The home economy.
Anderton, Bob ; Britton, Andrew ; Soteri, Soterios 等
CHAPTER I. THE HOME ECONOMY
The forecasts were prepared by Bob Anderton, Andrew Britton and
Soterios Soteri, but they draw on the work of the whole team engaged in
macroeconomic analysis and modelbuilding at the Institute. Parts One and
Two of the chapter are written by Andrew Britton, Part Three by Bob
Anderton and Soterios Soteri.
PART ONE. RECENT DEVELOPMENTS AND SUMMARY OF THE FORECAST
Seldom has such close attention been paid to the indicators of
economic activity and seldom have economic and political commentators
been so preoccupied with short-term forecasting. It seems right on this
occasion to reinforce our customary warning that the interpretation of
recent statistics, and their projection even a few months into the
future, is always an imprecise and hazardous exercise. This is true
whether one attempts to follow a scientific methodology based on an
econometric model or whether one prefers to rely on market sentiment,
informed anecdotes or surveys of business confidence.
Recent developments and their interpretation
A somewhat clearer picture is now emerging of the state of the
economy in the latter half of last year. The fall in output at the time
is accounted for, in the latest national accounts, by lower consumption
and fixed investment partly offset by an end to destocking. We would
interpret the positive stockbuilding in the non-manufacturing sector in
the third and fourth quarters as an involuntary consequence of an
unexpected contraction of demand. As such it would point to a further
fall in activity in the early part of this year.
The fall in consumer spending occurred despite a continuing rise in
real personal disposable incomes. In the latter part of last year rpdi
was up 3 per cent on a year earlier, but the whole of that increment was
devoted to extra saving. Part of the explanation may lie in the sharp
fall in the net wealth of the personal sector, although it would be
unusual for this to have such a quick effect on household spending. An
additional factor was the state of the housing market, where turnover
was exceptionally low and prices falling in real terms. Credit
conditions were also getting tighter, with the stock of consumer debt
hardly keeping pace with inflation.
In the early months of the year retail sales have fallen further
(although the preannouncement of a rise in VAT brought some purchases
forward into March). It seems likely that consumer spending fell again
in the first quarter. It may seem that the response of consumers to
repeated and well-publicised cuts in interest rates is disappointingly
slow, but the delay is not out of line with previous experience.
Fixed investment also fell in the latter part of last year. The
housing market had been depressed for some time, and even now when
turnover is beginning to improve builders are in no hurry to increase
new construction. There has also been a very general fall in industrial
investment, both in manufacturing and elsewhere.
Our model equation for manufacturing investment now fits the
downturn remarkably well. The explanation is based on the fall in
capacity utilisation, and on the decline in profits which would already
have been evident to businesses by last summer, coupled with excessive
borrowing in the late 1980s which left balance sheet positions very
fragile - picked up in our model by a measure of |disequilibrium net
liquidity'. The negative effects of these variables on investment
are likely to intensify this year. The CBI Industrial Trends Survey
throughout last year was pointing to a fall in investment, in both
buildings and new machinery. There was a further sharp deterioration in
the surveys conducted in January and April of this year.
The fall in investment has not been confined to manufacturing
industry. Separate figures are no longer available for distribution and
other services, but the suggestion is that the strong upward trend in
investment by these sectors may now be in reverse, and there is no
reason to be confident that it will revive the same pace even when the
present recession is at an end.
Business confidence, as measured by the CBI Survey, dipped sharply
last October. It is difficult to know to what extent this was a
reflection of what was actually happening to industry |on the
ground' at that time, or to what extent it reflected the Gulf
crisis or the political situation at home. This series is subject to
wide variation, sometimes unrelated to the current or immediately future
state of the economic cycle.
The reliability of this series as a forward indicator of the cycle
is of particular interest at the present time since it recovered sharply
in the April survey. (It is usual for business confidence to improve in
the Spring but this went beyond the normal seasonal pattern.) A
regression equation linking this indicator with the economic cycle as
measured by capacity utilisation suggests a lead of about six months. A
comparison of turning points indicates a lead of one or two quarters in
the 1980 trough, but as much as five quarters at the 1988 peak. The CSO include the series in their longer leading composite indicator, and give
it a median lead relative to their reference cycle of 12 months (with a
range from -34 to +6 months). All one can say is that the upturn in
confidence in the April survey, if it is sustained, probably points to
an upturn in the economy some time in the next year.
Apart from this and some similar evidence from other surveys there
is little if anything to suggest that the upturn is in sight at all. The
rise in unemployment in the first quarter confirms the depth of the
recession up to that point and will itself be associated with lower
employment earnings and with lower consumer demand. The relatively low
level of import volume is consistent with the picture of subdued demand
and activity.
The effect of the recession on the underlying rate of inflation is
still difficult to detect. The growth of average earnings in the latter
half of last year implied by the wage bill and the employment figures is
as high as 11 per cent, rather hard to believe at this stage in the
cycle. Perhaps one or other of the component series will be revised. The
more recent information on settlements shows a wide variety, including
some well over 10 per cent, but also some postponements which will bring
down the average increase.
The |headline figure' for the retail prices index came down
from 10 per cent in the first quarter of last year to 8.7 per cent in
the first quarter of this year, and it is bound to be much lower in the
second quarter. There is no suggestion as yet of a slowdown in the rise
in wholesale prices, which is surprising given the steep fall in
capacity utilisation. On the other hand the deflator for fixed
investment actually fell in the fourth quarter of last year.
The effective exchange rate index for sterling rose by 6 1/2 per
cent between the first and second halves of last year. Mainly for that
reason the prices of manufactured exports and imports both fell
significantly.
Membership of the exchange rate mechanism has held up sterling
against European currencies, but there has been a fall of 13 per cent
against the dollar since the fourth quarter of last year, associated
with a fall of nearly 5 per cent in the effective exchange rate index.
Especially since many world prices are set in dollars in the short term,
the effect of this depreciation on prices in this country will be
significant within the next few months. On the other hand we are already
benefiting from the halving of world crude oil prices between the fourth
quarter of last year and the first quarter of this year.
The only change in the Budget this year which is of significance
for the short-term forecast was the reduction in the poll tax (costing
4.5bn [pounds] in a full year) and the increase in the rate of VAT
(yielding 5.5bn [pounds] in a full year). The estimated effect of the
VAT increase on its own would be to raise prices by about 1 1/2 per cent
in the first year and reduce output significantly, even in the long run.
It is likely however that the economic effects of the poll tax reduction
together with the VAT increase will be broadly offsetting.
Short-term interest rates have been progressively reduced from 15
per cent last summer to about 11 per cent (for 3-month inter-bank
deposits) in the second quarter of this year. Mortgage interest rates
came down from 15 1/2 per cent to about 13 1/2 per cent and are
confidently expected to fall further in the next few months.
Policy assumptions
Early in May the 12-month interest rate on Euro-sterling deposits
implied a market expectation of short-term rates falling to little below
11 per cent by next Spring. This seems to us a little pessimistic. We
are forecasting base rates of 10 1/2 per cent by the end of this year
and 10 per cent by next Summer.
