFDC
families do move between states, they are much more likely to go to a
state with higher AFDC benefits (note that the entries below the
principal diagonal in table 1 are more than twice as large as those
above the diagonal). Gramlich and Laren point out that even though
migration is very sluggish, this blas in movement can alter the
inter-state distribution of the AFDC population substantially over time.
Blank (1988) takes a more direct approach, using data on individual
one parent families headed by the mother to study the joint decision of
whether or not to receive AFDC and the region in which to live. (6) Her
analysis makes it possible to estimate directly the responsiveness of
the probability of leaving a region to differences in AFDC benefits and
wages. It suggests that a 10 per cent increase in AFDC benefits in a
region increases the probability of remaining in the region by 1 per
cent (an |elasticity' of 0.1). This is not a very large impact, but
it could still be important in the longer run.
To investigate this, the hypothetical |equilibrium' proportion
of the AFDC population in each group of states implied by the migration
rates in table 1 is computed. These are |equilibrium' in the sense
that when these proportions are achieved they would be maintained, (7)
and they are shown in the first line of table 2. Blank's estimate
of the impact of benefits on the probability of moving to another region
is used in conjunction with the pattern of migration rates in table 1 to
estimate how the hypothetical equilibrium distribution changes when AFDC
benefits change in one region. The impact of a 10 per cent increase in
benefits in low benefit states on the equilibrium distribution of the
AFDC population is examined. The second line of table 2 shows the
resulting equilibrium distribution. It appears that even in the very
long run the impact of a 10 per cent rise in AFDC benefits is small. (8)
Furthermore, it takes a very long time to converge to the new
distribution. It would take about 40 years for half of the adjustment in
the proportion of the AFDC population in low benefit states to the 10
per cent rise in benefits to take place.
As suggested above, this small and sluggish change in people's
location in response to benefits is likely to be much higher than would
take place in Europe. Language and culture represent formidable barriers
to movement between European countries in response to differences in
social benefits. Moreover, responses to differences in social welfare
payments like AFDC are likely to be larger than to differences in other
social benefits, because the benefits of welfare payments to individual
families are large and transparent relative to other social policies.
Although one parent families are less mobile than other groups,
such as young unemployed men, this analysis suggests that such
differences between member countries of the EC in social policies would
not directly encourage much migration between countries. This favours
autonomy for individual countries in deciding social policy.
There could, however, be indirect effects which work through the
taxes that need to be levied to finance the social policies (assuming
that other public expenditure is not reduced to compensate). Taxes can
affect after-tax returns to capital, which is mobile between countries.
They also may affect take-home pay, and even though there is little
responsiveness to social benefits by the population for whom social
benefits are an important part of their income, there may still be large
responsiveness by the population to net real wage differences. This
would be the case when the part of the population receiving large social
benefits is small and/or different from the rest of the population. For
instance, the mobility of poor people, for whom these benefits are
particularly relevant, may be constrained by their poverty because of
the costs of migrating to another country and borrowing constraints.
3. Impact of taxes on location of economic activity
The taxation used to pay for collective goods and redistribution
could constrain social policy because businesses and people may move in
response to net (after tax) returns and wages respectively, and
governments take this responsiveness into account in social
policy-making. The incidence of the costs of providing the collective
goods and redistribution also depends on the mobility responses and the
type of tax used.
In this section, we focus on the effects of taxation, ignoring any
impact of the benefits of the social expenditure on location. The
benefits are likely to be small for firms, and the previous section
suggests that they are also probably not an important factor in
people's migration between member countries. Taxes on labour
(payroll taxes), capital (corporate or property taxes), or products (VAT on the |origin principle') are examined first.
Labour mobility and the effects of differences in indirect taxes
Payroll taxes, like employers' National Insurance contributions
in Britain, are a common method of financing pensions and social
security in European countries. The economic analysis of tax incidence
and industrial location can be used to investigate the impact of the tax
on industrial location. (9) Other laws and regulations that increase the
cost of labour, such as employment protection legislation, act as an
implicit tax on the use of labour. As such, they would have effects
similar to a payroll tax.
The analysis assumes, as is very plausible, that capital is
perfectly mobile, in the sense that the after-tax return on capital is
equalised acros s countries. It is also likely that the development of a
single market increases consumer responsiveness to relative prices, and
this is taken into account in the analysis. (10)
When workers move in response to differences in pay between
countries, then a higher payroll tax in a country discourages capital
investment in the country. Although the tax on labour encourages capital
to come in to substitute for higher cost labour, the tax on labour also
raises the cost of production, which reduces demand for the product and
production, thereby discouraging capital investment. The latter effect
dominates when the price elasticity of demand for the country's
products is larger than the elasticity of substitution between capital
and labour in production, and it is plausible that this would be the
case in the integrated European product markets.
The more responsive are workers to pay differentials, the more that
the tax discourages investment. If workers are very responsive, they are
better able to avoid the tax burden, placing a larger burden on capital,
thereby discouraging capital investment in the country levying the
higher payroll tax. Taxes on capital or production also have a stronger
discouraging effect on capital investment, the more that worker mobility
responds to pay differentials. (11)
Apparently, this is the effect that worried the European Commission
when they expressed concern about |social dumping'. Social policy
formulation would be constrained by this potential movement of
businesses in response to higher taxes, and it would be likely to result
in lower levels of social benefits and protection (for example, lower
social security benefits and pensions). The Social Charter was the
Commission's response. Its |levelling up' of social protection
would keep businesses in the countries with higher benefits (the richer
countries) while protecting those benefits.
The degree of worker mobility is crucial in determining whether
there are such constraints on social policy and a need for a Social
Charter to guard against social dumping. Taking the extreme case, in
which workers are not responsive to pay differences between countries, a
higher payroll tax in a country would not affect business location
there. Workers in that country would see their wages fall by the amount
of the additional payroll tax; in other words, workers would bear the
full burden of the tax. (12) This would come about because the demand
for labour would fall as a result of the higher payroll tax. At each
quantity of labour, businesses would offer a wage that is lower by the
amount of the increment to the tax. If workers' mobility responded
to pay differentials, some would leave the country, thereby reducing the
supply of labour and offsetting some of the fall in the wage. If,
however, workers were not mobile, their wage would be remain lower by
the amount of the additional tax. As the wage cum tax paid by firms
would be the same as before, there would be no incentive for capital to
leave the country.
