The world economy.
Gurney, Andrew ; Veld, Jan Willem In't ; Barrell, Ray 等
CHAPTER II. THE WORLD ECONOMY
Recent developments and short-term prospects GNP growth in the major
seven economies continues to decline from the cyclical peak reached in
1988. The latest national accounts statistics show that all major seven
economies are now growing more slowly than they did last year, with the
United States, United Kingdom and Canada in recession. This slowdown in
activity appears to have been caused primarily by the tightening of
monetary policy that occurred between 1988 and 1990. Short-term interest
rates rose by 4.4 percentage points in Germany between 1987 and 1990, by
3 percentage points in Japan between 1987 and 1990, and by 2.2 per cent
in the United States between 1987 and 1989.
The Gulf crisis contributed to the slower growth of economic
activity in the second half of 1990. Uncertainties over the future
supply of oil caused world oil prices to rise from $16 per barrel in
June to $40 per barrel at the beginning of October. Uncertainty
generated by the crisis also contributed to a drop in consumer
confidence, especially in the United States, and in investor confidence.
Concern about the economic consequences of the crisis was dispelled
by the outbreak of hostilities in January, when the oil price fell to
below $20 per barrel. With the conclusion of the war consumer confidence
has recovered and stock markets in the United States and the United
Kingdom have registered record highs. This may be attributed not only to
the reversal of negative impulses arising from the Gulf crisis, but also
to the reduction in US interest rates which took place in February.
We are still too close to the events of the Gulf crisis to estimate
how important an effect they have had on the world economy. However as
the negative impulses generated by the crisis were reversed within six
months it is unlikely that there will be significant lingering effects
on world economic prospects. A significant slowdown in economic activity
was already in prospect before the crisis, as a result of the tightening
of monetary policy between 1988 and 1990. We are forecasting that
economic activity will begin to grow more rapidly in the second half of
this year. As with the slowdown that we are experiencing now, the main
cause of this recovery is the evolution of monetary policy.
Table 1 summarises our forecast. GNP growth in the major seven
economies is expected to decline from 2.5 per cent in 1990 to 0.9 per
cent in 1991, before rising to 2.8 per cent in 1992. The pattern of
lower growth in 1991 but a recovery in 1992 is common to all seven major
economies, but the scale differs markedly. GNP growth in the major four
economies will range from zero in the United States to 3 per cent in
Japan for 1991, and from 2.4 per cent in the United States to 3.7 per
cent in Japan for 1992. [Tabular Data Omitted]
The United States experienced a 2.8 per cent (annual rate) fall in
GNP in the first quarter of 1991, indicating that the recession there is
deeper than had been expected. Our forecast of zero growth for 1991 as a
whole arises because recovery is expected to occur in the latter part of
this year. The main force behind this recovery should be renewed growth
in domestic demand, in response to lower interest rates.
Recent developments in interest rates are shown in charts 1 and 2,
and our forecast for short-term interest rates also shown in table 4.
The fall in US GNP in the first quarter of 1991 prompted the Federal
Reserve Board to reduce its discount rate by 0.5 percentage points to
5.5 per cent on 30 April. Monetary easing by the Fed reduces the risk
that the US recession will be prolonged by a credit crunch. We are
forecasting that three-month interest rates in the United States will
average 6.2 per cent in 1991, down 1.9 percentage points from 1990, and
2.9 percentage points from 1989. Our expectation that interest rates
have now fallen sufficiently to stimulate domestic demand is supported
by recent increases in the Department of Commerce leading indicators
index and a recovery in the Conference Board index of consumer
confidence. [Tabular Data Omitted]
While monetary policy has become less restrictive in the United
States, it remains tight in both Japan and Germany. At the G7 finance
ministers' meeting at the end of April the United States indicated
that it would like to see other countries reduce their interest rates as
well. This proposal was not taken up, on the grounds that both Japan and
Germany feel that their economies are still operating close to their
current supply potential, and are therefore unwilling to risk the
inflationary consequences of a premature monetary easing. In Box 1 we
report two simulations of our econometric model GEM(1). The first
simulation shows the effects of an interest-rate reduction in the
interest-rate reduction. Our results indicate that a global reduction
would add little to US GNP growth, but would lead to higher demand and
inflation in other countries, most notably Japan.
Chart 3 shows capacity utilisation rates in the major four
economies. Capacity utilisation remains high in Germany and Japan, and
inflation is forecast to rise in Japan in 1991, with the prospect of a
renewed rise in inflation in Germany in 1992 after a small decline in
1991 (see table 1 and chart 4). These indicators provide a case for
maintaining high interest rates, although there is a danger that if
monetary policy is held tight for too long then policy will exacerbate
the business cycle, driving the economy into recession rather than
merely dampening excess demand. On these grounds a reduction in interest
rates in Japan may occur later this year.
The situation in Germany is complicated by the pressures caused by
reunification. In the absence of reunification GNP growth in western
Germany would have declined in 1990 to around 3 per cent, instead of
rising to 4.5 per cent. In 1990 the German economy benefited from an
initial stimulus resulting from monetary union and unification, as east
Germans gained access to western markets, especially for durable goods.
In 1991 that initial stimulus will no longer apply, and indeed rising
unemployment and short-term working in the eastern Lander will cause
demand from the east to fall. It will also increase the German budget
deficit to around DM170bn. Increased government borrowing will entail some upward pressure on interest rates, especially as the Bundesbank
appears determined to ensure that the government acts to reduce the
budget deficit in the medium term. Money market rates indicate that in
the short run German interest rates may have further to rise, but there
is again a risk that maintaining a tight policy for too long could be
destabilising. In our forecast we have assumed that German interest
rates remain unchanged for this year, but that some relaxation occurs
next year, conditional on clear evidence that the rate of growth has
slowed to around 3 per cent per annum.
The French and Italian economies are both growing more slowly. The
French economy has slowed in response to higher interest rates, which
have been required both to restrain domestic inflationary pressure and
to maintain the value of the franc within the exchange-rate mechanism.
Italian interest rates only rose by 1.2 percentage points between 1987
and 1989, and fell in 1990. In the last three years, interest-rates in
both France and Italy have converged on German interest rates, as
foreign exchange markets have become increasingly convinced of their
governments' determination to maintain the value of their
currencies against the D-Mark. Convergence on German interest rates has
also occurred in other European countries. Interest rates in Austria and
the Netherlands are now virtually identical to German rates. Belgian
rates are around 0.5 per cent higher. Italian domestic demand growth has
slowed because of a tighter fiscal policy stance, and net exports have
worsened because of the loss of competitiveness arising from relatively
high inflation. Although France and Italy have both benefited from the
stimulus to German GNP, the net impact on both economies of higher
German GNP growth is not great. Simulations on our econometric model,
GEM, show that fiscal expansion equivalent to 1 per cent of GNP in
Germany leads to increases of 0.03 per cent of GNP in France and 0.05
per cent in Italy in the first year of the simulation, and 0.05 per cent
and 0.08 per cent respectively after 3 years (table 1 of Barrell and
Gurney (1991a)). In this regard the often quoted metaphor of the German
economy as a European locomotive exaggerates its significance.
The slowdown in economic activity within the European Community has
caused the various central banks to contemplate a less restrictive
monetary policy. Their ability to reduce interest rates is constrained by the need to maintain ERM parities. In recent weeks this constraint has become binding for the French authorities, since if the franc
weakens further it will breach its 6 per cent divergence limit with
respect to the Spanish peseta. While the peseta remains strong within
the exchange-rate mechanism, Spanish economic policy will continue to
act as a constraint on monetary policy within the rest of Europe. We
report on recent developments within the Spanish economy in Box 2.