This judgement is clearly linked with our forecast of the exchange
rate, which is explained in more detail than usual in Part Two below. As
the possibility of a realignment some time within the forecast period
cannot be ruled out we have to construct our central forecast as the
mean of a probability distribution. This shows a gradual depreciation.
We would in fact attach a high probability to a constant exchange rate
scenario, but this would involve the progressive correction of market
expectations. A variant forecast on these lines is described in the
Annex to this chapter.
In principle we treat the outcome of the general election in a
similar way. The situation now is different from that in the run-up to
the 1983 and 1987 elections in that the two largest parties have moved
closer together in their statements on macroeconomic policy. The main
difference of emphasis is the relative priority of tax cuts and public
spending increases if the growth of the economy justifies either. We
discussed Labour Party policy at some length in the Review last
November, and we do not have enough additional information to construct
a formal forecast variant. Instead we have adopted an intermediate
assumption with some tax cuts and a modest rise in public spending. This
could be interpreted as a fifty-fifty weighting of the probability of a
change of government. If so it is the mean of the probability
distribution, but not of course its mode.
The conclusion of our medium-term projections is that the scope for
either spending increases or tax cuts will be limited. This has been the
message of our forecasts for some time now; it is based on the view that
the reduction in interest rates resulting from ERM membership will on
its own stimulate demand as much as is compatible with keeping inflation
in check and with external balance. In our forecast growth averages over
2 1/2 per cent between 1992 and 1998. Tax receipts (especially
corporation tax) initially lag behind the recovery, but by the mid-1990s
a substantial |growth dividend' can be expected. In forecasting we
always assume that public sector pay rises in line with earnings in the
private sector. Since the value of public authorities' consumption
accounts for about three-quarters of the yield of direct and indirect
taxation much of the |dividend' is, on our assumptions,
automatically spent in this way. It also seems unrealistic to suppose
that the buoyancy of real receipts from national insurance contributions
will not be reflected in increases in benefits beyond the minimum
required by price indexation.
Summary of the forecast
We now expect GDP to fall by 2 to 2 1/2 per cent this year with the
recession just a little longer and deeper than we said in February. The
quarterly path will never be known precisely, so precise forecasting
would be almost meaningless, but the profile we have in mind would show
total output virtually flat for the rest of this year. This means that
there may not be clear evidence that the recovery has actually begun
until well into next year. Year-on-year growth in 1992 is forecast at
about 2 per cent.
Consumer spending should recover by the latter half of this year
with real incomes rising a little and the savings ratio beginning to
edge down again in response to interest-rate cuts. By next year the
growth of consumption could be up to 1 1/2 or 2 per cent again.
The prospect for an upturn in industrial fixed investment is more
distant. Our model equation for manufacturing investment predicts a fall
of 15 per cent this year, which is compatible with the survey evidence.
It then predicts a further fall in 1992, thanks mainly to the lagged
effect of falling profits and liquidity. This substantial investment
recession will have a lasting effect on the supply side of the economy
(see the box on page 27 below). We estimate that the level of
manufacturing capacity will be reduced by some 5 per cent at the end of
next year and productivity growth in the medium term will be some 1 per
cent a year lower as a result of the investment shortfall this year and
next.
The outlook for export growth is reasonably good if world trade
growth is maintained at 5 per cent this year and 6 per cent next year
(see chapter II). Thanks to this, and the subdued level of imports, the
balance of payments deficit this year should be much reduced - to about
6 billion [pounds], compared with 12.8 [pounds] billion last year. But
the outlook for 1992 and beyond is not so good.
Further falls in mortgage rates will help to reduce the
|headline' inflation figure to about 4 per cent by the end of this
year, but it is not expected to fall further than that in 1992. The
deflator for GDP at factor cost is expected to rise by 7 per cent this
year and 5 per cent next year. The fall in underlying inflation should
continue into the medium term.
Unemployment can be expected to rise strongly throughout this year,
reaching over 2 1/2 million by the Autumn. Thereafter its rise should be
much slower, but the actual peak may not occur until late in 1992.
For the medium-term we are again able to show a smooth transition
to monetary union in 1997. The rate of inflation settles at 2 to 3 per
cent a year which is similar to the rate elsewhere in Europe. This is
compatible according to our model with steady growth in GDP at around 2
1/2 per cent a year, with unemployment at about 2 1/2 million, falling
very slightly.
PART TWO: FORECASTING THE EXCHANGE RATE
In the past one of the most difficult tasks facing an economist
making a short-term forecast has been to anticipate movements in the
exchange rate. If we look back over the past 20 years at the record of
forecast made by the Institute or by any of the other forecasting teams
in this country we find that many of the largest errors in forecasts of
inflation and output occur as a result of unanticipated exchange-rate
movements. This is not at all surprising. Theory says that the expected
gain from holding any two currencies should be the same, so that the
predicted change in the exchange rate for any period ahead should be
equal to the difference between the interest paid on similar assets of
that maturity in the two currencies. As soon as any new information
becomes available to the market, the exchange rate will jump to a new
value, and the arbitrage conditions will again be satisfied. If a
reliable method existed for forecasting exchange-rate movements, the
market would soon discover it and make it ineffective.
Now that the UK has joined the exchange-rate mechanism, errors in
exchange-rate forecasting should be less of a problem, and as a result
forecasts of inflation and output should be more reliable. However, we
are now in a period of transition when the possibility of an exchange
rate realignment cannot be entirely ruled out. In this section we
consider the circumstances in which a realignment could still occur, and
interpret the present differential between interest rates in the UK and
Germany. Our main forecasts are based, as usual, on the assumption of
consistent expectations - that is that market expectations will in fact
be realised. But the market expectation is the weighted average of many
possible paths for the exchange rate in the future.
Analysing the policymaking process
The choice of an exchange rate within the new regime illustrates the
problem of time inconsistency. It pays the authorities to build up a
reputation for keeping their commitment to exchange-rate stability even
though in general the |optimum' exchange rate will change as new
information becomes available or simply with the passage of time. As the
commitment of the UK authorities is a recent one, the market is in the
process of learning how firm that commitment actually is. Eventually an
|expectational equilibrium' may be reached, when the behaviour of
the authorities is fully understood by the market, but we are not at
that equilibrium yet.
Formally the determination of the exchange rate in these
circumstances could be analysed as the interaction of three processes.
The first would be the behaviour of the economy (represented in our
forecasts by the Institute's macroeconomic model). The second would
specify the policymakers' preferences, which could be represented
by a welfare function depending on present and future values of
variables such as inflation and unemployment, together with a set of
parameters which define their relative priorities. In the short term an
exchange-rate depreciation adds to inflation, but reduces unemployment.
In the long run (if there are no further depreciations) both inflation
and unemployment will be unaffected. Because the authorities wish to
keep unemployment as low as possible they will be tempted to realign,
but if they value their reputation for consistency they will be
reluctant to do so.
The third process would be the formation of expectations, and this
is the most difficult of the three to describe because it involves
learning from experience. Expectations must reflect the subjective
probability of future realignments based on the evidence available about
the authorities' intentions. These probabilities will be updated
each time period in the light of a new observation of the
authorities' decision to realign or not to realign. But there is no
general rule, specifying how these estimates should be updated in the
light of new information, which would be appropriate in all
circumstances.