This account assumes that wages in the higher tax country can fall
relative to other countries. If, however, such falls are resisted, then
unemployment would increase in the higher tax country. But note that
declines in wages relative to other countries need not entail a decline
in a country's real wage, only a smaller increase than in other
countries.
Although it may be extreme to assume that workers are immobile, low
responsiveness to pay differentials between countries is plausible, even
after 1992, because of the language and cultural differences between
member countries of the EC. Rational workers would move to equalise
their personal (or family) welfare across countries. As not being able
to speak one's native language nor live in a familiar culture
represent large reductions in personal welfare, it would take much
larger pay in another country to compensate for this loss in welfare. In
the aggregate, therefore, it is likely to take large pay differences to
elicit small amounts of movement between countries, and the evidence
presented in the next section of the paper supports this hypothesis.
In these circumstances of low worker mobility between EC countries,
the richer countries, with more social protection, are not putting
themselves at a competitive disadvantage relative to poorer countries.
More social protection, paid for by higher payroll taxes, is offset by
wages being lower than they would otherwise be. In other words, a
country's workers have paid for their social protection. As noted
earlier, regulations that increase labour costs can be considered as an
implicit tax on labour, like a payroll tax. The costs of such
regulations are, therefore, also passed on to the workers when labour
mobility between countries is not responsive to pay differentials, and
these regulations do not affect capital investment patterns.
Payroll taxes are preferable among the indirect taxes in that they
distort capital allocation among countries least, particularly when
labour mobility is low. For a given tax yield, taxes on production or
capital usually discourage capital investment in the taxing country more
than a payroll tax. When labour mobility is not very responsive to pay
differentials, this is clearly the case, with taxes on capital
discouraging investment most (for a given tax yield). (13) This is why
the discussion has focussed on the effects of the payroll tax, and only
mentioned the effects of taxes on production and capital in passing. The
alternative of direct taxation is explored next.
Labour mobility and the effects of differences in direct taxes
The sensitivity of capital movements to differences in after-tax
rates of return suggests that income from capital should be taxed on the
residence principle; that is, it should be taxed in the country in which
the owner lives, not in the country in which the capital is invested.
This makes investors indifferent between domestic and foreign assets
when their pre-tax rates of return are the same, so that their pattern
of investment among countries is not affected by different direct taxes
on capital income. (14) Such differences could affect in which country
capital owners live, but this will not affect the allocation or cost of
capital among countries.
Differences in direct taxes on earning (e.g. income taxes or
employees' payroll taxes) can, however, affect the allocation of
both workers and capital among countries. As with indirect taxes, the
effects crucially depend on the mobility of workers. The effect on
capital investment in a country of a higher tax rate on earnings is
exactly the same as the effect of a higher payroll tax (see Ermisch
1991). It discourages capital investment in the higher tax country when
workers' mobility responds to pay differentials. It does so by
encouraging workers to leave the country, which raises pre-tax wages and
the cost of production in the higher tax country relative to that in
other countries. The size of this effect depends on the degree to which
people respond to differences in after-tax pay between countries. If
they are not very responsive, then the discouraging effect on capital
investment is small. In the extreme, when they do not respond at all,
neither capital investment nor pre-tax wages are affected.
Thus, as with indirect taxes, differences in direct taxes are not
likely to have a large effect on capital investment, because of the
likely low responsiveness of workers' mobility to differences
between countries in after-tax pay. In other words, |social
dumping' is unlikely to be important, social policy will not be
constrained by the potential mobility of businesses, and the need for a
Social Charter is questionable.
Impact of a Social Charter
Suppose that the Social Charter is implemented nevertheless. What
would be its effects? Not surprisingly, these depend on the mobility of
labour.
The Social Charter would put pressure on poorer countries to raise
their social benefits, and assuming that other public expenditure is not
reduced to compensate, this would lead to an increase in taxes to pay
for them. The analysis of the incidence of taxes has implications for
who will bear the burden of introducing the Social Charter. Whether the
industries in a country are, on average, capital-intensive or
labour-intensive is important in judging the incidence of a particular
tax. The poorer countries of the EC also tend to have more
labour-intensive industries.
Even when labour moves in response to pay differentials, higher
payroll taxes generally reduce wages. This is because the additional tax
encourages substitution of capital for labour, thereby reducing the
demand for labour. There is also an output effect, which operates
through the responsiveness of product demand to the price of the
product. This output effect could work in the opposite direction to the
substitution effect if production in the country raising the tax is
capital-intensive, but when production in the taxing country is
labour-intensive, payroll taxes definitely reduce wages. With
labour-intensive production, product taxes also reduce wages, and taxes
on capital are more likely to reduce wages, the more labour-intensive is
production.
Higher direct taxes on earnings can also reduce pre-tax wages in
the tax-raising country when production is labour-intensive and labour
is mobile in response to differences in take home pay. But, in these
circumstances, pre-tax wages would fall by more in the countries
receiving the labour whose migration was encouraged by the higher direct
tax rate. Thus, workers in the labour-importing countries would be
adversely affected by the higher direct tax rate in a labour-intensive
country. This scenario is likely when the demand for the product is very
responsive to its relative price and labour is mobile.
Thus, higher social benefits in poorer (labour-intensive) countries
are very likely to lead to a reduction in take home pay (or a rise in
unemployment) in these countries. If higher social benefits are paid for
with higher payroll or direct taxes, then low mobility in response to
pay differentials means that the cost of these benefits would primarily
be born by the country's workers in the form of lower after-tax
pay.
Wage rigidity
The analysis has taken a |long term' perspective. It has assumed
that adjustments in relative pay between countries occur eventually.
Slow adjustment of a country's relative wage to an increase in a
tax or regulatory cost would complicate the adjustment process,
particularly when migration responds to unemployment differentials, and
increase the cost of adjustment, in terms of higher unemployment, but it
would not alter the main conclusions.
If wages remained rigid however, capital investment would be
discouraged in the country raising its payroll tax. If mobility was not
responsive to differences in unemployment rates between countries, that
country's population would bear the entire burden in terms of
higher unemployment. If the unemployed were much more mobile than the
employed, or people's mobility is much more responsive to
unemployment rate differentials than relative wages, then a higher
payroll tax (or regulatory cost) would affect wages and/or unemployment
rates in other countries through emigration of the unemployed. In these
circumstances, social dumping could occur, and this could affect
decisions about social provision.