Slower growth of the major countries' GNP will also result in
slower growth of world industrial production and world trade in 1991. We
are forecasting that OECD industrial production will grow by 0.5 per
cent this year, its lowest growth rate since 1982. World trade in
manufactures is forecast to grow by 4 per cent, and total world trade by
4.5 per cent, marginally higher than last year, but well below the 7.1
per cent per annum average growth between 1985 and 1989. Chart 5 shows
that growth in world trade in manufactures has tended to follow the same
cyclical pattern as the growth of major seven GNP, although the
amplitude of the cycle is approximately twice as large. A simple
extrapolation of this pattern would suggest that our forecast for world
trade in 1991 is optimistic. However there are two special factors that
are likely to keep world trade growth strong in relation to G7 GNP
growth. The first of these is the collapse of east German and east
European manufacturing industry, which will mean that their demand for
manufactured goods will be met by foreign producers. The second stimulus
to world trade arises from oil producing countries spending some of the
extra revenue they received in the second half of last year, when oil
prices rose to $40 per barrel. In 1992 we are forecasting that G7 GNP
growth will be close to trend. This will also allow industrial
production, world trade in manufactures and total world trade to grow at
around trend values. In 1992 we are expecting growth of 3.4 per cent in
industrial production, 5.7 per cent in total world trade and 6.3 per
cent in world trade in manufactures.
Our forecast for commodity prices is shown in table 2 and
illustrated in charts 6 and 7. Slower growth in world economic activity
has been reflected in slower growth in demand for commodities, which has
resulted in a general weakening of commodity prices. [Tabular Data
Omitted]
The prices of metals declined in the fourth quarter of 1990 and the
first quarter of 1991, although there has been a recovery in copper
prices since February. Metals prices are expected to continue to weaken
in 1991, as mining and production capacity have expanded following the
large increase in prices between 1987 and 1989.
Coffee and cocoa prices have weakened significantly since the
second quarter of last year. Stocks remain strong in both commodities.
Low prices have led coffee producers to reduce their production, which
should enable prices to recover, but surplus production of cocoa looks
likely to continue, keeping prices depressed. Sugar prices fell by
around 30 per cent in 1990, but could rise in 1991 as a result of
reductions in sugar production.
The International Cotton Advisory Committee estimate that cotton
production will exceed consumption by 3 million bales in 1991/92 and 2
million bales in 1992-93. If this trend continues there will be downward
pressure on prices, but this may not be evident in the short term as
world cotton stocks are currently low. The price of wool fell 40 per
cent in 1990 following the suspension of wool price support in
Australia.
The price of oil is forecast to average $17 per barrel in 1991. The
Gulf crisis has temporarily reduced Iraqi and Kuwaiti oil production,
but there has been no decrease in world supply, as other producers,
notably Saudi Arabia, have raised their production. In the short term
this development gives Saudi Arabia more leverage over the oil market,
although this will be reduced when Iraqi and Kuwaiti production is
restored. In the medium term we expect real oil prices to grow at around
3 per cent per annum.
Exchange-rate developments
Chart 8 shows recent movements in exchange rates. Between November
and the end of April the US dollar appreciated by 18 per cent against
the D-Mark and by 7 per cent against the yen. Annex 1 looks at the
volatility of exchange rates between the major seven currencies since
the Louvre accord of 1987. A degree of exchange-rate stability was
achieved in the second half of 1988 and first half of 1989, but there
has been renewed volatility in 1990 and early 1991.
This new volatility has had a number of causes. The most important
is probably the unification of Germany and proposed market
liberalisation in eastern Europe. These changes have caused foreign
exchange markets to reassess exchange rates in the light of the implied
long-term current account and capital account flows. In particular
Germany will export less capital, but should also become more
competitive in the long term, as the increase in its supply of skilled
labour should reduce the level of real wages in the German economy.
Reduced capital exports imply a higher long-run equilibrium real
exchange rate, while the latter implication is that unchanged nominal
exchange rates would lead to lower real exchange rates. The appreciation
of the D-Mark at the end of 1989 reflected these developments.
A second cause of exchange-rate volatility appears to have been a
re-evaluation of the returns available from investing in Japan compared
to abroad. The yen depreciated by 22 per cent between February 1989 and
April 1990 but has since appreciated by 16 per cent. The scale of
depreciation was puzzling, and may have been caused by a temporary
increase in capital outflow relative to current account surpluses. This
development may have been triggered by the European Commission's
single market programme, causing Japanese firms to increase their
investment abroad. The effect was to give Japanese firms a competitive
advantage which, if it had been maintained, would have caused current
account surpluses to exceed long-term capital outflows. On this reading
the subsequent exchange-rate appreciation has taken the yen back towards
a sustainable exchange-rate path.
BOX 1. THE EFFECTS OF LOWER INTEREST RATES
We have run two simulations on our econometric model, GEM, to
illustrate the effects of a co-ordinated reduction in interest rates,
and the effects of a reduction in interest rates in the United States
alone. In both simulations exchange-rates are held unchanged from their
base values. In each simulation interest rates are reduced by 1
percentage point for the first two years of the simulation.
Table A1i shows the effect of a reduction in interest rates in the
US alone. US GNP is 0.5 per cent above base in year 2 of the simulation
but has returned to base by year 5. Inflation increases in the US, by a
maximum of 0.2 percentage points in year 3 of the simulation. The
increases in US GNP and inflation compared to the rest of the world
causes the US current account to GNP ratio to deteriorate compared to
the simulation base, by 0-12 percentage points in year 2 of the
simulation, but only 0-01 percentage points in year 5.
The US interest-rate reduction increases GNP and inflation in the
other major 7 economies, and causes their current account to GNP ratios
to improve. Canada experiences the greatest changes with GNP 0-2
percentage points above base in year 2, inflation 0-08 percentage points
above base in year 3, and the current balance to GNP ratio 0-14
percentage points above base in year 2. France experiences the lowest
increase in its GNP. Japan the lowest increase in inflation and the UK
the smallest improvement in its current account to GNP ratio.
The USA has recently been pressing for global reduction in interest
rates, as shown in Table A1ii. However our model suggests that this
would have only increased US GNP by a further 0-12 percentage points in
year 2 of the simulation and 0-22 percentage points in year 5 of the
simulation. There would be an additional increase in US inflation of
0-16 percentage points by year 5 of the simulation, and the US current
account balance would not deteriorate as much as in the first
simulation. From year 3 onwards the US current account ratio would
actually have improved compared to the simulation base.
However the co-ordinated interest rate reduction would also
increase GNP and inflation in the rest of the world. GNP in all seven
would be more than 0-4 percentage points above base in year 3 of the
simulation, with Germany 1-1 per cent above base and Japan 1-5 per cent
above base. In year 3 the increases in inflation range from 0-19 to 0-62
percentage points above base, and in year 5 from 0-13 to 0-48 percentage
points. The stimulus to inflation is greatest in Japan and the United
Kingdom, and least in Canada and the United States. Japan also
experiences the greatest deterioration in its current account to GNP
ratio while the United States has the greatest improvement. [Tabular
Data Omitted]
BOX 2. RECENT DEVELOPMENTS AND PROSPECTS FOR THE SPANISH ECONOMY
Table B1 shows that the Spanish economy has been transformed since
1987. In each of 1987, 1988 and 1989 GDP grew by over 5 per cent per
annum. In the previous twelve years GDP growth had never exceeded 3-5
per cent, and had been greater than 2 per cent in only four of those
years. Furthermore this improved growth performance occurred with
inflation had below 5-5 per cent in 1987 and 1988, compared with 16-6
per cent in 1980.