The expected exchange rate for next period must be calculated as
the weighted average of two possible outcomes - a realignment or no
realignment. But this probability has to be specified for each period of
the future before even a one-step forecast can be made, because
today's optimum exchange rate must depend on whether the
authorities expect to realign again at any period in the future. Thus
the distribution of expectations relating to the next period will in
general by asymmetric: there will be a concentration of probability at
the point of zero change, with the rest of the distribution scattered
over a range of points corresponding to the optimum outcome on all
possible assumptions about alignments in the future. The weights will
reflect the latest estimates of the authorities' preferences.
A realignment will occur when its expected benefits exceed its
costs, including the cost of lost reputation. Given continuity
(appropriately defined) these net benefits will be zero at the point
where realignment occurs, so any actual realignment would provide
valuable information about the authorities' preferences. Following
realignment a new commitment is made to the new exchange rate, which
will hold until it pays to abandon it. The authorities are themselves
uncertain as to whether they will realign again or not - but that
uncertainty reflects only the uncertainty about the future course of the
economy. They are assumed to know their own present and future
preferences.
A very simple approach
This rather complex interaction can be simplified by concentrating
attention on the issues of commitment by the authorities and learning by
the markets in the current situation.
The aim of the UK authorities is to get inflation down, at least to
the European average, but this must be at an acceptable cost in terms of
unemployment an international competitiveness, which depend on relative
prices. So long as our rate of inflation is higher than that in the rest
of Europe we are losing competitiveness. Sooner or later our loss of
competitiveness will stop; the more credible the commitment to the ERM,
the sooner that will happen. But there is in fact a level of
competitiveness (and hence of expected unemployment) at which the
authorities would give up the struggle and realign the exchange rate.
For obvious reasons they are not telling us what that level is. The
process of learning in this case consists simply of updating estimates
of the critical level.
If the authorities failed to acquire any reputation at all, then
competitiveness would suffer until that crucial point was reached. The
pound would then be devalued, inflation speed up again and the process
would be repeated. (It is possible however, that the rise in
unemployment would stop the inflation before the realignment was
triggered.)
Credibility improves the chances of avoiding the need for
realignments. As competitiveness worsens, but the authorities do not
devalue the pound, their credibility improves, and the mean expectation
of devaluation is reduced because estimates of the unemployment
threshold are revised up. In fact just before the threshold is reached
the mean estimate of where that threshold lies will almost certainly
indicate a greater toleration for unemployment than the authorities
actually have. If the threshold is actually crossed, it will (in this
very simple model) be known with certainty from that point on. But so
long as the threshold is not crossed the authorities can benefit from
the reputation they have built up, which could in fact be based on an
over-estimate of their determination not to realign.
Two further complications
At present, the forecasting of the exchange rate is further
complicated, both by the approach of a general election, and by the
transition to economic and monetary union.
The timing and the outcome of the election are both in principle
endogenous. It affects expectations even if the welfare function of the
authorities would in fact be the same under any government. If there
were a change of government then the markets would not know whether the
priorities had changed or not. The process of learning would have to
begin all over again. That would of itself the probability of
realignment. Equally important is the possibility that the approach of
an election would influence the priorities of the government in office.
Thus a realignment is unlikely just before an election, and more likely
just after, whatever the outcome of the election may be.
The possible approach of EMU provides an endpoint to the
authorities' optimisation. If exchange rates are to be |set in
stone' at some period in the future, the rate at that time becomes
especially important. It is possible that a last realignment will take
place at the time when EMU comes into effect. But the likelihood of EMU
happening (or of the UK being a full member of it) may itself depend on
what exchange-rate policies the UK follows in the meantime. Clearly the
general evolution of the ERM towards a more fixed exchange-rate system
has been influenced by the wish of most European governments to make the
transition to EMU. The French, for example, are keen to demonstrate that
they can manage without realignments, so as to make EMU more likely. If
the UK authorities want to avoid being in the slow lane of a two-speed
Europe, they will be reluctant to realign at all, in case that is seen
as a sign of weakness.
Table : Interest-rate differentials
The following were the Euro-currency rates quoted in the Financial
Times for 2nd May.
1 month 3 months 6 months 12 months
Sterling 11-81 11-66 11-38 11-19
D-Mark 8-88 9-06 9-19 9-31
Differential 2-93 2-60 2-19 1-88
We assume that the mean expected depreciation of sterling against the
D-Mark was equal to these differentials, so that the expected return from holding both currencies was the same. This may not be exactly true
because of transaction costs, or because the market prefers one currency
to another for reasons other than the expected return - possibility
related to the variances and covariances of currencies which go to make
up an optimum portfolio. But we would guess that between sterling and
the D-Mark the |arbitrage condition' nowadays holds more-or-less
exactly.
The expected depreciation of sterling implied by these interest
differentials would be consistent with a probability distribution such
that the likelihood of appreciation is very small, the likelihood of no
change is very high, and the likelihood of deprecation, even downwards
realignment, is not negligible. One scenario consistent with the mean
expectation would be a gradual depreciation within the present wide
band, followed by a narrowing of the band with a lower central rate. But
it should be emphasised that the forecast path is the average of a wide
variety of possibility scenarios, not the illustration of a particular
central case.
It is quite likely that, in the event, sterling will not in fact
depreciate at all in the forecast period. A variant forecast on that
assumption is described in the Annex to this chapter. Should this
happen, some market participants will be |surprised' and the mean
forecast of the exchange rate will rise as these participants learn from
their mistakes. Thus in the variant forecast the assumption of
|consistent' expectations in its usual strong form does not hold.
PART THREE. THE FORECAST IN DETAIL
Forecasts of expenditure and output (table 1)
The decline in output since the second half of last year has been
associated with some interesting developments. Although de-stocking
occurred in the last quarter of 1989 and the first of last year, this
did not continue into the final six months of 1990. Consequently, given
the output downturn, this latter period suggests that involuntary
stockbuilding has taken place. An explanation for this may be that
private sector decision makers did not expect the recession to be so
severe. A second feature of this recession is the rapid slowdown in the
growth of manufacturing exports (see Chart 1). However, it is difficult
to discern whether this is due to a deterioration in price
competitiveness and recently depressed world trade or whether the
squeeze on profit margins is reducing supply. Partly for these reasons
we are now forecasting substantial de-stocking this year, which extends
into 1992, and low export growth for 1991.
We have revised down or forecast for output growth this year and
now expect total GDP to decline by around 2 1/4 per cent with a slightly
larger fall in non-oil GDP. We expect non-oil GDP to stop falling in the
second half of 1991 and to remain fairly flat for the rest of the year.
Our forecast of a 10 per cent decline in total investment during 1991
contributes to the depressed activity. The largest fall occurs in
manufacturing investment. For 1991 this percentage fall in manufacturing
investment is similar to that predicted by the CBI but we are also
predicting a further fall next year. This is consistent with a revision
of output expectations by the company sector which had been too
optimistic. The current CBI survey indicates a substantial increase in
excess capacity from the beginning of last year.