But even if labour mobility responds strongly to unemployment rate
differentials, if higher social provision were paid for by higher direct
taxes on earnings and worker mobility was not responsive to relative
after-tax wages between countries, neither capital investment nor
unemployment would be affected. As before, a country's workers
would bear the entire burden of higher social provision in terms of
lower after-tax pay.
Even a combination of wage rigidity, payroll tax finance and
responsiveness of migration to unemployment rate differentials does not
imply that a Social Charter is needed. If a country's relative
wages are inflexible, say because of pay bargaining arrangements, it
would be more efficient to reform these arrangements in the countries
concerned than to impose a Social Charter on all of the countries of the
EC.
4. Effects of relative pay on migration
It has been argued above that the responsiveness of migration to
differences in after-tax pay between countries is crucial in deciding
whether social policy will be constrained and whether a Social Charter
is needed. What does the evidence suggest?
Size and direction of migration within the EC
The Treaty of Rome, which established the European Economic Community
in 1957, secured freedom of movement among the original six members of
the EC by 1 January 1970, at the latest. (15) Despite this legal
liberalisation, mobility among the original six members has hardly
increased since the formation of the Common Market. The total number of
workers from one of the original six who were working in the country of
another original member increased from about half a million before 1960
to about 830,000 in 1968, after which it remained constant until about
1980. During 1980-84, it decreased to about 650,000 (Straubhaar 1988,
Figure 1), which represents only 0.75 per cent of the labour force of
the original 6 EC countries in 1984.
The relatively small intra-EC migration cannot be attributed to an
absence of real wage differentials within the EC. For instance,
depending on the measure of real wages used, the standard deviation of
real wages ranged from 12 to 20 per cent of mean real wages in the
original EC countries during the 1970s; German real wages were 35-50 per
cent higher than French real wages in this period, and Italian real
wages were much lower than those in France (Tovias 1983). Thus, the
migration response by workers in EC countries to pay differentials has
been relatively small.
While small, the fact that two-thirds to three-quarters of these
migrant workers from another EC country were Italians does indicate
movement from low wage to high wage countries within the EC.
Furthermore, during 1973-80, the number of Italians working in another
of the original six EC countries working declined, which is consistent
with the increase in Italy's real wages relative to other EC
countries.
In contrast to the Italian movement throughout the original EC
countries, other intra-EC migration was regional. Workers from Belgium,
the Netherlands and Luxembourg primarily moved within the Benelux
countries, and French (German) migrants mainly went to regions in
Germany (France), Belgium and the Netherlands near the national border
(Straubhaar 1988). Moreover, the Italian northward migration was
occurring before the formation of the EC. These developments suggest
that the formation of the EC did little to change the patterns of
European labour migration.
Examination of the gross inflows to and outflows from the United
Kingdom suggests that the UK's membership of the EC also had little
immediate effect on migration between it and the other countries of the
EC. The UK, as well as Denmark and Ireland, joined the EC in January
1973. Even though movement between the UK and the rest of the EC should
have been freer after the UK joined, Chart 1 shows no change in
migratory flows between the UK and the rest of the EC in the years
following 1973. (16) During the 1970s there was a fairly steady outflow
from the UK to the rest of the EC.
After 1981, that changed. There was a sharp increase in inflows to
the UK from the rest of the EC in 1982, and during 1984-86 flows in both
directions increased dramatically, with net flows favouring the UK. In
these years, the EC's percentages of all out-migration from or
in-migration to the UK also increased sharply (see Chart 2). While
movement in both directions declined somewhat during 1986-89, it was
much higher than during the period before 1982.
Greece joined the EC in January 1981 and Spain and Portugal in
January 1986. There was a seven-year transitional period for Greece,
after which Greeks have been allowed to work in any country of their
choice in the EC. New emigrants from Spain and Portugal seeking
wage-earning employment in other EC countries require prior
authorisation up to the end of 1992.
These restrictions could be damping large potential movement from
the Spain and Portugal, and they may have restricted Greek emigration up
to 1988. Real hourly earnings during 1986-89 were only about of 30 per
cent of UK levels in Portugal and 45 per cent in Greece (Ray 1990).
These differentials provide large incentives for northern migration from
the new southern members of the EC. The situation of Italy at the
formation of the EC was somewhat similar, and so its experience after
the formation of the EC may be relevant to these new members. While
migration from Italy to the rest of the EC did increase during the
1960s, it was noted above that the scale of migration remained small.
More recent information available on EC countries' migration
is primarily aggregate data, particularly net migration to or from a
country. The inferences about the sensitivity of migration to relative
economic opportunities that can be drawn from such data are very
limited. As the market conditions for workers of different skills can
vary, these conditions could play an important role in affecting the
movement of people even though net migration is near zero. Nevertheless,
if movement is sensitive to real wage differences between countries and
large differences exist, then a bias favouring migration to high wage
countries and from low wage countries of the EC is likely to be present
in the aggregate data.
Table 3 groups countries of the EC by the level of their total
hourly labour costs in manufacturing during 1986-89, as estimated from
surveys by the Swedish Employers' Confederation (Ray, 1990). It
shows the maximum and minimum annual net migration rates (as a per cent
of the average population that year) during the 1980s and the cumulative
migration rate during 1980-88 (as a per cent of beginning 1989
population). As expected, the high wage countries (other than Belgium)
were net importers of labour during the 1980s, but the low wage
countries were as well. Greece and Portugal, the countries with the
lowest wages, have been net importers of labour since the mid-1970s,
following a long period (at least back to 1960) in which they were
exporting labour.
Thus, at least within the EC, net migration does not appear to have
particularly favoured the high wage countries in recent years.
Furthermore, with the exception of Irish emigration, the cumulative net
flows over the 9-year period are not very large, adding at most 2 per
cent to the population (Portugal). The 4 per cent reduction in the
population of the Republic of Ireland because of emigrations is,
however, fairly large, and Irish emigration is discussed further below.