The cause of this transformation was Spanish accession to the EEC in January 1986. The table shows that this provided the stimulus for
investment growth in excess of 10 per cent per annum for four
consecutive years, compared with an average annual growth rate of -1.4
per cent per annum in the five preceding years. Spain is now well
integrated into the European economy with around 75 per cent of its
exports and 60 per cent of its imports traded with other European
economies.
Spain strengthened its commitment to European integration by
joining the exchange rate mechanism in June 1989. The peseta is allowed
to deviate by up to 6 per cent from its central rate within the ERM.
Ever since joining the ERM the peseta has been one of the strongest
currencies, and at the start of May 1991 was at its 6 per cent ceiling
with respect to the weakest currency in the ERM, the French franc. The
continuing strength of the peseta has resulted in the liberalisation of
controls on outward capital flows, but this has not weakened the
currency.
The main reason for the strength of the peseta is the high level of
interest rates in Spain. Three-month interest rates exceeded 15 per cent
from the third quarter of 1989 until the first quarter of this year.
Monetary policy has remained tight in order to exert downward pressure
on domestic demand. This strategy appears to be working as growth of
consumer's expenditure and investment both slowed considerably in
1990. Inflation has averaged 6-7 per cent in the last two years, and
wage settlements remain high. Nonetheless signs that demand is growing
more slowly, combined with the desire to weaken the value of the peseta,
enabled the Bank of Spain to reduce its assistance rate by 1 percentage
point in March.
It is likely that 1991 will be another year of more moderate growth
in Spain. The OECD forecast growth of 2-7 per cent. Domestic demand
growth will continue to be held in check by high interest rates, and it
is likely that interest rates will be reduced further later in the year.
Slower growth of domestic should also prevent further deterioration in
the current account deficit, although slower growth in the rest of the
world will restrain the growth of spanish exports.
Prospects for 1992 are somewhat brighter. There are a number of
special events which will keep Spain in the news and boost Spanish
export earnings. Barcelona will stage the Olympic Games, Sevillea world
fair and Madrid becomes the European City of Culture. We expect GDP
growth in 1992 to be around 4 per cent which is just a little above
estimates of the growth of capacity. However, in the longer term high
interest rates may have to be maintained unless the government budget
deficit is reduced. These events have led to considerable improvements
in Spanish infrastructure which will enable Spain to enhance its growing
significance in the European economy. [Tabular Data Omitted]
PHOTO : Chart 1. 3-month interest rates
PHOTO : Chart 2. Long rates
PHOTO : Chart 3. Capacity utilisation rates
PHOTO : Chart 4. Inflation rates
PHOTO : Chart 5. GNP and world trade growth
PHOTO : Chart 6. Recent commodity prices
PHOTO : Chart 7. Real commodity prices
PHOTO : Chart 8. Recent exchange rates
A third reason for recent exchange-rate volatility is the
uncertainty generated by the Gulf crisis. It is not clear which of the
major seven currencies should have been revalued or devalued as a
consequence of the crisis, and indeed market sentiment may have shifted
as particular risks rose and fell in significance.
The recent strength of the dollar and weakness of the D-Mark could
reflect changing assessments of their long-term prospects in the light
of emerging |news' about the depth of the US recession, and the
length of time that it will take before the eastern Lander are fully
integrated into the German economy. In the latter case it appears that
the competitive gains will emerge more slowly than was first thought,
and that German inflation will stay higher for longer. Both reasons
would justify the recent depreciation of the exchange rate.
Table 3 presents our exchange-rate forecasts. In forecasting
exchange rates we normally adopt the convention that exchange rates
change in line with current market expectations, as given by the
uncovered interest parity condition, which states that the expected
exchange-rate depreciation should be equal to interest-rate
differentials. Econometric studies indicate that this forecasting rule
performs as well as any other, even though the forecasting error often
turns out to be large. This is because foreign exchange markets revise
exchange rates in the light of |news', that is information that is
newly available to the market. Our model also allows us to assess
whether the exchange-rate path is plausible, since the model generates
forecasts of long-term current account flows, which we can compare with
our own assessments of long-term capital account flows. The function of
the exchange rate is to ensure that the two types of flow balance, and
this comparison will sometimes suggest that a given exchange-rate path
is implausible. In the current forecast we would judge that current
exchange rates do not appear to be out of line with a sustainable
exchange-rate path. In 1999 our forecast shows current account deficits
equivalent to 1.2 per cent of GNP in the United States and Italy, and
1.5 per cent of GNP in France, and a surplus of 1.3 per cent of GNP in
Japan, with Germany close to current account balance. [Tabular Data
Omitted]
The United States
US GNP fell for the second successive quarter in the first quarter of
1991, and hence the US economy now fulfils the statisticians'
definition of a recession. The preliminary estimates suggest that GNP
fell by 2.8 per cent at a seasonally adjusted annual rate between the
fourth quarter of 1990 and the first quarter of 1991, following a 1.6
per cent fall between the third and fourth quarters of 1990. Such large
falls after a year of sluggish growth have taken GNP to its lowest level
since the second quarter of 1989.
The recession has been caused by a collapse in domestic demand,
which fell by 4.4 per cent (SAAR) between the third quarter of 1990 and
the first quarter of 1991. The biggest decline has occurred in
stock-building which fell by more than 0.5 per cent of GNP in both the
fourth quarter of 1990 and the first quarter of 1991. Consumer spending fell by 3.4 per cent (SAAR) in the fourth quarter of 1990, and by 1.4
per cent in the first quarter of 1991. Housing investment fell by more
than 20 per cent (SAAR) in both quarters, although in absolute terms this decline contributed less to the decline in GNP than the fall in
consumers' expenditure. Business investment remained flat in the
fourth quarter of 1990, but fell by 14 per cent (SAAR) in the first
quarter of 1991. The decline in domestic demand has contributed to a
decline in imports, but exports have continued to grow, so that net
exports have increased as a proportion of GNP. Net exports have
contributed to GNP growth since 1987, following the major decline in the
dollar between 1985 and 1987.
Even though the US economy entered recession in the final quarter
of last year, inflation continued to rise. The increase in oil prices
following the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait contributed to this, but
underlying consumer price inflation, which excludes energy and food
prices, also continued to rise. Indeed the underlying rate of inflation
reached an 8 year high of 5.7 per cent as recently as February 1991.
Inflationary pressures were increased by the depreciation of the US
dollar in the second half of 1989 and through most of 1990. Between June
1989 and November 1990 the dollar effective exchange rate fell by 17 per
cent, including falls of 25 per cent against the D-Mark and 10 per cent
against the yen. The dollar has however recovered strongly since
November. At the end of April the effective exchange rate had risen by
11 per cent, the exchange rate against the D-Mark by 18 per cent and the
exchange rate against the yen by 7 per cent.
The combination of a recession with rising inflation presented the
US monetary authorities with a policy dilemma. A reduction in interest
rates appeared necessary to support domestic demand growth, but would
also have risked further dollar weakness and hence a possible increase
in inflationary pressure. In 1990 the Federal Reserve Board appeared to
attach greater weight to the inflationary threat. The discount rate was
held at 7 per cent until December, although there was a slight easing of
the federal funds rate from 8.2 per cent in July to 7.8 per cent in
November. Since November the Federal Reserve has acted to counter the
recession, reducing the discount rate to 6.5 per cent in December, 6 per
cent on 1 February, and 5.5 per cent on 30 April. By the beginning of
May the federal funds rate had fallen to 5.75 per cent. This change in
policy was motivated by evidence that the recession was becoming more
severe than had previously been anticipated, but was also enabled by the
strong recovery of the dollar between November and April, which has
reduced the inflationary risk. Nevertheless the level of inflation
remains a concern.