Although our forecase of a recovery in total GDP growth next year
is similar to the February forecast, the extent of the downturn in 1991
now expected means the level of activity we expect this year is now
lower. Hence, unemployment is now expected to reach the higher peak of
over 2 3/4 million in 1992. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Personal income and expenditure (table 2)
Real personal disposable income increased at an annual rate of 3 per
cent during the final quarter of last year. The savings ratio therefore
rose to 10 1/2 per cent as real consumers' expenditure declined by
1 1/2 per cent over the same period. Data for retail sales for the first
two months of this year confirm the continuation of a deceleration in
consumption but the figure for March was biased upwards due to purchases
brought forward to avoid the VAT increase announced in the Budget.
Recent figures for consumer credit and bank lending indicate that
consumer borrowing was depressed in the first quarter of this year. In
addition, the number of new vehicle registrations in March was 6 per
cent less than in the previous three months (26 per cent lower than in
the same quarter a year ago). However, in contrast, to this data, the
Gallup survey indicates that consumer confidence, although remaining at
a very low level, has recently recovered slightly.
Our predicted path for consumption has a very important bearing on
our forecast as this category of expenditure accounts for more than a
half of total domestic demand. Our model equation for consumers'
expenditure has been overpredicting over the past few quarters but this
residual discrepancy frequently disappears when data are revised. Part
of the statistical adjustment, which itself is frequently revised, is
included in the data for consumption and this raises further concerns
about the accuracy of the data. Nevertheless, we apply the recent
negative residual to our forecast for consumers' expenditure.
We expect real consumers' expenditure to fall by more than 1
per cent this year with most of the decline occurring in the first half
of 1991. Expenditure on consumer durables will suffer the largest
decline of around 8 per cent. This is probably what most forecasters are
expecting although the Treasury is far more pessimistic in the budget
forecast (predicting a 1 3/4 per cent fall in consumption). The factors
determining our predicted decline in consumption are a slowdown in real
disposable income growth, lagged adjustment to the 10 per cent fall in
real net wealth last year, and continued slow credit growth especially
in the first part of 1991. Consumer credit growth will take time to
respond to the lower interest rates and the substantial expected falls
in inflation mean that real interest rates remain high. Given that we
expect real income to rise by almost 2 per cent this year, largely
because real wages remain high as price inflation falls more rapidly
than wage inflation, this implies a rise in the savings ratio in 1991.
Intangible factors such as consumer confidence affect the latter;
confidence will be boosted by declining interest rates, falling
inflation and the end of the Gulf War but the rapid rise in unemployment
should dampen the recovery in confidence. A recovery in consumers'
expenditure will probably begin in the latter part of this year, and
continue at an accelerating pace, throughout next year. Although real
disposable income growth will probably remain subdued in 1992,
consumption will be encouraged by cheaper credit and increased real
wealth as base rates continue to fall. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Fixed investment and stockbuilding (tables 3 and 4)
Growth in total real investment expenditure came to a halt in the
second half of last year. Although investment growth had been
decelerating for some time before this, it now seems that capital
spending was based on output expectations far more optimistic than those
currently held. The abrupt decline in activity from the later half of
1990 onwards has resulted in considerable excess capacity. The latest
CBI survey confirms that this is particularly acute in the manufacturing
sector. The situation is exacerbated by the financial deficit of the
company sector which was probably viewed as sustainable under the
previous more optimistic expectations. Therefore, instead of companies
reducing their financial deficit via continued output and hence profits
growth, the route back towards financial balance will partly be by means
of investment expenditure cut backs.
Although firms are forward looking and probably expect activity to
recover in the near future, the combination of uncertainty, financial
distress and excess capacity will encourage a substantial fall in
investment this year. We expect total investment to fall by 10 per cent
this year with declines in all categories except the oil sector where
safety equipment is being installed. Our new manufacturing investment
equation agrees with the CBI survey that investment in this category
will decline by around 15 per cent this year. Although profitability and
manufacturing output recover next year, the equation predicts there will
be a further fall in manufacturing investment next year largely because
capacity utilisation remains at a low level.
Housing investment experienced a substantial fall in 1990 and we
expect this to continue, but at a more moderate pace, this year. The
decline in base rates and mortgage rates so far has resulted in a rise
in sales of property but the supply has originated largely from the
existing surplus housing stock. Consequently, we expect positive growth
in housing investment next year (rather than this year) as mortgage
rates continue to decline. Both the business and financial services and
distribution sectors will probably experience a subdued recovery next
year. However, this may only be enough to arrest the decline in total
investment with the result that total capital spending is likely to
remain flat in 1992.
Considering the severity of the downturn in activity, the amount of
de-stocking has been surprisingly low. It seems that the scale of the
decline in demand has left firms with larger than desired levels of
stocks. This is confirmed by the CBI survey where stocks of finished
goods in particular are much higher than desired. We are forecasting
substantial de-stocking in all sectors this year. However, de-stocking
will probably continue at a decelerating rate through 1992 as the
expected output fall this year will cause stock/output ratios to rise to
an undesirably high level. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Balance of payments (table 5 and 6)
The recent 3 billion [pounds] revision to the invisibles trade
balance reduced the current account deficit for 1990 to around 12 3/4
billion [pounds] or 2 3/4 per cent of GDP. This amounted to a 7 billion
[pounds] improvement in the external balance of the UK compared to 1989
and the stepdown in the visible trade deficit when output declined in
the second half of last year is quite pronounced. The beneficial
movement in the terms of trade over this period may also partly explain
both the improvement over this period and the lack of any further
visible deficit reduction in the first quarter of this year. Chart 1
shows that, after performing exceptionally well in the past few years,
export volumes of manufactures have not contributed much to the recent
decline in the visibles deficit. Given the recession, many economists
expected UK manufacturers to switch from the domestic market to overseas
but weak world trade growth and a loss of price competitiveness may have
prevented this. It may also be the case that the poor financial
situation of UK firms has forced cut backs in non-price competitiveness
factors such as price-discounting and advertising.
Although the recent upward surge in the US dollar (see chart 2)
will improve the overall price competitiveness of UK exports we do not
expect a strong response from export volumes as the UK's major
export market is now Europe. Germany is our largest single export market
and sterling has recently appreciated against the D-Mark. Given these
factors and our forecast of subdued world trade growth of below 5 per
cent this year, exports of goods and services will probably only grow by
around 1 per cent in 1991. Next year should see a substantial recovery
in exports of goods and services in response to our expected sterling
depreciation against the D-Mark and renewed growth in the UK's
export markets. It is this external demand which will in part lead the
UK out of recession.
Import volumes of manufactures may decline by around 3 per cent
this year in response to large falls as investment, stockbuilding and
consumption of durable goods. Imports of raw materials and oil will also
fall in line with demand and the visible deficit should be reduced this
year to around 11 billion [pounds]. A visible trade deficit of 2 3/4 per
cent of GDP when GDP itself is falling by more than 2 per cent indicates
that the UK's trade deficit will be around for some years. Next
year will see a renewed deterioration in the trade balance as domestic
demand recovers.
