The world economy.
Gurney, Andrew ; Barrell, Ray
In the course of the last 2 years economic performance in the major
7 economies has become less synchronised. in 1988 GNP grew by more than
3.5 per cent in all seven economies, with growth rates either at or
close to cyclical highs. However for 1991 we expect negative GNP growth
for Canada and the United Kingdom, negligible growth in the United
States, growth of around 1.5 per cent in France and Italy, and of over 3
per cent in Germany and Japan. Table 1 shows that GNP growth in the
major 7 economies is expected to slow to 1.2 per cent in 1991. Chart 1
highlights the different responses among the major 4 economies.
These different responses can be in part related to the policies
pursued within each economy. Box A indicates that both the United
Kingdom and Canada experienced severe monetary tightening between 1988
and 1989, which contributed to their respective recessions. Germany also
experienced a tight monetary policy, but the effects of this were
countered by the large fiscal stimulus arising from increased transfers
to the east following German Monetary union in 1990. France, Italy and
Japan have experienced less severe monetary tightening, accompanied by a
mildly expansionary fiscal stance in France, and by a contractionary
fiscal stance in Italy and Japan. Japanese fiscal policy was however
expansionary in 1990. It is more difficult to relate the recent
performance of the US economy to policy developments. Monetary policy
has been progressively relaxed since the second half of 1989, and the
fiscal stance has changed little. The US recession therefore appears to
have been either a result of private sector behaviour or a delayed
response to the tightening of policy in 1988. Chart 1 shows that the
decline in US GNP growth has occurred progressively since the second
half of 1988, although recession did not occur until the second half of
1990. The slowdown has been associated with slower growth of
consumers' expenditure, and declines in the level of housing
investment, as consumer confidence has been eroded by failing real
estate values and fears of a credit crunch.
Table 1 summarises our forecast. GNP growth in the major 7
economies is expected to decline from 2.4 per cent in 1990 to 1.2 per
cent in 1991, before rising to 2.9 per cent in 1992. All major 7
economies are expected to grow more slowly in 1991 than in 1990,
although for Japan and Germany this means GNP growth of 4 per cent and
3.1 per cent respectively, whilst the United States will have zero
growth, and Canada and the United Kingdom negative growth. Japan and
Germany are expected to again grow more slowly in 1992, while
growth-rates in the other major economies are expected to increase.
Our forecasts represent an unwinding of recent cyclical
developments, and their associated policy responses. Charts 2 and 3 show
recent developments in interest rates in the major 4 economies. The most
striking feature in chart 2 is the sharp decline in United States
interest rates, especially since last November, as the monetary
authorities have attempted to stimulate a recovery from recession. As
yet it is unclear whether this attempt has been successful, and although
the preliminary estimate of second quarter GNP showed a small increase,
it is not clear that this was led by lower interest rates. Leading
indicator and survey evidence suggest that a weak recovery may be
underway. Our forecast suggests that the recovery will strengthen in the
second half of the year in response to the monetary easing that has
already occurred, leaving GNP for the year as a whole unchanged from
1990.
Chart 1 indicates that GNP growth in Japan in the year to 1991Q1
was actually higher than in the two previous quarters. Nevertheless
there are signs that domestic demand growth has slowed in response to
tighter monetary policy, and this prompted the monetary authorities to
reduce interest rates at the beginning of July. The Tokyo stockmarket
remains extremely volatile, and there is a risk that financial scandals
will affect consumer and investor confidence. The yen appreciated 14 per
cent between the second quarters of 1990 and 1991, and this will reduce
the contribution of net exports to GNP growth in the latter half of
1991, and in 1992.
There are signs that the German economy may also be growing more
slowly. Monetary policy remains very tight, and fiscal policy was
tightened through a tax package introduced in July. The tax increases
affected consumer price inflation, which rose to 4.5 per cent in July,
leading to speculation that monetary policy may be tightened further.
However survey evidence and July unemployment figures suggest that the
economy is already beginning to slow, and year on year growth rates will
fall sharply in the third quarter, when comparisons will no longer
straddle German monetary union in July 1990. GNP growth for the year is
therefore likely to be around 3 per cent, with a further decline
expected in 1992 in response to fiscal tightening and continued tight
monetary policy.
France and Italy have benefited from higher demand in Germany, but
have lost competitiveness against non-ERM countries as their currencies
appreciated with the D-Mark in 1990 (see chart 8 and table 3).
Interest-rate differentials with Germany have narrowed in the past two
years so that the monetary squeeze has been less severe than in Germany.
However without the direct benefit of the German demand stimulus, growth
rates have declined. Some recovery is expected in 1992, in part in
response to lower interest rates, in part to recovery in the world, and
also to a more competitive exchange rate following depreciation this
year.
Chart 4 shows recent developments in inflation rates. Inflation in
the major 7 countries is expected to fall from 4-4 per cent in 1990 to
4.3 per cent in 1991. However inflation is only expected to fall in the
United States, Italy and the United Kingdom. Higher inflation in Japan
and Germany arises out of strong pressure of demand, and in Canada from
the introduction of the Goods and Services Tax at the start of the year.
Chart 5 shows capacity utilisation rates in the major 4 economies.