Given the contradictory risks faced by the Federal Reserve, the
timing of interest-rate cuts was always going to be problematic. The
delay in enacting the cuts almost certainly exacerbated the decline in
domestic demand. The sharp fall in the level of domestic demand revealed
in the national accounts for the first quarter of 1991 carries the risk
of further declines invoked by the accelerator - multiplier responses of
investment and inventory accumulation.
The existence of these responses makes it notoriously difficult to
predict the turning-points of a boom or recession accurately. Our
forecast, presented in table 5, suggests, however, that the United
States economy will have started to grow again in the second quarter,
and that recovery in the latter half of the year will compensate for the
effects of the recession at the start of the year, leaving the level of
GNP for 1991 as a whole unchanged from that of 1990. [Tabular Data
Omitted]
Our forecast for 1991 is more optimistic than many United States
forecasters. We think that there are a number of grounds to justify our
relative optimism. The Department of Commerce's leading indicators
index rose by 1.1 per cent in February, the first increase since July.
The Conference Board index of consumer confidence has also risen
dramatically from 54 in January to 81 in March, but fell back slightly
in April. The National Association of Purchasing Managers' index
rose by 41.5 in March from a low of 37.7 in January. However the NAPM interpret values below 44 as evidence of a contracting economy.
There are also some signs of recovery in housing investment. The
level of housing starts fell for the fourth consecutive year in 1990,
and in January 1991 was 45 per cent down from a year previously. However
the level of starts was higher in both February and March, and the level
of building permits was also higher in these two months. The level of
housing investment in the first quarter of 1991 was the lowest recorded
for 8 years, and down 25 per cent from its peak in the fourth quarter of
1986. The recent reductions in interest rates should provide an
additional stimulus for the long-awaited recovery.
Our forecast for business investment is less optimistic. This
category of expenditure continued to grow through 1990, and only
declined in the first quarter of 1991. We therefore expect that it may
have further to decline, especially as the recession has reduced the
level of capacity utilisation in manufacturing, mining and utilities to
78.7 per cent, its lowest level since 1986. Lower interest rates and our
forecast of a recovery in GNP in the second half of this year, should
however reverse the decline in business investment towards the end of
the year.
We expect inflation to decline gradually during the course of the
year. The decline in oil prices following the Gulf war and the
appreciation of the dollar in the first four months of this year,
combined with the depressed level of domestic demand, will all exert
downward pressure on inflation, which is expected to fall below 4 per
cent in the fourth quarter of the year.
One benefit of the recent weakness of economic activity has been an
improvement in the trade and current account deficits. This improvement
has also been aided by the depreciation of the dollar through most of
1990. Even after its marked appreciation since November, the dollar
remained lower at the end of April 1991 than it had been a year
previously. The trade deficit for 1990 of $100 bn was the lowest since
1983, and the current account deficit of $99 bn the lowest since 1984.
Our forecast for US trade and balance of payments is presented in
table 6. We expect that export volumes will grow at 6.4 per cent, and
that import volumes will actually decline. This will enable a further
significant reduction in the current account deficit to below $50 bn,
taking it below 1 per cent of GNP. Chart 9 shows the evolution of the US
current account deficit in the 1980s. The deficit deteriorated rapidly
in 1983 and 1984, as a consequence of the very strong growth in US GNP,
combined with the lagged effects of a real exchange-rate appreciation
since 1980. The deterioration of the current account deficit continued
until 1987, albeit at a less rapid rate. The real exchange rate reached
a peak in 1985, and its subsequent depreciation enabled the current
account deficit to stabilise at the end of 1986, and subsequently to
diminish. This improvement will accelerate as a result of the current US
recession. [Tabular Data Omitted]
We expect that the recovery in GNP should be well under way by
1992, leading to growth of 2.4 per cent for the year as a whole.
Domestic demand is expected to grow by 2.8 per cent, but net exports are
expected to reduce GNP growth by 0.4 per cent. The deterioration in net
exports is due to a combination of higher domestic demand, and a further
appreciation of the exchange rate, in line with the uncovered interest
parity condition. This appreciation should enable the rate of inflation
to be held at 4 per cent, but will also contribute to a renewed
deterioration in the current account. In the longer term we anticipate
that the US economy will grow 2 to 2.5 per cent per annum, with interest
rates increasing from their current crisis levels to around 7 per cent,
but inflation falling below 3 per cent per annum. The current account
deficit as a proportion of GNP is expected to remain constant at around
1.2 per cent.
Japan
The rate of growth of the Japanese economy slowed markedly in the
fourth quarter of 1990. GNP grew at an annualised rate of 2.1 per cent,
compared to the rates of 6.6 per cent, 5.6 per cent and 4.6 per cent
achieved in the first three quarters of the year. Investment
expenditures grew much less rapidly than earlier in the year, and
consumers' expenditure actually fell by 0.3 per cent in the fourth
quarter. This was the first decline in consumer spending since the fall
in the second quarter of 1989, which was caused by the introduction of
the sales tax.
The cause of the current slowdown appears to be the monetary
tightening experienced during 1989 and 1990. The Gensaki rate rose from
4.2 per cent in the first quarter of 1989 to 7.6 per cent in the first
quarter of 1991, its highest level since 1981. This monetary tightening
followed clear signs of overheating that stemmed from growth in excess
of 4.5 per cent in each of 1988, 1989 and 1990.
Even though it now appears to be growing more slowly, the Japanese
economy remains close to capacity output. Business survey evidence
indicates that rates of capacity utilisation in manufacturing continued
to rise in the fourth quarter of 1990. Unemployment remains low, and the
ratio of vacancies to job seekers stood at 1.44 in January 1991, only
marginally down from the 16-year high reached in June 1990.
Labour shortages have led to higher wages and upward pressure on
prices, especially in the service sector. Wage increases in the annual
Spring wage round averaged just under 6 per cent in 1990, with a similar
outturn likely to occur this year. Higher wage costs combined with
higher oil prices caused consumer price inflation to rise to 4.5 per
cent in January 1991. The fall in oil prices since the start of the Gulf
war will provide some relief, but domestic price pressures are likely to
remain strong.
Our forecast(2), presented in table 8, is for Japanese GNP growth
of 3 per cent in 1991. The growth of domestic demand is forecast to be
3.1 per cent, down from 5.7 per cent in 1990, with net exports remaining
at -0.1 per cent of GNP. The main components of slower growth in
domestic demand are consumers' expenditure and business investment,
which will continue to be restrained by the high level of interest
rates. We expect interest rates to remain at current levels until there
is clear evidence that the current high levels of capacity utilisation
and labour market shortages have been reduced. [Tabular Data Omitted]
We expect that continued high interest rates will significantly
reduce the growth rate of business investment, which along with
consumers' expenditure has been the main component of Japanese
growth in the last three years. A survey of investment intentions
conducted by the Japan Development Bank in February indicated that
Japanese firms expected to increase investment by only 4.4 per cent this
year. The reduced growth of investment is due to high interest rates and
an expected decline in demand in both domestic and world markets. The
rate of inflation is forecast to be 3.9 per cent in 1991. The effects of
slower growth in domestic demand will reduce inflationary pressure
during the course of the year, leading to inflation of 2.2 per cent in
1992.