There is no reason to believe that the invisibles balance will not
continue at its revised higher level. The surplus on interest profits
and dividends this year will benefit from the recent upsurge in the
dollar which increases the sterling returns on UK assets held in the
USA. This effect will be bolstered by declining UK interest rate
differentials (and hence reduced returns on UK liabilities) and
transfers will benefit from foreign contributions to the Gulf War. The
surplus on services should remain at around 3 1/2 billion [pounds] for
this year and next. Given these factors the current balance will look
far more flattering than the visible deficit with a current account
deficit of the order of 6 billion [pounds] in 1991 deteriorating to
around 8 [pounds] billion next year. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Output and the labour market (tables 7 and 8)
The decline in real GDP since the peak of the economic cycle, in the
middle of 1990, has accumulated to approximately 3 per cent. In contrast
to the 1980/1 recession major output falls have been experienced in all
areas of the economy. The manufacturing and construction sectors have
endured the largest falls in output since the middle of 1990, 6 1/2 and
5 1/2 per cent respectively. They are closely followed by the
distribution and business service sectors whose corresponding rates are
4 and 2 per cent respectively. The uniformity of the recession amongst
sectors during the present downturn seems to be due to the effects of
continuous high real interest rates which are in contrast to real
interest-rate movements in 1980/1 (when base rates were actually lower
than inflation for a time). We expect further, though much more subdued,
falls in all non-oil output categories, except for the public sector,
until the middle of this year. A flat output profile is then expected
until growth is resumed at the end of the year. Year on year growth
rates in most sectors however will still be significantly negative.
The workforce in employment data series have recently undergone
major revisions on account of the 1989 Census of Employment and the 1990
Labour Force Survey. The revised figures indicate that employment peaked
in the second quarter of 1990 and has since fallen by 340,000.
Employment falls have lagged behind the decline in output in their usual
pro cyclical manner. This is usually interpreted as the effect of labour
being a quasi-fixed factor of production, the degree of fixity arising
from fixed costs associated with hiring, firing and training employees.
Even through employment falls had been predicted the steep increase
in unemployment in March of 113,000, the highest ever recorded, and the
subsequent rise in April of 84,000, were higher than previously
expected. This is probably due to a combination of two factors. Firstly
the recession is now expected to be worse than initially anticipated.
Labour hoarding may have taken place due to labour posessing a degree of
factor fixity, but once the true extent of the recession revealed itself
and firms' expectations adjusted to new information their optimal
employment requirement, was drastically reduced, giving rise to the
recent large increases in unemployment. The second reason is the sharp
squeeze on profit margins. High real interest rates, falling sales and
rising unit labour costs have squeezed profits dramatically. A bleak
domestic market and a tighter world market have led firms to contain
cost increases via reductions in stocks and employment levels since this
is a relatively quick way of restoring company sector profitability in a
depressed market. Our forecast sees substantial rises in the
unemployment total over the near future. We expect the unemployment
total to reach 2.6 million by the end of this year and then to continue
growing until its peak of 2.8 million in the middle of 1992. A
comparison of expected unemployment rates in the UK and other European
countries is discussed in Box. 1. The rapidly falling employment levels
and the slower rate of decline in output lead us to expect an increase
in productivity growth in the latter part of 1991 with a considerable
acceleration in 1992.
BOX 1. UNEMPLOYMENT by Paul Gregg
The somewhat deeper recession than previously forecast implies
somewhat higher claimant unemployment by the end of this year. Hence we
now anticipate claimant unemployment will rise to just under 2-6 million
by the fourth quarter and to just under 2.8 million by the third quarter
of 1992, which we anticipate will be the peak level. The continued rise
in unemployment after the beginnings of a recovery reflects in part the
weakness of the recovery in the later half of this year and partly that
unemployment lags behind output changes by between 6-9 months. The
latest Labour Force Survey results provide evidence that the claimant
count understated unemployment on the internationally accepted ILO/OECD
definition (i.e. those searching for work in the last four weeks and
available to start in the next two). As of Spring 1990 the LFS measure
stood 300,000 higher than the claimant count. As table 1 shows this
meant that the UK's unemployment rate stood at about one percentage
point higher than that indicated by the claimant measure. This
difference significantly alters our view of unemployment in the UK
relative to our EEC partners. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Wage and price inflation (tables 2, 9 and 10)
The most recent data indicate that the underlying rate of increase of
whole economy average earnings is 9 1/4 per cent. Although this is a
half per cent reduction since the previous quarter it is disappointing
given the substantial falls in wage drift that must have occurred since
the downturn began. For example, overtime hours worked in manufacturing
have been falling rapidly since the second half of last year. However,
the CBI's pay databank shows that manufacturing settlements fell to
8.3 per cent in the first quarter of this year from a growth rate of 8.9
per cent in the previous quarter. Further confirmation that wage
inflation is receding is provided by Incomes Data Services who report
that two thirds of pay deals monitored by them at the start of the first
quarter of this year were above 10 per cent whereas by March only one
third were above 10 per cent
The dispersion of pay settlements has increased during the early
phase of the downturn. Sectors particularly affected by the recession
are offering much lower pay settlements. For example, Thomas Cook staff
have experienced temporary pay cuts, pay settlements within the banking
industry have been between 5 to 8 per cent and the 5 per cent pay
increase in the concrete industry indicates the severity of the
recession in the construction industry.
Although average settlements and earnings are moving in a downward
direction the current rate of increase is clearly not sustainable. For
example, unit labour costs in manufacturing were growing at 12 per cent
in February of this year. Settlements should decline through this year
as unemployment increases rapidly and retail price inflation continues
to fall. We envisage that average earnings will be growing at around 8
per cent by the end of this year. Although the continued increasing
slackness in the labour market will put further downward pressure on
earnings next year this will be partly offset by strong import price
growth (stemming largely from the recent strength of the dollar) and a
recovery in productivity. Consequently earnings may still be above 7 per
cent at the end of 1992. Throughout our forecast we have assumed that
the switch from the poll-tax to VAT will have a neutral effect upon wage
inflation, although the increase in the RPI will be reduced.
Manufacturing output prices are currently still accelerating which
is disappointing given the sustained previous fall in manufacturing
input prices. However, the latest CBI survey firmly indicates that
manufacturing prices will soon slow down as the number of companies
expecting to increase prices for domestic sales is lower than at any
time since the survey began. We are also predicting falls in
manufacturing wholesale inflation but do not expect this to occur until
the growth in unit labour costs has fallen (in the latter part of 1991)
as these costs pressures are the main reason why output price increases
are still high now. Lower growth in unit labour costs next year should
ensure a further fall in manufacturing output inflation in 1992.
The underlying rate of inflation as represented by the consumer
price index (corrected for the poll-tax treatment in the national
accounts) should bottom-out by the end of this year. The officially
published consumer price index will again be distorted during 1991 by
the reduction in the poll-tax from the second quarter of this year.
Underlying consumer price inflation will creep up again next year as the
rise in import prices will feed directly into consumer goods.