Capacity utilisation remains above 1985-1987 levels in all four
economies except the United States, although it declined in all 4
economies in the first quarter of 1991. it is now much clearer that all
these countries have passed their cyclical peaks. Unemployment remains
low in Germany and Japan, but has risen in both France and the United
States, reducing inflationary pressure emanating from labour markets.
The decline in major 7 GNP growth has led to a decline in world
trade growth, table 1. World trade in manufactures is expected to grow
by 3.3 per cent in 1991, the lowest growth rate since 1986, and total
world trade by 2.6 per cent, the lowest since 1983. OECD industrial
production is expected to grow by 0.4 per cent, the lowest growth rate
since 1982. OECD industrial production and world trade growth will both
recover next year in line with recovery in G7 GNP.
Chart 6 shows recent developments in commodity prices. The price of
metals and minerals has fallen by 20 per cent since the third quarter of
last year, with the prices of zinc, lead and aluminum falling by over 25
per cent. Metals prices have been more stable since the first quarter of
1991, with a rise in the price of silver of almost 20 per cent, but
falls of over 1 0 per cent in the price of both aluminum and zinc. Chart
7 shows that while real metals prices have fallen by 30 per cent since
their peak in 1989, they remain 15 per cent higher than in 1986. Metals
prices are expected to remain weak in 1991 as mining and production
capacity have expanded following the large increase in prices between
1987 and 1989, while slower growth in OECD industrial production has
weakened demand.
The price of wheat rose 20 per cent between September 1990 and
April 1991, but has since returned to last September's levels. This
development accounts for a rise in developed country food prices in the
first half of the year. Less developed country food prices have fallen
by 10 per cent in the last year with cocoa prices 28 per cent lower than
in 1990OQ2, coffee prices 15 per cent lower, and sugar prices 20 per
cent lower. Sugar production has been reduced following price falls of
30 per cent in 1990, and this is expected to lead to higher sugar prices
in the second half of the year.
Our exchange-rate forecasts are contained in table 3. We continue
to assume that exchange rates will in future change in line with
interest-rate differentials so that the uncovered arbitrage condition
continues to hold. We do not presume that we have more information than
the market, and hence we are not currently predicting a major
realignment of exchange rates. Although there is some evidence (for
instance in Barrell and in't Veld in this Review) that the dollar
is overvalued, we do not expect this to be rapidly corrected as US
interest rates are below those elsewhere. However, rising US interest
rates and higher US inflation will cause the US to depreciate in real
terms in the mid-1990s. The yen also appears to us to be misaligned, but
its recent undervaluation is expected to be removed only very slowly. We
are predicting at least one re-alignment of EMS parities before the
forecast move to Monetary Union in 1997. The D-Mark-franc rate, however,
changes very little in our forecast, and the realignment is designed to
accommodate the effects of the current italian overvaluation and the
forecast level of excess inflation in that country. However, we are
predicting that convergence will proceed sufficiently for union to be
supportable.
United States
US GNP is estimated to have risen by 0.1 per cent in the second
quarter of 1991. Whilst the US economy ceased to be in recession, the
level of GNP remained 1 per cent lower than in the third quarter of
1990. Domestic demand grew by .7 per cent in the second quarter of
1991, as a result of increases of .9 per cent in consumer spending, .5
per cent in Government expenditure and a lower level of de-stocking.
However investment expenditure fell 0.2 per cent, and a deterioration in
net exports meant that GNP rose by 0.1 per cent.
The modest recovery in GNP is consistent with the evidence provided
by cyclical indicators. The Department of Commerce's leading
indicators index has been increasing since February, while the
co-incident index stopped falling in April and registered small
increases in May and June. The National Association of Purchasing
Managers index has also been increasing since February, and registered
51.8 in July. However the Conference Board index of consumer confidence,
which rose from 54 in January to 81 in March, declined to 77.7 in July.
The US recession between the third quarter of 1990 and the first
quarter of 1991 was caused by a fall of 2.4 per cent in domestic demand.
Consumer spending fell by 1.2 percent, investment expenditure by 6.3 per
cent and there was a reduction in inventories equivalent to 1 .2 per
cent of domestic demand. The weakness of domestic demand can be
attributed to the tight monetary stance maintained in 1989 and 1990. The
US Federal funds interest rate rose from 6.6 per cent in March 1988 to
9.9 per cent in March 1989, and remained above 8 per cent until November
1990. Since then there has been a substantial easing of monetary policy,
with the Federal funds rate falling to 5.5 per cent in early August.
Lower interest rates should stimulate the economy into stronger growth
in the second half of the year.
The reason that the US monetary authorities maintained a tight
monetary stance through most of 1990 was their concern about inflation.
The consumers' expenditure deflator increase of 5 per cent in 1990
was the highest inflation rate since 1982. Underlying inflationary
pressures were exacerbated by the increase in oil prices in the second
half of the year.
The subsequent reversal of the oil price increase has contributed
to a reduction of inflation in the first half of this year. By the
second quarter of the year CED inflation had fallen to 4.5 per cent.
Further declines in inflation are likely in the second half of the year,
as producer price inflation has moderated from 3.6 per cent in 1990 to
1.7 per cent in April and May. Inflationary pressures should also ease
as a result of the rise in unemployment, which reached 8.7 million in
June 1991, an increase of 2.2 million compared to a year previously. The
rate of capacity utilisation in manufacturing fell to 77.1 per cent in
April, down from 84.6 per cent in the first half of 1989.