A particular uncertainty in constructing a forecast of Japan is to
predict the course of the exchange rate. Our usual forecasting rule,
which we have again used in this forecast, is to predict future exchange
rates from current exchange rates and interest-rate differentials. This
is consistent with economic theory concerning the determination of
exchange rates by rational, forward-looking, exchange-rate markets. In
the course of the last two and a half years, however, the Japanese
exchange rate has been especially volatile. Between the fourth quarter
of 1988 and the second quarter of 1990 the yen depreciated by 21 per
cent, but has since appreciated by 11 per cent. However in the last six
months the yen has been much more stable, and now appears to be at a
level which will allow a medium-term current account surplus of 1.5 per
cent of GNP, which we judge to be around the level needed to match
long-term capital account outflows.
Our forecast for trade and the balance of payments is shown in
table 9. Export growth was constrained in 1990 by the slow growth in
demand from Japan's export markets. This helped to reduce the
current balance surplus to $36 billion, or 1.2 per cent of Japanese GNP.
Export markets are expected to grow more rapidly in 1991, particularly
in the second half of the year when the US economy is projected to grow
again. Japanese import volumes are forecast to grow more slowly in
response both to slower growth in Japanese domestic demand, and to the
appreciation of the yen since the second quarter of last year. [Tabular
Data Omitted]
We expect that 1991 will be primarily a year of consolidation for
the Japanese economy, in which monetary policy will remain tight. If
current policy proves successful in curbing inflation, there should be
scope for interest-rate reductions later in the year which will provide
a stimulus for domestic demand growth in 1992. The Japanese economy will
also benefit in 1992 from higher economic activity in the rest of the
world. However we judge that the Japanese economy will remain close to
capacity output, and consequently that the authorities will aim to keep
GNP growth below 4 per cent per annum in order to ensure long-term
non-inflationary growth.
Germany
GNP rose by 4.5 per cent in the western Lander in 1990, but declined
dramatically in the eastern Lander. Economic and monetary union between
the two parts of Germany fuelled demand in the western Lander,
particularly as the conversion rate of Ostmarks into D-Mark was
favourable to east German consumers. However much of east German
industry was rendered uncompetitive, through a combination of too high a
conversion rate, workforce demands that monetary union should entail
west German wage rates, and not least by the interior quality of east
German goods.
For the western Lander monetary union and the subsequent
unification of Germany led to the highest rate of economic growth since
1976. Consumers' expenditure rose by 4.2 per cent and business
investment by 10.3 per cent. While extra demand from the east was the
main stimulus, consumers' expenditure also benefited from a DM24
billion cut in income taxes at the start of the year. These factors
enabled strong growth despite interest rates rising from 7 per cent in
1989 to 8.5 per cent in 1990, a marked slowdown in the growth of export
markets and an exchange rate appreciation of 8.1 per cent between 1989
and 1990.
The outlook for 1991 is much less favourable. The collapse of the
eastern economy will reduce demand for western goods and services.
Monetary policy will remain tight and fiscal policy will also tighten as
the German authorities attempt to moderate demand in the western Lander.
In addition recession in the United States combined with slower growth
in western Europe and Japan will reduce external demand.
The German authorities are faced with two distinct problems arising
from unification. The first problem is to prevent the western economy
from overheating. GNP growth has now exceeded 3.5 per cent in each of
the last three years, leading to capacity utilisation rates increasing
from 84.9 per cent in the fourth quarter of 1987 to 90 per cent in the
fourth quarter of 1990. Unemployment has fallen from 2.22 million in
1988 to 1.67 million in February 1991, in spite of the substantial
immigration that occurred in both 1989 and 1990. Inflationary pressures
have also emerged in the labour market. The largest trade union, IG
Metall, obtained a 6 per cent increase in wages in both 1990 and 1991.
Some unions are demanding 10 per cent increases.
The second problem posed by unification is the need to reconstruct the eastern economy. It is estimated that industrial production in the
east has fallen by around 50 per cent. Unemployment in the east had
reached 800,000 in March 1991, with around 1.8 million on short-time
working. Ths rise would have been even higher if substantial numbers of
easterners had not started commuting to jobs in the west. A further
substantial increase in unemployment is expected to occur in July when
guarantees against redundancy in the year after monetary union are due
to expire. New investment in the eastern Lander has not occurred on as
large a scale as had been hoped, and there is a danger that the east
will prove to be a drain on the German economy, as we commented in the
August 1990 issue of the Review. Nevertheless it was always likely that
there would be a big decline in economic activity in the east, since it
was necessary to get rid of the dead wood before reconstruction could
get under way. We expect that increased investment from western firms
faced with labour shortages or high wage costs will lead to recovery in
the east, although the scale of the present disjunction will mean that
it will take some years before the two economies are effectively
integrated.
The German public sector deficit is estimated to have been DM87bn
in 1990. A further deterioration will occur in 1991, caused by higher
spending in the east. Higher spending in the east is in part the
consequence of high unemployment, but it also reflects the regional tax
transfer system that has been established for some time. Income tax
payments by commuters to the west are automatically transferred to
eastern Lander, and 95 per cent of VAT revenue is shared out in
proportion to population. This alone implies a substantial transfer to
the east. We are embedding a small model of the east into our German
section, and the public sector component reflects these transfer rules.
Despite his election promises, Chancellor Kohl has raised indirect
taxes, and imposed a 7.5 per cent surcharge on income and corporate
taxes beginning on 1 July. These two measures are expected to yield
DM36bn. An increase in VAT is scheduled for January 1993.
Monetary policy is likely to remain tight through 1991. German
three-month interest rates remained at around 8.3 per cent in the first
ten months of 1990, as the Bundesbank adopted a wait-and-see response to
unification. However evidence that the budgetary costs of unification
were going to be higher than had been expected has led to further
monetary tightening. The Lombard rate was increased by 0.5 percentage
points on 2 November 1990 and on 1 February, and now stands at 9 per
cent. The discount rate was also raised 0.5 percentage points on 1
February to 6.5 per cent.
The tight monetary policy has kept inflation in check. In March the
annual rate of inflation was 2.5 per cent, compared with 2.7 per cent in
1990. However the planned increases in indirect taxes and the weakening
of the D-Mark since the fourth quarter of 1990 are likely to cause
inflation to pick up again in the second half of the year.
A major effect of German reunification has been the reduction of
the German current account surplus. The compilation of current account
and trade statistics has altered since monetary union in July 1990, so
that the statistics cannot be directly compared with previous figures.
Nevertheless whereas in 1989 west Germany had a current account surplus
of DM104 billion, or 4.6 per cent of GNP, the new Germany was in deficit
in January and February of this year. Between July 1990 and February
1991 the visible trade balance declined from DM9.9bn to DM2.6bn, while
the invisible balance improved from DM - 5.9bn to DM - 4.8bn. The
deterioration of the visibles balance reflects the continued strength of
demand in Germany, and the weakening of demand in its major trading
partners.
Our forecast for Germany is shown in table 10. Our forecast for GNP
is for the western Lander only, since national accounts are not yet
available on an all-German basis. Western Lander GDP will grow by around
3 per cent, but GNP will grow by only 2.4 per cent. The difference
arises because of the increase in factor payments to the eastern Lander,
as a result of an increase in the number of residents in the eastern
Lander who earn their income by working in the western Lander. We expect
the growth of domestic demand in the western Lander to fall from 4.9 per
cent in 1990 to 3.9 per cent in 1991. Consumers' expenditure is
expected to grow by 2.8 per cent compared with 4.2 per cent last year.