The increase in the retail price index will fall considerably
through this year as mortgage interest payments decline in line with our
projected base rate falls. By the end of 1991 retail price inflation
should be around 4 per cent but this will increase slightly to 4 1/2 per
cent next year as underlying inflation is pushed up by rising import
prices. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Public sector finance (table 11)
It seems that the public sector was roughly in financial balance for
the 1990/1 fiscal year. This compares with a debt repayment of 8 billion
[pounds] for the previous fiscal year. Recent research by the Treasury
has shown that the PSBR is more pro-cyclical than previously thought and
this is consistent with the dramatic deterioration in public finances
since the beginning of the recession. Revenue growth will continue to
decline as corporation and income tax are depressed by lower economic
activity and current grants will increase considerably given the actual
and expected rise in unemployment. The March Budget will have an almost
neutral effect on the PSBR for the 1991/2 fiscal year although the
partial switch from the poll tax to VAT will have a more pro-cyclical
negative effect upon revenues. However, transfers from Kuwait etc. in
the form of Gulf War payments will slow down the slide into public
sector deficit. Given these factors we are expecting a PSBR of
approximately 8 billion [pounds] for this fiscal year followed by a
further deteriotation to around 14 1/2 billion [pounds] next year.
As explained in Part One, our forecast is based on a 50-50 mixture
of Conservative and Labour policies (as the result of the election is
uncertain). Therefore, privatisation revenue is set at roughly half that
scheduled by the government and public expenditure is somewhat higher.
We also assume some limited tax cuts in the medium term. [Tabular Data
Omitted]
Medium and long-term forecast (table 12)
It seems that the average growth rate for the UK economy for the rest
of this century will be around 2 1/2 per cent. Growth may be slightly
above this rate in the mid-1990s if interest rates fall in line with our
projections. Given this profile for GDP we expect unemployment to remain
around the 2.5 million for some years. UK membership of ERM will dictate
that external price competitiveness cannot be improved by exchange-rate
depreciation. Therefore, to maintain a sustainable current balance
deficit over the longer-term unemployment at this level is necessary to
maintain competitiveness by restraining domestic earnings and prices
growth. Slow employment growth enables total productivity to grow by
approximately 2 per cent in the medium term.
Consumers' expenditure will probably be the major source of
demand over the medium-term period. From 1993 onwards the personal
sector savings ratio will probably experience a gradual but clear fall.
This is partly due to our assumption of monetary union circa 1997 and
the corresponding fall in UK interest rates towards German levels (see
chart 3). Consumption is therefore largely driven by upward revaluations
in net wealth and strong consumer credit growth as base rates fall.
Subdued real disposable income growth in the medium-term also
contributes to the savings ratio fall. Downward pressure on wage
inflation from both the high level of unemployment and the discipline of
ERM membership explains much of the slow growth in real incomes.
The balance of payments deficit will probably deteriorate in the
mid-1990s. This will be associated with the aforementioned decline in
the personal sector savings ratio and the continued dis-saving of the
public sector. The PSBR will probably remain at around 2 1/2 per cent
until the mid-1990s due to high unemployment and the lower growth rate
of GDP compared to the 1980s. In contrast, over the same period, the
financial deficit of the company sector will gradually diminish but
renewed investment and dividend growth will limit the extent of the
recovery in corporate finances.
The medium-term supply-side effects of the expected decline in
manufacturing investment caused by the current recession are analysed in
Box 2 below. [Tabular Data Omitted]
BOX 2. THE SUPPLY SIDE AND THE RECESSION (*)
The stated objective of the government has been to reduce inflation
by maintaining a high level of interest rates. The current contraction
in demand provides evidence that this policy is certainly deflationary in the short term but the associated fall in investment will cause
longer term damage to the supply side of the economy. We have attempted
to quantify these supply side effects by simulating what would have
happened to the economy if manufacturing investment had continued to
grow at its trend rate rather than declining during the recession as in
our main forecast. We have therefore constructed a variant where
manufacturing investment grows from the last quarter of 1990 at an
annual rate of 3 per cent for three years. We have ensured that the ex
ante demand for manufactures is the same as in our main forecast by
reducing expenditure on consumer durables by the same amount as the
extra investment generated in the variant. Therefore, the simulation
captures a scenario where the current recession is generated by a
contraction in demand by reducing consumption without damaging
manufacturing investment. Given that the UK is now a member of the ERM
we have assumed that the exchange rate and interest rates are the same
as in our main forecast. The simulation results are expressed as
percentage changes from our main forecast and are shown in table B1. B1.
Table B1. Manufacturing investment growing at trend rate of 3 per
cent per annum
1991 1992 1993
Manufacturing investment (volume) 16.6 1992 30.3
Manufacturing capacity utilisation -0.6 29.3 -3.5
Manufacturing capacity (volume) 0.9 -2.2 6.3
Manufacturing output (volume) 0.3 3.5 2.8
Consumer prices 0.7 1.3 -3.7
Average earnings -0.6 -2.4 -1.0
Manufacturing productivity -0.2 -1.2 3.2
Imports of manufactures (volume) 0.1 1.3 -1.1
The National Institute's econometric model embodies a vintage
capital model of production. New investment embodies technical progress
which will tend to raise the average productivity of labour. The capital
stock is defined in terms of vintages of machinery and variations in
demand and (hence capacity utilisation) will change the age profile of
machinery used and the productivity of workers. In our model, a higher
level of manufacturing capacity utilisation will raise both prices and
imports. The first effect is capturing the pressure of demand (i.e.
overheating) and higher imports result from a deterioration in non-price
competitiveness factors (i.e. delivery delays, poor quality control
etc.). Higher import also cause substitution away from domestic goods
and result in a fall in UK production.
Turning to the simulation results we see that imposing a trend rate
of growth for manufacturing investment raises its level by about 30 per
cent compared to our main forecast over the period shown. Manufacturing
capacity is therefore higher with the result that when the economy
recovers from the recession |overheating' is not so prevalent and
there is less upward pressure on the price level. Productivity is also
higher; in our base forecast older vintages of machinery are brought
back into production when output rises whereas in the simulation younger
vintages of capital are employed which embody superior technology. Wages
benefit from the higher productivity and therefore earnings do not fall
as much as prices. However, unit costs fall because of the rise in
productivity. As the nominal exchange rate is fixed, price
competitiveness improves. Non-price competitiveness benefits from the
lower level of capacity utilisation and this increases domestic
manufacturing output as UK goods replace those previously supplied from
overseas.
Given that this simulation only relates to manufacturing
investment, it is fair to assume that the damaging supply side effects
of the current recession will be greater than those reported above as we
are also expecting substantial falls in non-manufacturing investment
this year.
NOTE
(*) This exercise is based upon similar simulations originally
performed by Simon Wren-Lewis in |Supply, liquidity and credit: the
Institute's domestic econometric macromodel', National
Institute Economic Review, November 1988, pp. 32-43.
ANNEX. MODELLING THE EVOLUTION OF STERLING'S CREDIBILITY IN
THE ERM
Introduction
Part Two of this chapter has discussed some of the issues involved in
forecasting the exchange rate under a policy regime where the
authorities have stated their intention to hold the exchange rate within
a particular band but the credibility of that policy announcement is not
complete. Accordingly, the forecast assumes that the exchange rate
depreciates in line with market expectations. This Annex illustrates the
implications for the forecast outturn if the government does stick to
its intended exchange rate path and the private sector gradually learns
about the government's true policy stance.