Our forecast is presented in table 5. We expect that domestic
demand will grow by 1.6 per cent in the second half of the year, with
consumers' expenditure growing by 1.4 per cent and a slower rate of
destocking. This recovery in the second half of the year will not
compensate for the fall in the first half of the year, so that domestic
demand for the year as a whole is expected to decline by .6 per cent.
However net exports should improve relative to their level in 1990, as
weak domestic demand suppresses the growth of imports whilst relatively
buoyant demand in the rest of the world maintains the growth of exports.
This improvement in external demand will leave GNP little changed for
the year as a whole, with growth in the second half of the year
nullifying the effects of the earlier recession.
Inflation is expected to continue to fall in the second half of the
year, leading to an inflation rate of 4.3 per cent for the year as a
whole. As recovery gets underway it will prove more difficult to reduce
inflation further. Our forecast assumes that the US monetary authorities
will raise interest rates to 6.0 per cent towards the end of the year in
order to slow the speed of recovery and keep inflation under control.
This assumption is consistent with money market rates at the start of
August.
In 1992 GNP is expected to grow by 2.8 per cent, with domestic
demand growth of 3.2 per cent. Consumers' expenditure is expected
to grow by 2 per cent, with domestic demand growth boosted by investment
expenditure growth of 7 per cent, and by a return to positive
stockbuilding. Net exports are expected to deteriorate as higher
domestic demand leads to a resurgence of imports. Renewed growth in
demand will eliminate deflationary pressures, so that the rate of
inflation is likely to remain at around 4 per cent. Against this
background it is likely that there will be further upward pressure on US
interest rates, and we envisage a rise to 7 per cent by the end of the
year.
Table 6 shows our forecast for US trade and the balance of
payments. The US current account balance was in surplus in the first
quarter of the year for the first time since 1982. This surplus was due
to transfers from abroad of around $20 billion to help pay for the war
with Iraq. (These unrequitted transfers affect the current account but
not the level of measured Gross National Product.) Nevertheless there
has also been an underlying improvement in the current account balance
as imports have declined as a consequence of the US recession, while
exports have continued to grow. In January-May the visible trade deficit
was $26 billion compared to $42 billion in January-May 1990. For the
year as a whole we expect a visible trade deficit of $63 billion and a
current account deficit of $20 billion. Renewed growth of the US economy
in the second half of this year and in 1992 will result in renewed
growth in imports, which will cause the visible trade deficit to
deteriorate slightly in 1992. The current account deficit will no longer
benefit from Gulf War transfers and consequently will deteriorate more
markedly to $65 billion or 1 1 per cent of GNP. This remains a
significant improvement from the deficit of 3.6 per cent of GNP recorded
in 1987. The correction has come in part from a depreciation of the US
dollar over the last four years, and also because the economy is no
longer operating above capacity. This reduction in demand has been
associated with a reduction in the cyclically adjusted public sector
deficit. Past details and our forecast for the US public sector are set
out in table 7.
Japan
Japanese GNP grew by 5-7 per cent in 1990, with an apparent
slowdown in the second half of the year when GNP was 5.2 per cent higher
than a year previously. It appeared likely that GNP would continue to
grow more slowly in the first half of 1991. This expectation was
confounded by the publication of GNP estimates for the first quarter,
which showed GNP 5.9 per cent higher than a year earlier, and 2.7 per
cent higher than in 1990Q4. The growth-rate between 1990Q4 and 1991Q1 is
equivalent to an annualised growth-rate of 11.2 per cent. This estimate
almost certainly overstates the current strength of the Japanese
economy, but nonetheless indicates that earlier forecasts of a
significant slowdown were somewhat premature.
In 1990 GNP growth of 5.7 per cent was composed of domestic demand
growth of 5.8 per cent and a deterioration in net exports equivalent to
0.1 per cent of GNP. The 1991Q1 figures showed domestic demand growth of
4.5 per cent compared to a year earlier, and an improvement in net
exports equivalent to 1.4 per cent of GNP. Although both elements of
demand grew by more than was expected, the improvement in net exports is
especially striking. It appears that the Japanese traded sector is
exploiting the gain in competitiveness derived from the depreciation of
the yen. In the first quarter of 1991 the yen was 1 1 per cent lower
than in the first quarter of 1989, in spite of an appreciation of 1 1
per cent since the second quarter of 1990.
Japanese monetary policy has been tight for much of the last year.
The discount rate was raised from 5.25 per cent to 6 per cent on 30th
August 1990, and was held at that level until 1st July 1991, when it was
reduced to 5.5 per cent. The policy has aimed to reduce the growth of
domestic demand, which increased by over 20 per cent between 1987 and
1990, contributing to increased capacity utilisation, and inflationary
pressures emanating from a tight labour market. Unemployment has
remained at 2.1 per cent of the labour force since the first quarter of
1990, and the ratio of unfilled vacancies to job seekers stood at 1.44
in May 1991, close to its 16 year high of 1.47 reached in June 1990. The
annual Spring wage negotiations produced wage increases averaging 5.7
per cent in 1991, which while slightly down from 1990 will contribute to
domestically generated inflation.