Slower growth here is caused by a combination of tax increases in 1991
compared with tax cuts in 1990, higher interest rates and a decline in
spending by east Germans. Business investment is also expected to grow
less rapidly due to high interest rates, and as a result of lower growth
in economic activity, both within Germany and abroad. We expect that
housing investment will continue to grow strongly, in spite of high
interest rates, as immigration into western Germany has generated severe
housing shortages. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Even though the rate of growth is expected to fall, the west German
economy remains close to capacity output and we expect that inflation
will rise later in the year. For the year as a whole inflation is
forecast to be 3.3 per cent. Towards the end of the year we expect that
demand from eastern Germany and from the rest of the world will begin to
pick up. This will generate extra inflationary pressures on Germany. The
Bundesbank is expected to maintain a tight monetary policy and may need
to raise interest-rates further. However we expect that rates will
remain unchanged, as we judge that policy is already sufficiently tight.
Nevertheless inflation may rise further in 1992 as recovery in the east
gets under way.
Our forecast for German trade and balance of payments is shown in
table 11. We expect some improvement in the current account balance
during the year as the rate of growth moderates in Germany, while demand
from the United States and the United Kingdom begins to pick up. For the
years as a whole [Tabular Data Omitted]
PHOTO : Chart 9. US current account we are forecasting a current
account surplus of $6bn, or 0.4 per cent of German GNP. Small surpluses
are expected to continue throughout the decade. This is in contrast with
the large west German surpluses prior to monetary union, and reflects
the fact that west German savings will be primarily directed to
reconstruction in the east.
Table 12 shows our forecast for the German public sector deficit.
The deficit is expected to increase from DM87bn to DM171bn in 1991. This
deterioration partly reflects the fact that 1991 will be the first
complete year of German unification, and partly our expectation that
conditions in the east are likely to deteriorate further during the
course of 1991. In the first instance the deterioration of the deficit
will be curbed by the tax increases that have already been announced. In
the longer term recovery in the eastern economy will lead to a gradual
but continuing reduction in the budget deficit. [Tabular Data Omitted]
France
In the fourth quarter of 1990, real GDP fell by 0.4 per cent, for the
first time since early 1987. For the year as a whole, real GDP grew by
2.8 per cent, compared with 4 per cent in 1989. The fall in the fourth
quarter was associated with declines in industrial output, which fell by
2.3 per cent, and total investment, which fell by 0.8 per cent - the
first decrease for four years. Almost all sectors showed declines in
output, but the sharpest drop was found in car production. For the first
quarter of 1991 no significant improvement is expected. Business
investment fell sharply by 2.7 per cent.
Import volumes fell by 0.5 per cent, due to lower domestic demand
and a fall in energy imports, but export volumes grew by 2.5 per cent.
Industrial production grew by 1.1 per cent in 1990, the lowest growth
for four years, compared with 3.6 per cent in 1989. The signs for the
first quarter of 1991 indicate that no recovery can be expected.
Industrial production in the three months to February fell by 1.2 per
cent, compared with a 1.4 per cent drop in the previous three months.
New company registrations were unchanged in March but had dropped to a
six year low in February. Total starts in 1990 were 2 per cent lower
than in 1989, with the sharpest drop in industry and trade. The INSEE survey showed that business confidence remains very weak, stocks have
built up again, and order books remain poor.
Unemployment started to rise in September and the sharpest rise was
in February when the number of unemployed rose by 45,000. The increase
in March was 15,900, bringing the total number of unemployed to 2.6
million. The rate of unemployment rose to 9.3 per cent. In 1990 the rate
of unemployment was 9.0 per cent on average, down from 9.4 per cent in
1989 and 10 per cent in 1988. The rise in unemployment is expected to
continue as less jobs are created due to slower economic growth both at
home and abroad, and despite government efforts to boost job creation
through reducing labour costs.
The annual inflation rate continues to fall. For 1990, inflation,
excluding energy, reached its lowest point since 1966 and although the
rate of inflation edged up slightly in the beginning of this year, the
overall inflation rate has continued its decline in recent months. We
expect the annual inflation rate for 1991 to fall below the German rate.
This reflects both the success of the French efforts to tame inflation
through its commitment to a strong currency in the ERM, and the increase
in the rate of inflation in Germany.
The trade deficit widened to FF49.8 billion in 1990, compared with
FF44.7 bn in 1989 and was the worst trade balance since 1982. The
current account showed a FF31.1 bn deficit last year, compared with a
FF25.0 bn deficit in 1989. The worsening of the current account can be
attributed to the widening trade deficit and a decline in the invisibles
surplus, with a marked deterioration in the balance of investment
income, caused by the appreciation of the franc.
Our forecast for the French economy is set out in tables 13 and 14.
In our last forecast we expected real GDP to grow by 1.6 per cent in
1991. Our latest forecast is only slightly lower at 1.5 per cent,
compared with 2.8 per cent in 1990. Although domestic conditions have
deteriorated the recent improvement in competitiveness will in part
offset this decline in the projected rate of growth of domestic demand.
Domestic demand is projected to grow by 2.2 per cent, compared with 2.9
per cent in 1990. Rising unemployment and lower wage growth means lower
disposable income growth and as a result consumption is expected to grow
by only 2.0 per cent. Private investment is forecast to grow by 2.9 per
cent, 1 per cent lower than 1990 and 3 points lower than 1989. [Tabular
Data Omitted]
We expect exports to grow by 3.3 per cent, much less than in
previous years. This is mainly due to the slowdown in foreign markets.
The effective exchange rate rose almost 8 per cent in 1990 due to the
decline of the dollar. This has made French exports more expensive and
French industry has lost competitiveness vis-a-vis its major
competitors. The recent recovery of the dollar and the decline of the
franc means that the French economy has regained some of its lost
competitiveness and we expect a drop in relative export prices almost
offsetting last year's rise. Imports are expected to grow by 4.9
per cent and this, combined with the expected worsening of invisibles,
leads to a projected current account deficit of 1.1 per cent of GDP.
Italy
The Italian economy is growing at a much slower pace than in previous
years. Real GDP grew by 0.7 per cent in the third quarter of 1990,
compared with a 0.6 per cent fall in the second quarter. For 1990, real
GDP is expected to have grown by 2 per cent, compared with 3.2 per cent
in 1989 and 4.1 per cent in 1988. The first indications of an economic
slowdown were seen in 1989 and the economic situation worsened in 1990
with a sharper slowdown in consumption, investment growth and net
exports. Consumers' expenditure grew modestly by 2.8 per cent, with
a marked slowdown in expenditure on consumer durables. New car
deliveries fell by 10 per cent, compared with an increase of 8.1 per
cent in 1989. There was a sharp decline in private investment growth to
2.1 per cent, compared with 5.1 per cent in 1989.
Inflation accelerated again and rose to 6.3 per cent in 1990. The
inflation differential vis-a-vis Germany has risen from 2.8 points to
3.7 points, while the differential with France has increased from 2.7 to
3.3 points. The indications for the first months of 1991 are not much
better, with inflation rising to 6.6 per cent in March. Inflation
increased as a result of higher energy prices, although the acceleration
is mainly due to domestic factors. Hourly earnings rose by 7.3 per cent
in 1990. Despite an improvement in hourly labour productivity over the
last years, unit labour costs have risen substantially as the growth in
hourly wage costs has exceeded growth in productivity. This has further
eroded the profitability of Italian firms, which have been limited in
their ability to pass the rise in unit labour costs on to prices. There
are indications of further wage increases, with the sharpest increases
in sectors that are protected from international competition, like
earnings per employee in the public sector that grew by 14 per cent last
year. With these wage increases there is no prospect of the unemployment
rate coming down significantly from the 11 per cent recorded in 1990.
The lira appreciated substantially against the dollar and yen in
1990 and this, combined with the increased inflation differential
vis-a-vis its major European partners, led to a fall in Italy's
competitiveness. The volume of exports grew by 5.6 per cent in 1990,
while imports grew by 6 per cent.