Despite the government's announced policy of pegging the
sterling-D-Mark exchange rate, the main forecast described in this
chapter is characterised by a forecast path which reflects the mean
expected depreciation of sterling against the D-Mark as given by the
differential between sterling and D-Mark short term interest rates.
Thus, we are assuming that the uncovered arbitrage condition holds
exactly, implying that, ex ante, investors will be indifferent between
holding sterling and D-Mark assets. As explained in Part 2, the expected
depreciation implied by the interest rate differential will depend upon
the probability distribution as perceived by the markets of all possible
outcomes for the exchange rate. The base forecast which is assumed to
reflect this probability distribution is shown in Chart A1. In what
follows, we illustrate how this expected path for the exchange rate may
have been arrived at by making a number of sylised assumptions about the
underlying probability distribution. In doing this, we are necessarily
taking as given the complex economic and political factors considered in
Part 2, which actually determine this probability distribution. As will
be shown below, the methodology required for computing the mean expected
depreciation is itself complicated enough.
Computing the mean expected depreciation
The authorities have entered into a fixed exchange rate regime, the
ERM. Let us suppose the announced policy rule is that interest rates
will be set at the required level to hold the exchange rate at its
target level against the D-Mark; we assume this is set at the forecast
91q2 value of 2.97 D-mark. Further, let us suppose that interest rates
can only be changed at the beginning of each year at which time
expectations within the private sector will also be set. However, at any
time within the year there is a possibility that the authorities will
realign by a certain amount with a particular probability. Given the
foreign exchange market's assessment of this probability
distribution, the mean expected depreciation can be calculated and hence
the expected path for interest rates.
The mean expected depreciation of the sterling-D-Mark rate assumed
for the first four years in our base forecast is given by the top row of
Table A1. What type of probability distribution for expected
depreciation might have generated this path? Clearly, the underlying
probability distribution will not be unique since the expected path may,
for example, be consistent with a large probability of a small
depreciation or a small probability of a large one, or some combination
of both. To illustrate the methodology, it is instructive to postulate one particular distribution which might plausibly have generated these
expectations. This is done by using a probability tree which has been
constructed to be consistent with our forecast path for the exchange
rate and interest rates: see Table A2. It embodies the following sylised
assumptions;
Table : A1. Expected exchange rate depreciation
(in case of no realignments ex post after year 1)
Expectation formed 1 2 3 4
at beginning year
1 1.8 1.6 1.3 1.0
2 1.56 1.21 0.85
3 1.10 0.69
4 0.55
[Tabular Data Omitted] - in any year the probability distribution is
bi-modal in the sense that the exchange rate can either stay fixed or
be realigned by a particular amount.
- if the authorities do choose to realign, they will devalue by 10
per cent.
- in year 1, the probability of a realignment is 18 per cent. For
every year that the authorities are observed to
hold the exchange rate fixed (which it is assumed is done by
concerted intervention within the ERM), the
probability of a future realignment declines, to under 10 per cent
after four years.
- if the authorities do realign by 10 per cent, they are then
strongly expected to allow the exchange rate to
depreciate gradually thereafter (by 2 per cent with probability
0.9)
- if the authorities do realign but then hold the exchange rate
fixed, the expectation that they will not
depreciate again (i.e. their credibility) builds up gradually. The
probability tree contains all the relevant information for calculating
expected exchange rate movements. Each |branch' of the tree
represents a possible outcome for the exchange rate in a particular
year. The two branches at the top represent the alternative
possibilities in the first year. The sixteen branches at the bottom of
the tree represent the proliferation of possible outcomes by the fourth
year. From this we can calculate the ex ante expected devaluation in the
exchange rate for the first four years (which will be equal to the
required interest rate differential) as expected at the beginning of the
first year; see the top row of table A1. For example, the expected
depreciation in year 2 as perceived at the beginning of year 1 is given
by the probability of a realignment of 10 per cent, given that there was
no realignment in the first year (0.82 X 0.156 X 10) plus the
probability of a depreciation of 2 per cent in year 2 which would happen
if there had been a realignment in year 1 (0.18 X 0.9 X 2). This sums to
1.6 per cent as given in table A1.
Evolving credibility: stylised example
Of course, in this particular example, the path implied by the
central expectation will never occur so after one year expectations will
have been wrong ex post. The probability tree then informs us how to
revise our expectations of future exchange rate movements depending on
which branch of the probability tree we have |travelled along'. To
give a specific example of how expectations may evolve, suppose the
authorities chose not to realign during the first four years. In our
example, this happens to be the outcome which is most likely to occur,
happening with probably 0.58. Table A1 illustrates how exchange rate
expectations are sequentially revised over the future as the private
sector effectively learns about the government's policy intentions.
For example, at the beginning of the forecast period, the exchange rate
is expected to decline by 1 per cent in the fourth year of the forecast.
However, by the time the fourth year begins and the authorities have
been observed to hold the exchange rate fixed, the expected depreciation
for that year is then revised downwards to 0.55 per cent (see the fourth
row of table A1). This may be interpreted as an increase in credibility
of the authorities' fixed exchange rate commitment which will
consequently allow interest rates to be cut in the fourth year by more
than was envisaged at the beginning of the forecast period.
In fact, this example is of more than academic interest. By
computing this path where credibility evolves gradually, we may be
putting ourselves in the position of the Treasury forecasters who may
know with certainty (for the sake of argument) that the exchange rate
will not be realigned. This is a specific example of the general case
where forecasters hold different expectations to the markets. The
interesting corollary to this is that even if the Treasury were using
the Institute model and had the same information regarding all
variables, they should be producing a different forecast from ourselves
because of their superior information on the true intended policy
stance.
The evolution of credibility in the forecast - or - |A
Treasury's Eye View'
Having illustrated the methodological issues involved in deriving an
ex post forecast where the private sector learns about government
behaviour, it is now possible to illustrate the implications of this for
the forecast itself. As in the stylised example given above, it is
interesting to illustrate the ex post forecast outcome if the government
does not allow the sterling-D-Mark exchange rate to depreciate despite
the fact that the market is discounting such a fall. As noted above, by
doing this forecast variant we are perhaps putting ourselves in the
position of Treasury forecasters who know that the exchange rate will
not be realigned but who are confronted by a private sector which has a
mean expectation of a non-zero depreciation (note that in our base
forecast we are implicitly assuming that we have the same information
about government intentions as the rest of the market).
To undertake this exercise on the forecast itself is slightly more
complicated than the stylised example for a number of reasons;
- the updating of expectations is carried out every quarter. Rather
than computing a probability tree on a
quarterly basis (which would have 65536 branches by the end of the
fourth year) we adopt an updating rule
for the expected depreciation which approximately retains the same
properties as that used in the stylised
example. Starting from the ex ante mean expected depreciation shown
in chart A1, it is assumed that for
every period the government is observed to hold the sterling-D-Mark
exchange rate flat, so the depreciation
expected thereafter will be progressively reduced relative to its
base value until it has complete credibility by
the end of the decade. For example after two years holding the
sterling-D-Mark rate fixed, the mean
expected depreciation for every period thereafter is assumed to be
reduced by 25 per cent, whereas after
four years, it has been approximately halved (see chart A1). As the
expected depreciation falls, so interest
rates decline in line.