Taking the entire period of UK membership of the EC (1973-89),
cumulative migration between the UK and the rest of the EC was virtually
in balance (+ 600 people). (17) It is clear from Chart 1 that this long
term net balance has come about because, in the period since the low
wage countries of Greece, Spain and Portugal became members, movement
between the UK and the rest of the EC increased and the UK
PHOTO : Chart 1. Migration between UK and EC
PHOTO : Chart 2. Migration between UK and EC became be a net
importer of labour from other EC countries (a net balance of 56,500
during 1981-89).
In that real wages in the UK are toward the middle of the range
among the present membership of the EC, this pattern could be consistent
with intra-EC movement toward higher wage countries. (18) Before these
low wage countries became members, the UK was one of the low wage
countries of the EC (along with Ireland), and that may explain the net
movement from the UK to the rest of the EC during the 1970s.
Nevertheless, the small scale of movement, even in recent years,
suggests either low responsiveness of people to real wage differences
among EC countries, or, at best, very sluggish responses.
Reinforcing this conclusion is the fact that a relatively large
proportions of these migrants are returning to their original country.
For instance, during 1979-88, 45 per cent of the migrants coming into
the UK were British citizens, and 35 per cent of people leaving the UK
were not British citizens. Focussing on migration between the UK and
other countries of the EC, 50 per cent of people coming into the UK from
the rest of the EC in 1988 were British citizens, and 28 per cent of
people leaving the UK for other countries of the EC were citizens of EC
countries other than the UK.
The failure of the pattern or volume of migration among EC
countries to change much after the formation of the EC may primarily
reflect a tendency for trade in commodities to substitute for movements
in factors of production, particularly labour migration. The formation
of the EC increased trade between EC countries substantially, rising
from 30 per cent to 52 per cent of all EC-trade between 1958 and 1973.
According to the theoretical arguments of Mundell (1957), freer trade
would reduce migration flows. Indeed, Straubhaar (1988) finds a
significant negative correlation between intra-EC trade flows and
intra-EC migration flows during 1958-80. (19) Markusen (1983)
demonstrated a number of conditions under which freer trade would
increase labour migration, but the similar production technologies and
preferences among the original six EC countries (with the possible
exception of Italy) were probably conducive to trade and labour
migration being substitutes. Production technologies of the new southern
members of the EC may be sufficiently different from the northern
countries to create conditions under which freer trade could increase
south-north migration within the EC (see Markusen, 1983).
Migration into the EC
The big change in European migration was the increase in migration to
the EC from non-EC countries, particularly from countries that were to
join the EC later, namely Greece, Spain and Portugal, but also from
Turkey and North Africa. The Portuguese and Northern Africans mainly
went to France, the Greeks and Turks primarily to Germany, and the
Spanish to France, and to a lesser extent Germany. As consequence, only
about one-fifth of migrants working in the original EC countries in 1974
were from another of the original six members.
Much of this migration into the EC was |organised migration'
through recruitment bureau of the host countries in the countries of
origin. Thus, the size and direction of this movement was primarily
determined by policy in the destination countries rather than by
spontaneous movement in response to economic opportunities. When
European (and world) economic growth slowed after 1973, this policy went
into reverse, encouraging large reductions in the number of foreign
workers in the original EC countries.
But not all foreign nationalities returned home to the same extent.
Between 1973 and 1980, there were declines in the number of Spaniards
(200,000), Portuguese (100,000) and Greeks (150,000) working in EC
countries, but not in the number of Turkish and North African workers
(Molle and Van Mourik 1988). That is, workers from the poorest countries
were more likely to stay on in the EC countries. In 1984, about 5.5 per
cent of the total active labour force living in the original EC member
countries were migrants from other countries. Only one-fifth came from
another of the original six members, a further fifth came from one of
the new members (Greece, Spain or Portugal), another fifth came from
Turkey, and the remaining two-fifths came from other countries,
primarily Yugoslavia, North Africa and non-EC European countries
(Straubhaar, 1988, p.51).
The organised nature of this migration does not preclude the
destination pattern of migration from countries outside the EC being
responsive to relative pay. Indeed, econometric analysis indicates that
the larger the difference between average wages in a northern European
destination country and a southern European or north African origin
country, the more foreign workers from that southern country present in
that northern European country in 1980 (Molle and Van Mourik 1988). (20)
This analysis suggests that a 1 per cent increase in an EC
country's real wage differential would increase its labour supply
by 0.3 per cent, purely because of the increase in migration from non-EC
countries (an elasticity of 0.3). But this estimates of responsiveness
clearly reflects the behaviour of EC governments in the 1960s and 1970s,
and their difficult experience in assimilating foreign |guest
workers' is very likely to reduce the future responsiveness of
migration into the EC to real wages there. The reduction in foreign
workers in EC countries after 1973 was probably not only a cyclical response, but also an attempt by EC governments to reduce reliance on
foreign workers.
Variation in real wages among countries
It may appear that the sensitivity of migration to wage differentials
could be gauged indirectly by examining the variation in real wages
among countries of the EC and its change over time. Perfect labour
mobility would tend to equalise real wages across countries, as people
moved in response to real wage differences. But, as noted earlier, free
trade can serve as a substitute for mobility of labour and capital.
Under certain conditions, it also tends to equalise wages across
countries in a customs union like the EC (Samuelson, 1948, 1949). Recent
research (Mokhtari and Rassekh, 1989) suggests that freer trade among 16
OECD countries has made the most significant contribution to reducing
the variation in real wages among these countries. Thus, less variation
in real wages among EC countries over time need not imply that labour is
mobile in response to real wage differentials.
Failure to exhibit a tendency toward convergence of real wages
would, however, suggest low responsiveness of labour mobility to real
wage differences between countries. While Tovias (1982) finds evidence
of convergence in labour costs among five original EC members between
the mid-1950s and mid-1960s, this process was reversed during the 1970s.
(21) In the latter period, labour costs diverged, thereby suggesting
poor responsiveness of migration to wage differentials, as well as
factors (eg. increasing returns to scale) working against the tendency
for freer trade to produce convergence of labour costs.
Direct estimates of the responsiveness of migration
So far we have tried to infer the degree of responsiveness of
migration to real wage differentials by examining the size and pattern
of European migration and whether there has been convergence in real
wages. This section uses studies of migration between particular
countries and of internal migration within countries to estimate the
responsiveness, or |elasticity', of a country's labour supply
to real wage differentials.