The trade deficit fell to 14 billion lire, compared with 17 billion
in 1989, due to the improvement in the terms of trade. The current
account deficit is expected to have widened in 1990 to around 2 per cent
of GDP. This reflects the worsening of the deficit on invisibles due to
a marked decline in the surplus on services. In the second half of the
1980s the surplus on tourism has declined steadily, due to the loss of
competitiveness and the growth in Italian expenditure on foreign travel
that has accompanied the removal of foreign exchange restrictions.
Our forecast for the Italian economy, presented in table 15,
indicates a further deterioration in the economic situation compared
with 1990. Real GDP is projected to rise by only 1.1 per cent. We expect
consumption growth to slow down further to 2.1 per cent, due to the
acceleration of inflation that reduces real earnings growth. Inflation
is expected to rise further given the wage increases, and we see little
prospect of a rapid convergence of Italian inflation to that of its
major European partners. With fiscal policy directed towards bringing
the ratio of public debt to GDP under control, there is not much scope
for a counter-cyclical policy. As monetary policy is committed to a
stable exchange rate, interest rates are expected to remain high and we
see no recovery of investment growth in 1991. In our forecast, exports
suffer from the loss of competitiveness and the slowdown in Italy's
export markets. Exports to Germany account for 19 per cent of total
exports and given the slowdown in Germany, exports are not expected to
grow at the same rate as over the previous years. We expect the deficit
on invisibles to widen further. The current account deficit may fall to
1.1 per cent of GDP as the terms of trade improve. [Tabular Data
Omitted]
The long-term outlook for the Italian economy remains hampered by
the relatively high wage inflation, which hinders any prospect of a
decline in the inflation differential vis-a-vis its European partners,
and by the high public sector deficits and rising public debt to the GDP
ratio. This may make it difficult to maintain the value of the Lira
within the exchange-rate mechanism. In our forecast the Lira is devalued
within the ERM in the mid 1990s.
Canada
The Canadian economy is in severe recession. Real GDP fell in each of
the last three quarters of 1990. For the year as a whole, real GDP rose
by 0.9 per cent but in the fourth quarter it was 16 per cent below its
peak level in the first quarter of 1990. However, this is less severe
than the 2.8 per cent decline experienced in the last three quarters of
the 1981/2 recession. Consumers' expenditure grew by 1.3 per cent
in 1990, but total domestic demand did not grow as private investment
fell sharply, due to high interest rates. This slowdown in the US has
contributed to a deterioration in the contribution of net exports.
The signs for the first quarter of 1991 are not encouraging.
Industrial production in January was almost 5 per cent below its level
of a year before, and housing starts have continued to decline in the
first three months of this year. Unemployment has risen by 161,000 in
the first quarter of 1991, bringing the total number of unemployed in
March to 1.44 million. The unemployment rate has risen sharply over the
last year to 10.5 per cent in March, compared with 9.3 per cent in
December and 7.2 per cent in March 1990. There is however some evidence
that the first quarter of 1991 may be the bottom of the recession.
Consumer confidence, as measured by the Conference Board of Canada,
increased slightly at the end of 1990, and the decline in petrol prices
will benefit the energy intensive Canadian economy.
These indications of a severe recession have led the monetary
authorities to ease monetary conditions further and lower interest
rates. Inflation rose sharply to over 6 per cent in January and
February, due to the replacement of the Manufacturers Sales Tax by a
Goods and Services Tax (GST). This more broadly based value added tax has added approximately 1.25 percentage points to the inflation rate and
will further reduce growth of real personal disposable income.
Our forecast for Canada is set out in table 16. Real GDP is
expected to decline by 1.6 per cent. We expect consumers'
expenditure to drop by 0.4 per cent this year, due to higher
unemployment and the adverse effect of higher inflation on real personal
disposable income. Domestic demand is expected to fall by 0.8 per cent,
as private investment is also forecast to fall. We expect a further
negative external contribution, as export volumes are projected to fall
slightly due to the slowdown in the United States. The current account
deficit is expected to remain unchanged, around 2.4 per cent of GDP.
[Tabular Data Omitted]
NOTES
(1) The latest version of GEM includes new equations for business
investment in which we find
long-run effects from
long-term interest rates. These equations are discussed in Annex
2 to this chapter. Some
standard simulations using the
new version of GEM are reported in Barrell and Gurney (1991b).
(2) Detailed forecast tables are available from the National Institute.
These include rebased
Japanese national accounts data.
REFERENCES
Barrell, R. and Gurney, A. (1991a), |Fiscal and monetary policy
simulations with forward-looking
exchanges using the National
Institute Global Econometric Model (GEM)', National Institute
discussion paper no. 200. Barrell, R. and Gurney, A. (1991b), |Standard
simulations', Paper prepared for SPES macromodelling
conference, Paris, June
1991.
ANNEX 1 EXCHANGE-RATE VOLATILITY 1987-1991
The appreciation of the US dollar in the last six months has given
the issue of exchange-rate volatility renewed topical interest. This is
an issue which has been debated over many years. A recent summary of the
debate can be found in Krugman (1989). In this note we review the
volatility of exchange rates for the major seven economies in the period
since January 1987. This date has been chosen for two reasons. Firstly
it covers the period since the last major international agreement on
exchange rates, the |Louvre accord' of February 1987. Secondly it
also covers the period since the last major realignment in the european
exchange-rate mechanism, which occurred in January 1987. The analysis
uses monthly averages of exchange rates. The measure of volatility over
a sample period is taken as CV = 100xSD/Mean
where CV = Coefficient of Variation
Mean = Mean value of exchange rate over the sample period
SD = Standard deviation of the exchange rate over the sample
period
Alternative methods for analysing exchange-rate volatility can be
found in Wadhwani (1987) and Artis and Taylor (1988). Haldane (1991)
provides a survey of literature on the EMS, including the effects of the
exchange-rate mechanism on volatility. Table 1 shows mean exchange rates
over the whole sample period, and table 2 the coefficients of variation.
The most general measure of each country's exchange rate is its
effective exchange-rate index. Table 2 shows that the most volatile G7
currency, measured in terms of the coefficient of variation of its
effective exchange rate between January 1987 and March 1991, has been
the Japanese yen, followed by the US and Canadian dollars. The least
volatile G7 currency has been the Italian lira, followed by the French
franc and the German mark. Table 2 also shows the effect of the European
exchange-rate mechanism in securing this low currency volatility for
Germany, France and Italy. Taking individual cross exchange rates
against the US dollar, the German mark and Japanese yen appear the most
volatile currencies, and the Canadian dollar the least volatile, while
in terms of exchange rates against the mark, the yen is the most
volatile and the franc the least volatile. More importantly the
coefficient of variation for the franc and the lira against the D-Mark
are 0.8 per cent and 1.5 per cent respectively, whereas the lowest
coefficient of variation for a currency measured against the US dollar
is 5.3 per cent for the Canadian dollar, and for a currency measured
against the yen is 5.6 per cent for the lira. [Tabular Data Omitted]
Tables 3 and 4 show the mean value and coefficient of variation for
each country's effective exchange rate over overlapping
sub-samples, each spanning 12 monthly observations. In table 3 it is
clear that movements in exchange rates have not been systematic, in the
sense that none of the exchange rates has been consistent appreciating
or depreciating since 1987. Table 4 shows that there have been periods
of greater and lesser exchange-rate volatility. In most periods either
the yen or the US dollar has a coefficient of variation in excess of 3.5
per cent, but in the two periods January-December 1988 and July
1988-June 1989 all seven currencies had coefficients of variation less
than 3.5 per cent, representing periods of less exchange-rate
volatility. In contrast July 1989-June 1990 and April 1990-March 1991
were periods of greater exchange-rate volatility, in which the
coefficient of variation of the yen effective exchange rate exceeded 5.0
per cent. [Tabular Data Omitted]
The use of effective exchange-rate indices inevitably masks the
volatility in individual cross exchange rates. These are illustrated in
tables 5-7. A summary of the results is also shown in table 8, which
divides the results from tables 5-7 into four categories. The division
of the categories is arbitrary, but useful as a way of visualising the
results. Some interesting observations can be made. Firstly with the
exception of the Canadian dollar, volatility against the US dollar
generally falls in the medium-high or high categories. Again with the
exception of the Canadian dollar, currencies have tended to be less
volatile against the yen than against the US dollar, with the UK pound
showing greater stability against the yen than against the D-Mark. This
result is unlikely to persist now that sterling has joined the european
exchange-rate mechanism. The success of the exchange-rate mechanism in
limiting exchange-rate volatility between the French franc, Italian Lira
and the German mark is also apparent in table 8. The pound has been
noticeably more stable against the mark than against the dollar.