- as exchange rate policy is defined with respect to the
sterling-D-Mark rate, we need to re-calculate the
implied effect on the sterling-dollar and the sterling effective
exchange rate every time that the sterling-D-Mark
expectation or outturn differs (note that the effective exchange
rate will fall even when the D-Mark rate
is constant because of the assumed forecast appreciation of the
dollar against the D-Mark).
- since the exercise is undertaken on a model of the whole economy we
need to consider the expectations of
other parts of the private sector such as wage bargainers, as well
as the foreign exchange markets. We
assume, as in the base forecast itself, that the expectations held
by these different groups do not differ, that
is they perceive the same probability distribution of realignments
(for the implications of making a different
assumption see Miller and Sutherland (1990)).
The actual implementation of this type of ex post forecast is also
more complicated than the procedure used to derive the base case. This
is because the usual consistent expectations assumption can not be
adopted since expectations are continually being falsified. As a
consequence, a sequential or rolling forecast procedure needs to be
adopted. This technique is necessary whenever expectations are formed in
a forward-looking manner and when the information set on which those
expectations are conditioned alters unexpectedly within the forecast
period; in this case the |news' which is obtained during the
forecast horizon is that the exchange rate has not moved in line with
expectations and hence that the subsequent expected path must change.
Thus, the actual forecast procedure adopted is as follows;
(1) Start from the forecast base beginning in 91Q3. (2) Hold
expectations constant but run the forecast with the sterling-D-Mark rate
flat for 91Q3. (3) Update exchange rate expectations and the required
interest rate profile from 91Q4 onwards, and
recompute the forecast from 91Q4 onwards with expectations set
consistently again. (4) Repeat (2) but with the exchange rate flat in
91Q4. (5) and so on.
Since the expected depreciation is relatively small after 1995 with
the expected convergence towards monetary union, the rolling forecast
procedure is only carried out for four years. A fuller description of
how this |stacked solution' technique is adopted in a stochastic simulations context, see Ireland and Westaway (1990).
We can now determine how much difference it makes to the forecast
outcome if the government sticks to its exchange rate commitment and the
private sector gradually perceives this. Charts A1-A3 compare the ex
post outcomes of the sequential forecast, which we will refer to as
variant A, with the original ex ante prediction, our base forecast.
Period by period, variant A shows the sterling-D-Mark rate remaining
constant for the first four years (chart A2) despite the original
expectation that it would depreciate, as reflected in the short term
interest rate differential (see chart A1). As a result, variant A
displays ex post inconsistency of the exchange rate path with the
interest rate differential over the first four years. Subsequently,
expectational consistency does hold, but the expected depreciation after
95Q2 has been lessened because of the enhanced credibility of the
authorities' exchange rate commitment. Chart A3 clearly
demonstrates the advantages to the government of holding the exchange
rate at its target level as in variant A. Inflation is some 1 1/2 per
cent lower over the first four years as a direct consequence of lower
import prices caused by the |unexpectedly' lower exchange rate.
Indeed, since inflation undershoots European levels, it might appear
that the authorities could afford, ex post, to relax the stance of
policy as a |reward' for their commitment to exchange-rate
stability. This case should not be overstated, however, since some
degree of low inflation relative to our competitors may still be
necessary to restore the real exchange rate to its sustainable
equilibrium level (which in previous work we have argued is below
prevailing levels, see Wren-Lewis et al, (1990)).
It is important to note that most of the gains in inflation
performance in variant A occur because of the direct effect of the
higher exchange rate. Interestingly, since the period-by-period revision
to future depreciation is modest the |credibility' effects caused
by gradual learning manifested in lower expectations of depreciation
over the future seem relatively small. But this is not to say that the
lack of credibility of policy in the ex ante forecast and in variant A
is not costly. Chart A3 also illustrates how the inflation outcome would
differ if the exchange rate policy of the authorities had been foreseen correctly. This is shown as variant B which shows an improved inflation
outturn relative to Variant A since the implications of the higher
exchange rate are anticipated by forward-looking agents in labour and
product markets who revise down their inflation expectations
accordingly. In fact, the direct expectational effect on inflation is
even larger than this but that improvement is partly offset by the
effects of lower interest rates which necessarily have to fall to German
levels if the exchange rate target is completely credible; the lower
interest rates also produce higher output than in variant A but this
effect is relatively unimportant and short lived.
By quantifying the unequivocal superiority of variant B over
variant A and even more so over the base case, this exercise illustrates
clearly how important it is that the authorities should be able to
persuade the markets of their intentions to hold the exchange rate
fixed. It also casts light on the question of the validity of the so
called |Walters critique' of UK membership of the ERM which
suggested that the policy could not be sustained because of the
disruptive effects on domestic demand of lowering interest rates too
quickly (see Walters (1990)). Our conclusion, which has been confirmed
by recent experience of sterling within the ERM, suggests first that the
|Walters critique' oversimplified the problem by ignoring the issue
of evolving credibility. Second, it indicates that even if credibility
of the authorities' ERM commitment were total the expectational
effects on inflation would outweigh the potentially harmful effects of
lower interest rates.
What are the main conclusions from this exercise? First, it
illustrates clearly that forecasts of future exchange rate movements
based on the mean expectation may be misleading for a forecaster who
holds significantly different views about government intentions from the
rest of the markets. Second, it has demonstrated the appropriate
forecasting methodology in these circumstances and for the more general
case where expectations evolve during the forecast horizon. Finally, and
perhaps most importantly, it has illustrated that consideration of the
evolution of the credibility of sterling within the ERM has an important
bearing on the immediate prospects for the UK economy. In particular, it
shows that the forecast path for inflation will be lower than we are
currently predicting if the government manages to hold the exchange rate
around its current level rather than depreciating in line with market
expectations. Moreover, this inflation outcome will be improved still
further if both wage bargainers and foreign exchange operators can be
persuaded of the government's resolve to stick to this policy.
REFERENCES
Ireland, J. and Westaway, P.F., (1990) |Stochastic simulation and
forecast uncertainty in a forward-looking model', National
Institute Discussion Paper No. 183 Miller, M. and Sutherland, A.
(1990) |The |Walters critique' of the EMS: A Case of Inconsistent
expectations', CEPR
Discussion Paper No. 480. Walters, A. (1990) |Sterling in
Danger', London, Fontana. Wren-Lewis, S. Westaway, P., Soteri, S.
and Barrell, R., (1990) |Choosing the rate: an analysis of the optimum
level of entry
for sterling in the ERM', National Institute Discussion Paper
no. 171, also Manchester School forthcoming.
PHOTO : Chart 1. UK export of manufactures
PHOTO : Chart 2. UK exchange rates
PHOTO : Chart 3. UK and German interest rates
PHOTO : Chart A1. UK - German short-term interest-rate differential
PHOTO : Chart A2. Sterling-D-Mark exchange rate
PHOTO : Chart A3. Annual price inflation (consumer price index)