Consumer price inflation peaked at 4.5 per cent in January 1991,
and averaged 3.6 per cent in the second quarter, as against 4.2 per cent
in the first quarter. Domestically generated inflation remains high, but
imported inflation has declined as a result of the fall in the oil price
in early 1991 and the 14 per cent appreciation of the yen between the
second quarters of 1990 and 1991. The first quarter GNP figures also
indicate that domestic demand is growing more slowly. Consumers'
expenditure was only 2.2 per cent higher than a year previously, and
although investment expenditure was 10.4 per cent higher than a year
previously, it was growing more slowly than in 1990, when it averaged
12.7 per cent.
The decision to reduce the discount rate by .5 per cent on 1st
July can be seen as an indication that the Japanese monetary authorities
felt that the economy had slowed sufficiently to avoid the possibility
of overheating, and that consequently some monetary easing was
justified. As well as slower growth in consumers' expenditure,
housing investment has declined substantially, with a fall of 19 per
cent in housing starts in March-May compared to a year previously.
Survey evidence indicates that business investment is expected to grow
more slowly this year. A Bank of Japan survey in May showed planned
increases of 7 per cent, well below outturns for the last three years,
and also the lowest survey figure for several years.
Our forecast presented in table 8, shows GNP growth of 4.0 per cent
for 1991. We expect that the economy will continue to grow more slowly
in the second half of the year as domestic demand growth is restrained
by high interest rates and the growth in external demand is restrained
by the appreciation of the yen over the last year. Domestic demand is
forecast to grow by 3.3 per cent, with growth of consumers'
expenditure slowing to 2.2 per cent, growth in investment slowing to 6.8
per cent and a decline in the level of stockbuilding. Net exports are
forecast to add 0.7 percentage points to GNP growth, as a consequence of
slower growth in Japan combined with a lagged response to the
depreciation of the yen since 1989.
Inflation should continue to decline in the second half of the
year, resulting in an average of 3.3 per cent for the year as a whole.
If inflation does continue to fall in this way it should prove possible
for the Bank of Japan to reduce interest rates again, although this is
unlikely to occur until the fourth quarter. Unemployment is expected to
edge up a little, but the increase will be small, and labour markets are
likely to remain tight.
We expect that in 1992 the growth rate of domestic demand will rise
to 4.0 per cent, but that the growth rate of GNP will decline to 3.6 per
cent, as net exports deteriorate. The recovery in domestic demand growth
will be caused mainly by higher growth in consumers' expenditure.
This will result from higher growth in real personal disposable income as the rate of inflation subsides, and from a lower level of interest
rates than in 1991. The deterioration in net exports will arise from a
higher growth of imports due to higher growth of domestic demand, and
from an erosion of competitiveness caused by the appreciation of the yen
through both 1991 and 1992.
Chart 9 shows the evolution of the Japanese current account balance
over the 1980s, in relation to the level of the Japanese real exchange
rate, and table 9 shows our forecast for Japanese trade and the balance
of payments. The chart shows that the Japanese real exchange rate was
relatively stable in the early 1980s, at a level which enabled Japan to
generate increasing current account surpluses. Between 1985 and 1988 the
real exchange rate appreciated by 44 per cent, leading to a decline in
the current balance surplus from 4.2 per cent in 1986 to 1 .2 per cent
in 1990. However the real exchange rate has depreciated since 1988,
making further erosion of the surplus less likely. In 1991 we expect
that the current account surplus will increase to 2.2 per cent of GNP as
the traded sector benefits from the real depreciation in 1990, but that
thereafter the surplus will gradually erode, as the real exchange rate
is expected to appreciate again in 1991 and 1992.
Germany
Although it is over a year since German economic and monetary
union, and almost a year since political unification, the German economy
is still absorbing the short-term consequences of these two events. The
economy of the western Lander has had to absorb increased demand for the
products, at a time when it was already close to capacity output, while
much of the economy of the eastern Lander has been unable to compete
with western goods, with the result that the east has experienced a
severe recession. The partial integration of the two German economies is
reflected in the gathering of economic data. Our analysis and forecast
focusses on developments within the western economy, although data for
trade and the current balance is now only available for the whole of
Germany.
West German GNP grew by 5.2 per cent in the year to the first
quarter of 1991, compared with growth of 5.4 per cent in the second half
of 1990. Domestic demand grew by 5 per cent in the first quarter of 1991
compared with 5.4 per cent in the second half of 1990. it could
therefore be argued that demand growth is abating, although the effect
is small. Comparisons with a year ago do not give a true picture of
underlying demand growth, since they compare demand before and after
monetary union."
There are, however, some signs that the west German economy has now
absorbed the initial demand shock arising from German monetary union.
The rate of capacity utilisation in manufacturing fell in both 1990Q4
and 1991Q1, and is now at its lowest level since 1989Q1. Seasonally
adjusted unemployment, which fell from 7.3 per cent of the labour force
in June 1990 to 6.2 per cent in January 1991, remained little changed at
6.3 per cent in June 1991. New orders to manufacturing were lower in
February-April 1991 than in any 3-month period since May-July 1990,
before monetary union. Survey indices of the business climate and the
future tendency of production also indicate that demand is growing more
slowly.