Migration between European countries Lianos (1972) studies Greek
migration to West Germany, Australia, Canada and the United States during 1959-66. Focussing on Greek emigration to Germany, his analysis
(his equation 9') suggest that a once and for all increase of 10
per cent in the German-Greek real wage differential would eventually
decrease the Greek labour force by 0.67 per cent, or an elasticity of
0.067. (22) This response in the labour force is only that arising from
a increase in gross migration from Greece to Germany. It ignores changes
in return migration from Germany to Greece, which would probably
decline. Also, if it was a fall in the wage in Greece that increased the
German-Greek wage differential, that this response also ignores changes
in migration between Greece and other countries as a consequence of
changes in wage differentials. Thus, this elasticity measure may
understate the total responsiveness of the Greek labour force to pay
differentials between Greece and other countries. (23)
Analysis of the response of Irish migration to real wages in the
Republic of Ireland relative to those in Great Britain may provide a
better measure of the total labour force response. During the 1950s and
1960s, approximately four-fifths of Irish emigration was to Britain.
Thus, the British-Irish wage differential is likely to be by far the
most important pay differential affecting total Irish net migration.
Walsh's (1974) econometric study of net emigration from Ireland
during 1951 - 71 suggests that a one-off 10 per cent increase in Irish
real wages relative to those in Britain would ultimately increase the
Irish labour force by about 1.5 to 3 per cent. (24) In other words, the
elasticity of the Irish labour force with respect to Irish real wages
relative to Britain's appears to have been between 0.15 and 0.3
during this period. (25)
Walsh (1974) also finds that the unemployment rate in Ireland
relative to that in the UK had a strong effect on Irish migration, and
this is confirmed by extension of the analysis of Irish migration beyond
1971. The turnaround in Irish migration during the 1970s, when Ireland
became a net importer of people, stimulated a re-examination of the
analysis of the sensitivity of Irish migration to economic conditions.
Keenan (1981) reports on a better series for Irish net migration, and
have used the data that he provides to estimate models of Irish net
migration which include the experience of the 1970s. (26)
These estimates indicate that the unemployment rate in Ireland
relative to that in the UK is more important than relative pay in
explaining the large changes in Irish net migration. (27) Indeed, the
high unemployment rate in Ireland relative to the UK appears to have
been primarily responsible for large emigration from Ireland during
1951-71, when net emigration totalled 543,000, amounting to half the
Irish labour force in 1971 (Walsh 1974). Chart 3 shows the Irish net
migration (as a proportion of the labour force) predicted by my
estimated model if the unemployment rate in Ireland had remained
constant at twice the UK rate, and actual net migration. The difference
between the two series during 1955-71 shows the contribution of high
Irish unemployment to net emigration. (28) It appears that 85 per cent
of Irish net emigration during this period was attributable to the high
Irish unemployment rate relative to the UK rate.
The estimated model implies elasticities of the Irish labour force
with respect to Irish real wages relative to British of about 0.1, which
is only slightly lower than those implied by Walsh's (1974)
analysis of the earlier period, using a different measure of net
migration. Thus, while there is evidence that migration between
countries that are linguistically and culturally similar can be very
responsive to relative unemployment conditions, the responsiveness to
relative pay is fairly small. Between countries less similar in these
respects, the responsiveness of the labour force to relative pay is
likely to be even smaller.
Internal migration in European countries It is very likely that
estimates of the sensitivity of migration within a country to
differential economic opportunities would overstate the sensitivity of
migration between EC countries, because linguistic and cultural
homogeneity within a country favours mobility. American studies have
often suggested that interstate migration is responsive to earnings
differences between states, (29) but, as noted earlier, American people
tend to be much more mobile than Europeans. A more relevant upper bound
on the responsiveness of migration and labour supply to differences in
pay can be obtained from studies of inter-regional migration within
European countries.
The study of net migration from southern to northern Italy during
1958-74 by Salvatore (1977) provides information from which it is
possible to estimate the responsiveness of the southern Italian labour
force to north-south pay and unemployment differentials. During this
period, average per capita income in the South was about 60 per cent of
that of the North of Italy, and 1 million workers (about 17 per cent of
the Southern labour force) emigrated from the poorer South of Italy to
the North. (30) Again, unemployment differential appear to be more
important in accounting for changes in migration than pay differences.
Salvatore's (1977) analysis suggests that a 10 per cent increase in
the North's real wage relative to the South's would reduce the
South's labour force by 0.7 per cent, or an elasticity of 0.07.
(31) This is only slightly smaller than the elasticity suggested by the
experience of Irish migration, and it is very near the estimate from a
recent study of internal migration in Great Britain (Pissarides and
McMaster 1990).
This study of migration among Scotland, Wales and the 7 planning
regions of England (the South East and East Anglia are grouped together)
during 1961-82 allows estimation of the responsiveness of a
region's labour supply to relative pay and unemployment rates.
Using their estimated migration equation, in the long run, a 10 per cent
higher regional wage (relative to other regions) increases regional
labour supply to 0.6 per cent (an |elasticity' of 0.06). Their
estimate of the labour force response to regional unemployment
differentials also indicates a very sluggish response. For instance, it
takes 10 years for migration to eliminate half of a regional
unemployment rate differential.
Other studies of migration in Great Britain have produced mixed
results concerning the effect of relative wages. Hughes and McCormick
(1990) find, using data on individuals, that migrants move from regions
of relatively low levels of real wages to regions with higher real
wages. They find that regional wage differentials particularly affect
the destination of people who have decided to migrate, but regional real
wage levels do not appear to affect significantly the decision to leave
a region. Pissarides and Wadsworth (1987) find that a region's
relative wage has a significant effect on the migration decision, and a
number of studies of net migration between Scotland and the rest of the
UK also suggest that regional earnings are an important influence on
migration. (32) Muellbauer and Murphy (1988) also provide evidence that
higher relative earnings encourage migration to the South East. On the
other hand, Mohlo's (1984) analysis of inter-regional migration
flows suggests that relative earnings do not affect migration patterns
significantly.
The aggregate migration equations in some of these studies have the
level of a region's relative wage as an explanatory variable,
rather than the change in the relative wage used by Pissarides and
McMaster (1990). Presumably they are meant to suggest how labour supply
adjust to wage differentials resulting from disequilibrium, but such an
estimated net migration equation is not measuring the response of labour
supply to relative pay, but rather the equilibriating compensating wage
differentials, under the maintained assumption of perfect mobility. (33)
Clearly, we do not need any econometric estimates of elasticities if we
adopt this maintained assumption.