[Tabular Data Omitted]
Our analysis of exchange-rate volatility since 1987 has revealed
that the exchange-rates of the US dollar and the Japanese yen have
tended to be the most volatile in this period, both because they are the
most heavily traded currencies and because they have been outside any
formal exchange-rate arrangement. While Canada is not formally part of
an exchange-rate agreement, its economy is highly integrated with that
of the United States, and hence the value of the Canadian dollar has
been relatively stable against the US dollar.
In the last four years the most difficult country to categorise has
been the United Kingdom, since the pound has tended to be more stable
against the yen than against the mark, despite the greater level of
integration of the UK economy with that of continental Europe. The
French and Italian results indicate that the ERM has been effective in
limiting the volatility of European cross exchange rates. Now that the
pound has joined the ERM the major currencies of the world can be more
readily divided into three distinct blocks. This study finds no evidence
to suppose that exchange-rate volatility is diminishing. This reflects
continuing divergences in both the economic structure and the stance of
economic policy between the three main currency blocks.
REFERENCES
Artis, M. and Taylor, M. (1988), |Exchange rates, interest rates,
capital controls and the European
monetary system', in
Giavazzi et al (eds), The European Monetary System, Cambridge
University Press. Haldane, A. (1991), |The exchange-rate mechanism of
the European monetary system: a review of the
literature', Bank of
England Quarterly Bulletin, vol. 31, no. 1. Krugman, P., (1989),
|The case for stabilising exchange rates', Oxford Review of
Economic Policy,
vol. 5, no. 3. Wadhwani, S. (1987), |Are exchange rates
|excessively' volatile?', Journal of International
Economics, vol. 22, no. 314.
ANNEX 2. THE EFFECTS OF CHANGES IN LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES
ON BUSINESS INVESTMENT
In the last year we have included long-term interest rates in our
econometric model GEM. These are modelled as a geometric average of
future short-term interest rates in forward-looking simulations of the
model, and hence provide an additional channel in which expectations of
future interest rates can affect current economic behaviour. One of the
ways in which we expect such expectations to influence current behaviour
is through changes in investment decisions. We have therefore
re-estimated our business investment equations to allow for changes in
response to variation in long-run interest rates.
On GEM total investment is disaggregated into business investment,
housing investment and government investment for all 7 major economies
with the exception of Italy. We have chosen to model total Italian
investment in the same way as we model business investment for the other
major 7 economies. We assume that the main determinants of investment
are the level of economic activity, as measured by either GDP or GNP,
and interest rates. In equilibrium we would expect that business
investment would be a constant proportion of total GNP. This requires a
long-run unit elasticity with respect to GNP. Our econometric
methodology was to test down from a general model which allowed
short-run effects from lagged changes in business investment and current
and lagged changes in GNP and interest rates, and long-run effects from
the levels of GNP and long-term interest rates. Our aim was to estimate
an equation over the period 1970Q1-1990Q2, but in some cases we were
unable to obtain a satisfactory econometric representation, and we have
accordingly reduced the period of estimation.
In all cases except Japan we have found equations that are
statistically well-specified. The Japanese equation marginally fails the
test for normality of residuals at 5 per cent significance levels. Tests
for parameter instability are all insignificant at 5 per cent
significance levels. The restriction of a long-run unit elasticity is
statistically acceptable in all cases except the United Kingdom. We have
nonetheless retained the unit elasticity restriction in our equation for
the United Kingdom in order to ensure sensible forecasting and
simulation properties when used in GEM.
The equations for the United States and Canada include a dummy
variable C79, which takes the value zero up to 1978Q4 and 1 from 1979Q1
onwards, indicating a possible step increase in the equilibrium business
investment to GNP ratio from 1979 on. The Japanese equation includes a
dummy variable that takes the value 1 in 1974Q1 to account for an
outlier. The United Kingdom equation includes a dummy variable with
values 1 in 1985Q1 and - 1 in 1985Q2, which accounts for the switch in
business investment between those two quarters as a result of a charge
in company taxation.
The dynamic responses of business investment to changes in the
level of economic activity and the long-term rate of interest are
summarised in Tables D1 and D2. Table D1 shows business investment in
the US, Germany and France responds rapidly to changes in the level of
activity, with an elasticity exceeding 0.9 achieved within a year. Italy
and Canada reach an elasticity of 0.9 after about 3 years, the United
Kingdom after 6 years and Japan after 7 years. The slow speed of
response in these last two countries appears rather odd, and may
indicate that the equations are missing important explanatory variables,
even though they are statistically well-specified. [Tabular Data
Omitted]
Table D2 reveals a considerable range of both speed and magnitude
of response to changes in 10 year interest rates. [Tabular Data Omitted]
The short-run semi-elasticity ranges from -0.001 in Italy to -0.013
in Germany, and the long-run semi-elasticity ranges from -0.007 in the
United States to -0.184 in Japan. However the mean lag in the United
States is much lower than in the other countries while the mean lag in
Japan is the highest. In Italy and Canada also a relatively low long-run
semi-elasticity is combined with a relatively low mean lag.
In simulations of GEM, long term interest rates are modelled as a
geometric average of expected future short-term interest rates. This
means that the relationship between short-term and long-term interest
rates will vary according to how long the short-term interest rate is
expected to remain at a given level. Table D3 shows that a 1 percentage
point increase in short-term interest rates will only result in a 1
percentage point increase in long-term interest rates if it is expected
to persist for 10 years or more. If the increase is expected to persist
for 5 years, then long-term interest rates will initially rise by 0.5
percentage points, and then decline by 0.025 percentage points per
quarter. An increase that is expected to last for 1 year only will cause
long-term interest rates to rise by only 0.1 percentage points. [Tabular
Data Omitted]
Table D4 shows the effects of this differential response on the
simulation properties of the model. Two simulations have been run for
each country. In both simulations short-term interest rates are raised
by 1 percentage point. In simulation A the increase is expected to
persist for 1 year and in simulation B for 5 years, so that long-term
interest rates respond differently in the two simulations. In each
country business investment falls by more in simulation B, but the
effect ranges from an additional fall of 0.08 percentage points in Italy
to 0.61 percentage points in Germany. This range reflects primarily the
short-run semi-elasticities shown in Table D2. The effect on GNP depends
on the proportion of business investment in GNP. GNP declines by an
additional 0.08 percentage points in Japan and 0.07 percentage points in
Germany but by less than 0.02 percentage points in Italy, the United
States and France. In all countries the differences in inflation between
the two simulations is negligible. [Tabular Data Omitted]