German monetary union has led to a higher level of inflation as the
west German economy has had to meet increased demand at close to
capacity output. Consumer price inflation rose from 2.5 per cent in the
first half of 1990, prior to monetary union, to 3.1 per cent in the
second quarter of 1991, and 4.5 per cent in July 1991. The July increase
included the effects of increases in indirect taxes, including taxes on
petrol, which were introduced in order to fund some of the costs of
unification. Inflationary pressures have also become apparent in the
labour market. The annual increase in hourly wage rates rose from 3.2
per cent in the first half of 1990 to 6.9 per cent in June 1991. These
increases have occurred despite the increase in German labour supply
following unification.
The integration of the German labour market is occurring slowly.
East German GNP is estimated to have fallen by around 30 per cent
following unification, with the result that unemployment has risen
strongly. In July 1991 east German unemployment reached 11 million, or
12 per cent of the workforce. Unemployment would be substantially higher
if the authorities had not extended their part-time working support
scheme. However, the labour market is adjusting, albeit slowly. Around
.5 million east Germans are estimated to be working in western Germany.
The reconstruction of east Germany has to date been slow. However it has
received a welcome impetus from the decision to relocate the Bundestag
in Berlin, which will transfer considerable spending power into the
heart of the eastern Lander.
German monetary policy remains tight. Three-month interest rates
averaged 8.4 per cent in 1990, up from 4.3 per cent in 1988 and they
rose further to 9.1 per cent in the first half of 1991, following
increases in the Lombard and discount rates on 1st February. There has
been a widespread expectation that the Bundesbank will tighten monetary
policy further. Our forecast includes an increase in the short-term
rates to 9.5 per cent in the fourth quarter of 1991, in line with money
market expectations. However given that there are signs that economic
growth may be slowing, the Bundesbank may decide to maintain interest
rates at current levels.
Table 10 presents our forecast of west German GNP. National
accounts statistics for the eastern Lander now exist but the disruptions
to the eastern economy means that the quality of this data is unknown,
and for the time being it remains more useful to focus on developments
within the western Lander, which will continue to influence the setting
of German macroeconomic policy. GNP in the western Lander is expected to
grow by 3.1 per cent in 1991. This represents a decline from 4.7 per
cent in 1990, both because the initial stimulus arising out of monetary
union has subsided as the east has experienced recession, and because
monetary policy has continued to bear down on the growth of German
demand. Nevertheless growth for the year will remain high, with
consumers' expenditure growth of 3.3 per cent, higher than in 1988
or 1989, and investment growth of 9 per cent, the second highest rate
recorded in the last twenty years. High growth in domestic demand,
combined with weak external demand will produce a contribution to GNP
growth from net exports of 0.6 per cent of GNP, compared to 0.5 per
cent in 1990 and 11 per cent in 1989.
Inflation is forecast to increase to 3.8 per cent for the year as a
whole. Inflation in the second half of the year is expected to be higher
than in the first half, as wage and indirect tax increases lead to
higher prices. Monetary policy will remain tight, and the Bundesbank
will continue to press for a reduction in the fiscal deficit. These
policy measures will exert downward pressure on both demand and
inflation. Domestic demand growth is expected to slow to 2.9 per cent in
1992, and GNP growth to 2.5 per cent. Inflation may stay above 4 per
cent for the year as a whole. The Government has announced that VAT will
be increased in January 1993, which will cause inflation to increase
temporarily in that year.
Table 11 shows our forecast of German trade and balance of
payments. German imports have grown rapidly since monetary union, while
export growth has slowed in response to weaker demand abroad. in the
first half of 1991 the German trade surplus totalled DM5 billion,
against DM65 billion in the first half of 1990. The current account has
also been affected by payments associated with the Gulf War of DM10.4
billion. These contributed to a current account deficit of DM20 billion
in the first half of the year compared to a surplus of DM50 billion in
the first half of last year.
The current account is expected to return to surplus in the second
half of the year, as the special factor of Gulf War payments no longer
applies, and as German growth slows and external demand recovers. For
the year as a whole the current account may register a deficit of $1
billion. The more favourable current account developments will continue
in 1992, leading to a current surplus of $7 billion or .5 per cent of
West German GNP.
Table 12 shows our forecast of the German public sector deficit,
which emphasises the continuing disequilibrium in the German economy
following monetary union. The public sector deficit for 1991 is expected
to be DM156 billion, or 6 per cent of west German GNP. However this
figure excludes debts incurred by the railways, post and the Treuhand
agency, engaged in privatising east German industry. The Finance
Ministry estimate that transfers to east Germany will amount to DM93
billion this year, DM109 billion in 1992, DM105 billion in 1993 and
DM113 billion in 1994. The public sector deficit will remain at around
DM150 billion in 1992, but is expected to decline to DM108 billion in
1993 when recovery should be underway in the eastern Lander, and when
revenues will be enhanced by the projected increase in VAT in January
1993.
France
French GDP grew by 0.25 per cent between the fourth quarter of 1990
and the first quarter of 1991, after a fall of 0.1 per cent between the
third and fourth quarters of 1990. The French economy has therefore
avoided recession, according to the widely used technical definition of
a recession as two consecutive quarters of falling output. Nevertheless
GDP growth remains weak, with GDP only 1.2 per cent higher than in the
first quarter of 1990.