If regional wage differentials primarily compensate for other
differences between regions (for example, lower pay in regions with
nicer climates), then wage differentials would not affect migration. For
instance, Pissarides and McMaster's (1990) analysis suggests that,
in the long run, higher than average regional wages compensate for
higher than average unemployment. A combination of disequilibrium and
compensating regional wage differentials may explain the mixed results
in estimating the effect of the level of a region's relative wage
on migration. These other British migration studies provide insufficient
information to calculate the elasticity of regional labour supply with
respect to a region's relative wage.
As the elasticity estimates from the internal migration studies are
likely to be an upper bound on the responsiveness of a country's
labour supply to its relative wage, it appears that workers'
responsiveness to inter-country pay differences is likely to be small.
Estimates from Italy and Great Britain suggest elasticities of less than
0.1, and the studies of Irish and Greek migration discussed above also
suggest elasticities in this range. The Irish case is also likely to
overstate the responsiveness of labour supply to relative pay between
other European countries, because of the linguistic and cultural
similarity of Ireland and Great Britain, to which a large proportion of
migrants went, and the long tradition of emigration from Ireland.
5. Conclusions
While clearly not conclusive, the limited evidence available suggest
that the mobility of workers between member countries of the EC is not
likely to be very sensitive to differences between countries in social
benefits or after-tax pay. In these circumstances, if relative wages
between countries are allowed to adjust, higher payroll or direct taxes
in a country only have a small discouraging effect on capital
investment, and the discouraging effects of taxes on capital and on
production are also much smaller. In some countries, pay bargaining
arrangements may impede relative wage adjustment. But, if this is the
case, it would be more efficient to reform these arrangements than to
impose a social charter on EC members.
When, as is preferable, social benefits are paid for through
payroll taxes and/or direct taxes, the small responsiveness of labour
mobility to pay differentials also implies that workers in each country
bear virtually the entire burden of the taxes. In that they pay for and
receive the benefits exclusively, decisions concerning the level of
social benefits are best left to the population residing in each
country. The option of voting and paying for higher social benefits is
already open to those countries with poorer social protection, and the
decision is not constrained by the forces of economic competition.
Imposition of higher social benefits on such countries, through the
Social Charter, would, therefore, reduce the welfare of the majority of
the population in these countries. In other words, member countries of
the EC should be given autonomy in setting their social policies,
including those involving redistribution. A Social Charter does not
appear to be needed.
The argument by the UK government that the Social Charter would
raise unemployment is consistent with the analysis here if a
country's wages relative to other countries are not allowed to fall
when it raises taxes to pay for better social benefits. When relative
wages can adjust, higher social benefits are paid for by low after-tax
pay in the country rather than higher unemployment.
The conclusion that member countries should be given autonomy in
social policy follows from the lack of responsiveness of workers'
mobility to differences in social benefits or take home pay. The Social
Charter also attempts to encourage labour mobility between member
countries. While all of the attempts at harmonisation in the Charter
work in this direction, it particularly provides that |The right of
freedom of movement shall enable any worker to engage in any occupation
or profession in the Community in accordance with the principles of
equal treatment as regard access to employment, working conditions and
social protection in the host country.' (para.2). It goes on to
call for |Elimination of obstacles arising from non-recognition of
diplomas or equivalent occupational qualifications;' (para.3).
It is unclear how effective these provision would be in increasing
worker responsiveness to differences in pay and benefits. If they are
effective, then we may need to reconsider the need for the other aspects
of the Social Charter. But the experience of migration after the
formation of the EC and the addition of new members in 1973 suggests
that large changes in the responsiveness of migration to differential
economic opportunities in EC countries is unlikely.
REFERENCES
Adams, D.W. (1980a), |Migration from Scotland to the rest of the
United Kingdom', Discussion Paper
10, Economics and Statistics Unit, Scottish Office, Edinburgh.
Adams, D.W. (1980b), |Migration from Scotland to the rest of the U.K.
Revisited', Discussion Paper
Economics and Statistics Unit, Scottish Office, Edinburgh. Blank,
R.M. (1988), |The effect of welfare and wage levels on the location
decisions of
female-headed households', Journal of Urban Economics,
24:186-211. Ermisch, J.F. (1991), |Labour migration and the incidence of
taxes', paper presented to the Fourth
Annual Conference of the European Society for Population Economics,
Pisa, June. Flatters, F., Henderson, V. and Mieszkowski, P. (1974),
|Public goods, efficiency, and regional
fiscal equalization', Journal of Public Economics, 3:99-112.
Gramlich, E.M. and Laren, D.S. (1984), |Migration and income
redistribution responsibilities',
Journal of Human Resources, 19:487-511. Graves, P.E. and Linneman,
P.D. (1979), |Household migration: theoretical and empirical
results',
Journal of Urban Economics, 6:383-404. Greenwood, M.J. (1985),
|Human migration: theory, models, and empirical studies', Journal
of
Regional Science, 25:521-544. Harberger, A.C. (1962), |The
incidence of the corporate income tax', Journal of Political
Economy,
70:215-240. Hughes, G.A. and McCormick, B. (1990), |Housing and
labour mobility in Housing and the National
Economy (J.F. Ermisch, ed), Avebury-Gower, Aldershot (UK). Keenan,
J.G. (1981), |Irish migration, all or nothing resolved?', The
Economic and Social Review,
12:169-186. Lianos, T.P. (1972), |The migration process and time
lags', Journal of Regional Science, 12:425-433. Markusen, J.R.
(1983), |Factor movements and commodity trade as complements',
Journal of
International Economics, 14:341-356. McLure, C.E. (1970),
|Taxation, substitution, and industrial location', Journal of
Political
Economy, 78:112-132. Mieszkowski, P.M. (1967), |On the theory of
tax incidence', Journal of Political Economy, 75:250-262 Mohlo, I.
(1984), |A dynamic model of interregional migration flows in Great
Britain', Journal of
Regional Science, 24:317-337. Mokhtari, M. and Rassekh, F. (1989),
|The tendency towards factor price equalization among OECD
countries', Review of Economics and Statistics, 71:636-642.