The weakness in GDP growth can be largely attributed to weak
domestic demand growth. Consumers' expenditure in the first quarter
of 1991 was 1.9 per cent higher than a year previously, but private
sector investment was only .6 per cent higher than a year earlier. Net
exports reduced GDP growth by .3 per cent, although this represented an
improvement on 1990, reflecting slower import growth in response to
slower domestic demand growth.
The slower growth of demand has been reflected in failing capacity
utilisation and rising unemployment. Capacity utilisation fell to 82.9
per cent in the first quarter of 1991, having reached a peak of 86.3 per
cent in the second quarter of 1990. Unemployment rose to 2.7 million in
May 1991, an increase of 200,000 since May 1990. These developments
should exert downward pressure on labour costs. Hourly wage-rates in
industry rose by 5 per cent in the year to March 1991, compared to 4.5
per cent in 1990. Low pressure of demand has also been reflected in
continuing low inflation. Consumer price inflation registered 3.3 per
cent in June 1991, and was lower than in Germany for the first time
since 1973.
Survey evidence points to stronger growth in the French economy in
the second half of the year. In May those expecting manufacturing
production to increase outnumbered those expecting it to fall for the
first time since July 1990, and whilst there remained a negative balance
in response to a question on the prospects for the industrial sector,
the degree of pessimism has declined since February. The leading
indicators index has also been rising since February. The more
optimistic outlook has been partly conditioned by a relaxation in
monetary policy, with 3-month interest rates failing from 10.3 per cent
in January 1991 to 9.2 per cent in May.
Our forecast, presented in table 13, is for GDP growth of 1.5 per
cent in 1991. Domestic demand is expected to grow by 1.3 per cent, with
a fall in investment expenditure and consumers' expenditure growth
of 2.1 per cent. Net exports should add 0.2 per cent to GNP growth.
Import growth will be restrained by weak domestic demand growth, while
exports will benefit from strong growth in Germany, although other
export markets are either in recession or growing more slowly than in
1989 and 1990.
GNP growth is expected to pick up in the second half of this year
and into 1992. Domestic demand growth should respond to the reduction of
interest rates in the second quarter of this year, and external demand
will benefit both from a recovery in demand in French export markets and
from the recent depreciation of the franc against both the US dollar and
the yen. The stance of monetary policy is unlikely to change
significantly, although a small increase in French interest rates may
occur if Germany interest rates are increased. In our forecast we assume
that French rates rise by 0.2 percentage points in the fourth quarter,
but this is unlikely to restrain the recovery in economic activity.
The reduction in capacity utilisation and increase in unemployment
that have arisen from slower growth in the second half of 1990 and first
half of 1991 should enable inflation to remain at around 3 per cent in
both 1991 and 1992. French inflation will consequently remain below
German inflation, and this should provided scope for further narrowing
of the interest-rate differential between the two countries.
The French Government expects that tax revenues for 1991 will be
around FF40 billion below their budget projection, and that consequently
the budget deficit will exceed the target of FF80 billion. The target of
FF80 billion has been retained for 1992, and since the Government does
not wish to increase the tax burden, this is expected to entail lower
growth in public spending. Spending on education and research remains a
priority, but defence spending is likely to be cut.
Our forecast for French trade and the balance of payments is shown
in table 14. The trade deficit for 1991 Q2 was FF7.6 billion, down from
FF1 3.7 billion in 1991 Q1. Import growth has slowed in response to
slower growth in demand. Export markets are expected to grow by 4.8 per
cent in 1991, with high growth in Germany compensating for lower growth
in other markets. In the latter half of the year the trade balance will
improve as a result of improved competitiveness following the
franc's depreciation against the US dollar and the yen. The visible
balance should therefore improve compared to 1990, and this will also
contribute to an improvement in the current balance, which is expected
to register a deficit of 7.8 billion in 1991 and 4.8 billion in 1992.
Italy
Italian GDP was unchanged between the third and fourth quarters of
1990. This meant that growth over the preceding year slowed from 1.8 per
cent in the third quarter to 10 per cent in the fourth quarter. This
deterioration was mainly due to a deterioration in net exports, since
domestic demand growth over the preceding year remained at 2.8 per cent
in the fourth quarter, compared to 2.9 per cent in the third quarter.
The growth-rates of domestic demand and GNP were both lower in 1990 than
in 1989, as the economy continued to respond to the restrictive monetary
and fiscal stance adopted in 1989.
Recent indicators suggest that the economy has continued to grow
slowly in the first half of 1991, but may begin to grow more rapidly in
the second half of the year. The leading indicator index increased from
112.1 in January 1991 to 113.7 in May. Industrial production increased
by .3 per cent between the fourth quarter of 1990 and the first quarter
of 1991 although it declined in April for the fourth consecutive month.
Business survey evidence shows that manufacturers have become more
optimistic in recent months, although it remains the case that more
respondents expect economic prospects to deteriorate than to improve.
Employment in industry increased in both the fourth quarter of 1990 (by
.7 per cent) and the first quarter of 1991 (11 per cent), although
unemployment also increased in the first two quarters of 1991.
Our forecast is presented in table 15. GNP growth is expected to
slow to 1.4 per cent in 1991. This will be the lowest annual growth-rate
since 1983. Lower growth in 1991 is due to lower growth of domestic
demand, since the change in net exports as a proportion of GDP is
expected to improve from 0.9 per cent in 1990 to -0.4 per cent in 1991.
Italian interest rates rose from 114 per cent in the third quarter of
1990 to 13.1 per cent in the first quarter of 1991, and although they
were reduced to 12.3 per cent in the second quarter, it is expected that
the higher level of interest rates will restrict domestic demand growth
in 1991. Lower domestic growth will also restrict the growth of imports,
and net exports will also benefit from strong growth in German demand
and from the depreciation of the lira since the middle of the 1990. In
July 1991 the effective rate for the lira was 3.2 per cent lower than in
August 1990. These developments will also lead to a reduction in the
italian current account deficit to $3 billion, or 0.3 per cent of GDP.
Inflation is expected to fall to 5.8 per cent in 1991 from 6.2 per
cent in 1990. In the second half of last year inflation rose to 6.6 per
cent, but had fallen to 6.4 per cent in February 1991. Wholesale price
inflation registered 0.1 per cent in April 1991, reflecting the
weakening of demand pressures. This is also evident in the decline of
capacity utilisation from 80.8 per cent in the second quarter of 1990 to
77.2 per cent in the first quarter of 1991, and in the rise in
unemployment since the fourth quarter of 1990. Continuing progress in
reducing inflation will however require a reduction in wage inflation
especially in the non-traded goods sector and in the public sector.
Hourly wage rates in industry increased by 7.8 per cent in the year to
February 1991.
Our forecast shows that GNP growth will increase to 2.9 per cent in
1992. Domestic demand growth is expected to increase to 2.8 per cent, as
consumers' expenditure responds to an increase in real earnings
caused by wage inflation declining less rapidly than price inflation.
Net exports are also expected to improve as a result of recovery in
external demand and continuing depreciation of the lira. The current
account balance is expected to deteriorate slightly as a proportion of
GDP. Consumer price inflation may fall below 5 per cent for the first
year since 1969. However, inflation is still expected to be higher than
in other ERM member countries, and this will make it difficult to
maintain the value of the lira within the ERM. In our forecast the lira
is devalued within the ERM in the mid-1990s.
Canada
Canadian GDP declined for the fourth consecutive quarter in the
first quarter of 1991, to record a cumulative decrease of 2.8 per cent
over the preceding year. Domestic demand also fell by 2.8 per cent in
the year to the first quarter, with net exports unchanged as a
proportion of GNP. Consumers' expenditure and investment continued
to decline in the first quarter, but there was some rebuilding of
inventories, for the first occasion since the fourth quarter of 1989.
The severity of the Canadian recession can be attributed to
increases in interest rates from 8.5 per cent in the first quarter of
1988 to 13.6 per cent in the second quarter of 1990, and to the
weakening of demand in the United States. These developments were
exacerbated by the effects of the free trade agreement between Canada
and the United States, which has resulted in some relocation of
production from Canada to the States. However, as interest rates have
fallen to 9.7 per cent, and prospects for the United States economy have
improved, there are grounds for expecting some recovery in the Canadian
economy in the second half of the year. The leading indicators index
rose in April, although it remained below its February level. The
reduction in interest rates appears to have already stimulated activity
in the housing market, with seasonally adjusted housing starts
registering 186,000 in July 1991, an increase of 85,000 on the average
for January-March. Survey evidence shows increased optimism in
manufacturing industry. In the second quarter of 1 991 more respondents
expected that the production would increase in the future than that it
would fall, whereas in the three previous quarters the balance of
respondents had expected that production would fall.
Our forecast, shown in table 16, indicates that the Canadian
economy will move out of recession in either the second or third quarter
of the year. However recovery in the second half of 1991 is likely to be
weak, so that GDP for the year as a whole will be 0.7 per cent below its
level in 1990. Domestic demand is expected to be .5 per cent lower in
1991. Increases in stockbuilding, housing investment and consumers'
expenditure are expected to occur by the third quarter, but the recovery
in business investment may not occur until the fourth quarter, as
capacity utilisation has fallen considerably in the course of the
recession. in the first quarter of 1991 capacity utilisation registered
73 per cent, compared to over 85 per cent in 1987 and 1988. Despite the
decline of domestic demand net exports are expected to deteriorate as a
proportion of GNP in 1991. This is because recession in the United
States, appreciation of the Canadian dollar against the US dollar, and
the higher rate of Canadian inflation will reduce Canadian exports. The
current account deficit is however expected to decline to US$16.2
billion, or 2.7 per cent of GDP.
The introduction of the Goods and Services Tax (GST) at the start
of 1991 has caused a step change in the price level, and consequently
raised the rate of inflation in 1991. The GST was introduced in order to
control the federal budget deficit. However the Canadian recession has
reduced Government revenue, and causing the budget deficit in the fiscal
year commencing in April 1991 to increase to C$30.5 billion. The
February 1991 Budget reduced programme spending, increased some excise levies and raised unemployment-insurance premiums in an attempt to
maintain the deficit at C$30.5 billion for the fiscal year 1991/92.
By 1992 we expect the recovery in GDP to be well under way, with
housing investment and consumers' expenditure growing strongly,
although business investment is expected to recover more slowly. The
recovery in the Canadian economy will be supported by the recovery in
the United States. Inflation is expected to fall to 3.6 per cent, as the
recession will have reduced price pressures within the economy, and
because the inflation figures will no longer include price increases
caused by the introduction of GST.