Molle W. and van Mourik, A. (1988), |International movements of labour
under conditions of economic
integration: the case of Western Europe', Journal of Common
Market Studies, 26:317-342. Muellbauer, J. and Murphy, A. (1988),
|Housing and regional migration to and from the South East',
Nuffield College, Oxford, mimeo. Mundell, R. (1957) |International
trade and factor mobility', American Economic Review, 47:321-335.
Myers, G.M. (1990), |Optimality, free mobility, and the regional
authority in a federation', Journal
of Public Economics, 43:107-121. Olson, M. (1969), |The principle
of fiscal equivalence: the division of responsibilities among
different levels of government', American Economic Review
Proceedings, 59:479-487. Pissarides, C.A. and McMaster, I. (1990),
|Regional migration, wages and unemployment: empirical
evidence and implications for policy', Oxford Economic Papers,
42:812-831. Pissarides, C.A. and Wadsworth, J. (1987), |Unemployment and
the inter-regional mobility of labour',
Center for Labour Economics Discussion Paper 296, London School of
Economics. Ray, G.F. (1990), |International labour costs in
manufacturing, 1960-88', National Institute
Economic Review, Number 132 (May). Rothenberg, J. (1970), |Local
decentralization and the theory of optimal government', in The
Analysis of Public Output (J. Margolis, ed), National Bureau of
Economic Research and Columbia
University Press, New York. Salvatore, D. (1977), |An econometric
analysis of internal migration in Italy', Journal of Regional
Science, 17:395-408. Samuelson, P.A. (1948), |International trade
and the equalisation of factor prices', The Economic
Journal, 58:163-184. Samuelson, P.A. (1949), |International
factor-price equalisation once again', The Economic Journal,
59:181-197. Schachter, J. and Althaus, P.G. (1989), Journal of
Regional Science, 29:143-159. Straubhaar, T. (1988), |International
labour migration within a Common Market: some aspects of EC
experience', Journal of Common Market Studies, 27:45-62. Sinn,
H-W. (1990), |Tax harmonization and tax competition in Europe',
National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper No. 3248. Tovias, A. (1982), |Testing factor
price equalization in the EEC', Journal of Common Market Studies,
20:375-388. Walsh, B.M. (1974), |Expectations, information, and
human migration: specifying an econometric model
of Irish migration to Britain', Journal of Regional Science,
14:107-120.
NOTES
( 1) See McGuire (1974) for a rigorous demonstration of this
principle. ( 2) It does not, however, imply that separate bureaucracies
or elected officials are needed for
every jurisdiction. A
collective good could be voted on and paid for by the
appropriate jurisdiction, by the
administration of the provisions
could be handled by a larger jurisdiction. ( 3) The principle of
fiscal equivalence implies that the jurisdictional boundaries should be
drawn
to include all beneficiaries
of the collective good. When people are mobile, the number of
people within those boundaries
would be affected by the
cost per head of the collective good, and when there are
decreasing costs per head, movement of
people would affect
the cost per head. This fiscal effect of the movement of people
across jurisdictional
boundaries could lead to inefficient
decisions about the level of provision of collective goods by
the local jurisdictions, but this
need not be the case (see
Flatters, Henderson and Mieszkowski, 1974, and Myers, 1990). (
4) Gramlich and Laren's (1984) analysis of variation in the average
levels of welfare (AFDC)
benefits paid by different
states in the US suggest that, ceteris paribus, there is a weak
positive relationship between
average income and
redistribution, supporting weak dominance of the altruism
motive. ( 5) Furthermore, redistribution involving distant populations
are not likely to be a source of
welfare: |charity begins at
home'. ( 6) She groups the states into twelve regional
groupings, each of which has similar women's wages,
unemployment rates
and AFDC benefit levels as well as being close together
geographically; see her Appendix III.
In her study, migration
rates are defined over a four-year period (1975-79), which is
comparable to the five-year
period (1975-80) used by
Gramlich and Laren (1984). ( 7) If M is the matrix of
inter-state migration rates, then the equilibrium proportions are the
elements of the vector [alpha], where [alpha]
is defined so that [alpha]M = [alpha]. ( 8) The assumptions used
to make this calculation are likely to be favourable to a large impact.
An
alternative set of
assumptions, which changes only the outflow rates, produces an
even smaller changes in the
equilibrium distribution of
the AFDC population. ( 9) The conclusions that follow concerning
tax effects are based on further development of McLure's
(1970) two-country,
two factor model, which builds on the analysis of Mieszkowski
(1967) and Harberger (1962). A
companion paper,
Ermisch (1991), presents the model and demonstrates the main
propositions. (10) In the formal analysis (Ermisch 1991), more consumer
responsiveness in a single, integrated
market is approximated by
letting the elasticity of product demand with respect to the
relative price of the two
countries products be larger than the
elasticity of substitution between capital and labour in
production. A special case of this
would be to allow the demand
elasticity to approach infinity. (11) As McLure (1970) shows,
this is true under the plausible condition, assumed earlier, that the
price elasticity of demand
for the country's products is larger than the elasticity of
substitution between capital and
labour in production. (12) The analysis has abstracted from
other sources of labour supply elasticity: changes in hours
and employment
participation by the home population in response to real wages.
Men's hour'' elasticity tends
to be small and negative,
while women's hours' elasticity is small positive.
Women's participation elasticity has been
larger and positive, but it
has fallen as women's labour force participation has
approached men's. It is not clear whether
these responses would
be positive or negative on balance, but the net response is
likely to be small relative to
potential changes from migration. (13) Furthermore, it is the
EC's intention to levy VAT on the |destination principle'
rather than
the |origin principle' (a
production tax); that is, goods that leave the country are
exempt from the exporting country's
VAT, and are subject to the
importing country's VAT. Sinn (1990) argues that this may,
however, be difficult after border
controls are removed, thus
making VAT more like a production tax. (14) The residence
principle is, in theory, applied by most OECD countries, including
members of the
EC. (15) For employed persons, the Treaty stipulated that |the
freedom of movement shall entail the
abolition of any discrimination
based on nationality between workers of the member states as
regards employment, remuneration
and other
conditions of work and employment.' (article 48ff.) (16) In
Charts 1 and 2, the EC is constituted as it actually was in each year;
that is, the
countries included in the EC change
over time. Migration between the UK and the Republic of Ireland
is excluded from the UK
statistics on international
migration, used in Charts 1 and 2. (17) Over the period 1964-89,
net migration between the UK and the rest of the rest of the EC
was +9, 100 people. (18) The published information does not give
details on the individual countries of the EC who are
the origins and
destination of the migration. (19) This negative correlation is
maintained when intra-EC trade is expressed as a proportion of
total EC trade, and intra-EC
migration is expressed as a proportion of total EC migration
flows; the correlation coefficient
is -0.55 (Straubhaar,
1988, Table 1). (20) The analysis controls for distance between
the two countries and for trade between them. The
destination countries
considered in the study are France, Germany, Netherlands,
Belgium, Sweden, Austria and
Switzerland, and the origin
countries are Italy, Greece, Spain, Portugal, Yugoslavia,
Turkey, Morocco, Algeria and Tunisia. (21) Luxembourg is excluded.
Similar conclusions arise from examining the wage differential between
France and the
Federal Republic of Germany. (22) Estimation of the labour
supply elasticity from net migration equation estimates is based on
the assumption that the
change in a country's labour force is equal to net labour
migration into/from the country.
Thus, net migration should
depend on the change in relative wages rather than the level of
the relative wage. In
equilibrium, both net labour
migration and relative wage changes should be zero. The net
migration equation is, therefore, a
disequilibrium, labour
supply adjustment equation. Letting [M.sub.x] = net labour
migration and dlog [W.sub.x] = the
proportionate change in country X's
relative wages and expressing net migration to the
country's labour force ([L.sub.x]), a
natural expression for net
migration is [M.sub.x]/[L.sub.x] = d. Log [W.sub.x,] where x is
the elasticity of labour supply
with respect to relative wages. Because of
response lags, a distributed lag model is likely to be more
appropriate; thus, as in Lianos'
analysis, net migration in
period t is given by
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
where [xi] is a random term, and the constant term [C.sub.x]
captures autonomous migration
(independent of economic
opportunities) to or from the region or country. (23) It should
be noted, however, that Greek migration to Germany was by far the
largest migration
flow during the period
under study. Furthermore, Lianos does not allow for the
unemployment rate in Greece relative to
Germany to affect
migration. Analysis of Irish migration, described below,
suggests that omission of the relative
unemployment rate from
the migration equation biases upwards the estimate of the
elasticity of the labour supply with
respect to relative pay. (24) This range of estimates is based
on the coefficients in Walsh's |extrapolative and |adaptive
expectations' models
reported in Table 3 of Walsh (1974), which he appears to prefer.
The estimates assume that 75
per cent of migrants and
50 per cent of the total population are in the labour force.
This is consistent with the
evidence that, in the mid-1960s, 86
per cent of male and 71 per cent of female migrants from Ireland
to the UK were labour force
participants. Walsh's
models generally express migration as a function of the level of
the relative wage. As
explained below (footnote 33), this
type of model implicity assumes perfect labour mobility and
compensating wage differentials. In
order to use his
empirical estimates, I have assumed that the long run response
of net migration to a temporary
(one year) change in the
relative wage implied by his equations is the total labour
supply response to a permanent
relative wage change. (25) Estimates of Walsh's (1974)
|information flow' model produce much larger elasticities, but my
own analysis of the Irish
migration data (described below) strongly suggests that these
arise because he constrains the
constant term to be zero,
thereby inflating the coefficient on the lagged dependent
variable. (26) I estimate models analagous to that of Pissarides and
McMaster (1990). A country/region's
relative unemployment rate,
[U.sub.xt]/[U.sub.t], is taken as an indicator of existing
disequilibrium in the labour market,
to which migration is also responding:
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
The estimate of the long run labour supply elasticity is a/(1 -
[gamma]. In other words, the
long run labour supply response to the
relative wage is estimated as the sum of annual migration
responses to a one-off permanent
increase in the region's
relative wage, holding relative unemployment in the region
constant. This is the appropriate
calculation for determining
the structural, long run effect of relative wages on labour
supply. (27) My analysis of the Irish migration data provided by Keenan
(1981; Table A. 1) finds an
acceptable econometric model
virtually identical to that of Pissarides and McMaster's
(1990). Using the new migration
series, which appears to be
preferable to the official series (and real non-agricultural
earnings per hour for the Irish
wage series), the estimated
equation for 1955-77 is:
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
The estimate of [gamma] (of the previous note) was not near
being statistically different from
zero; thus the lagged dependent
variable was dropped the equation. (28) The model implies that
an Irish unemployment rate of about twice the UK rate would result in
zero net migration from
Ireland; this can be interpreted as an equilibrium relative
unemployment rate. The predicted
series in Chart 3 allows for
actual changes in Irish real wages relative to British. (29)
Indeed, in recent years, American researchers have favoured a so-called
equilibrium model of
migration' which
assumes perfect mobility of people and that all regional wage
differentials are |compensating
differentials', compensating
for different amenities etc. Such differentials would not
directly encourage migration. See,
for example, Graves and
Linneman (1979) and Schachter and Althaus (1989). This contracts
with the traditional
assumption that migration
equations represent disequilibrium adjustment functions (see
Greenwood, 1985). (30) The South, or Mezzogiorno, consists of the
regions of Abruzzi-Molise, Campania, Puglia,
Calabria, Sicily and Sardinia.
The labour supply elasticity estimate is based on the migration
equations for the entire South
in Salvatore's (1977) Table
2. (31) This estimates is based on the same assumption as that
used to derive estimates from Walsh's
models, as noted in
footnote 24 above. (32) Adams (1980a, 1980b) and Harrigan,
Jenkins and McGregor (1986). (33) When the net migration equation takes
the following form:
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
there are |compensating wage differentials' between
countries or regions. To see this, note
that in equilibrium [M.sub.x] = 0, so
that [C.sub.x] = - b.log[W.sub.xt] +
[delta]([U.sub.xt]/[U.sub.t]). Thus, workers in regions/
countries favoured by migrants (high [C.sub.x], say because of a
favourable climate) receive lower pay and/or experience higher
equilibrium unemployment than
average. It also
implicitly assumes that the regional labour supply is perfectly
elastic with respect to
relative pay. In order to see this
clearly, let [delta] = 0. Then in equilibrium - [C.sub.x/b] =
log[W.sub.xt], and as long as
log[W.sub.xt] exceeds - [C.sub.x]/b, there will be net inward
migration.