Developments in Eastern Europe are, at least in the short term,
shrouded in uncertainty. Even in EastGermany the development of a new
set of market mechanisms has been slow, and the scale of capital inflows
has been rather disappointing. However as systems of property rights and
of contract change then we would expect large scale capital inflows to
take place, and these are likely to be matched by current account
deficits. In long run equilibrium real wages in East Europe are likely
to rise toward western levels, and their subsequent evolution over time
will be affected by the rate of population growth and by the other
factors considered by neoclassical growth theories. These factors
include the scale and nature of technical progress. However, in the
short to medium term East Europe has both a large pool of cheap and
reasonably educated labour and a shortage of capital.
Net capital outflows from the major western economies are likely to
help augment the level of domestic saving in the East. These capital
outflows will be responding to the availability of higher rates of
return in the East, and this will have an effect on the rate of return
in the west. Investors will have a tendency to equalise the rate of
return on assets in all locations, and if returns rise outside the major
economies then resources will be bid away from them. This will push up
the domestic rate of return, and saving will be increased. We need to be
able to judge the scale of the potential change in the real interest
rate in order to analyse the effect of capital flows to the East on
western economies.
Real interest rates depend upon the desire to save, upon the
absorption of resources by the government, and on the availability of
productive investment opportunities at both home and abroad. if returns
are high overseas then capital will flow out, the current account will
be in surplus and the real interest rate will be high. Chart Al plots
the relationship between real interest rates, current balances and
government deficits in the G7.
The average real interest rate over this period was 2.8 per cent,
the average G7 current balance deficit was 0.2 per cent and the average
government deficit was 2.6 per cent. We would expect that a rise in
investment opportunities outside the G7 would cause real interest rates
to rise, and we have assumed that a rise in the G7 current balance
surplus of 1 per cent of GNP would raise real interest rates by 1/2 a
per cent. We have used this relationship to analyse the effects of a
permanent 50 per cent increase in imports into eastern Europe financed
largely by capital inflows.
We have assumed that exchange rates do not vary, and that nominal
interest rates rise by the same amount everywhere. Real interest rates
rise on average by less than a half a per cent, but the effects vary
between countries because the effects on inflation and output differ.
Output rises slightly in most countries, but higher interest rates
reduce it in Japan. Table Al summarises the effects after four years.
Output changes much less than does investment in each of the major
economies. The rise in real short-term interest rates affects long
interest rates, and this has particularly strong effects in Japan,
Germany and the UK. Current balances improve everywhere, but especially
in Germany. Capital flows to the East would be substantial. Table A2
gives the effect of the shock on world trade and on East European
exports and current balances after four years.
The commodity price equations on GEM have been re-estimated. We
tested down from a general specification of the form:
where WDPCOM = logarithm of commodity price
WDPXG = logarithm of world export prices
M7GNP = logarithm of major 7 GNP
T = time trend
This specification gives a long-run solution for the real commodity
price. We would expect that technical change in the production processes
in agriculture and mineral extraction should put downward pressure on
real commodity prices, and that this pressure would not be offset by
increases in demand. As both technology and demand evolve at relatively
constant rates in the long run we would expect our equations to contain
trends. The time trend captures any trend in the real commodity price.
The term in AM7 GNP provides a short-term response to changes in the
growth-rate of major 7 economies.
Table 1 specifies the four commodity price equations. All equations
were initially estimated over 1970Q1-1990Q3, and tested for econometric specification and structural stability. The equation for metals and
minerals proved satisfactory on both counts, but the three other
equations failed the structural stability tests, and have therefore been
estimated over shorter time periods. The equations shown in Table 1 all
reject tests for serial correlation, mis-specified functional form and
heteroskedasticity at 5 per cent significance levels. The equation for
agricultural non-food does not reject the test for nonnormality of its
residuals. All the equations appear to be structurally stable.
The effects of these new equations on the simulation properties of
the model are shown in charts 1 and 2. In the case of the US
appreciation the real prices of food and agricultural non-food initially
rise, as the dollar price of world exports falls more rapidly than the $
price of these commodities. However by year 4 of the simulation all 4
real commodity prices have returned to their base values. Our previous
equations which were discussed in the August 1988 Review-did display
some dollar inhomogeneities and these have been removed. Chart 2 shows
that the oil price increase has a small effect on real commodity prices,
with an initial fall of less than 1 per cent that is largely reversed by
year 4 of the simulation. Our old equations embodied permanent effects
from oil prices onto all commodity prices. These reflected the
experience of the early 1970s, and the relationship between oil prices
and commodity prices now a ears much less strong.
We have recently re-estimated the unemployment equations on GEM for
the G7 economies. Our new equations have been derived from a common
functional form. The equations were obtained by testing down from the
following specification:
where
U = Unemployment rate
y = logarithm of GDP
(GNP for US, Japan, Germany)
This specification has the following long-run solution:
g = steady-state rate of growth ( per cent per quarter)
They can be described as simple Okun's Law relationships that
are designed to pick up the cycle in unemployment that follows from
cycles in the rate of growth of the economy. The lags are very long, and
unemployment cycles can lag well behind those in output. However, these
equations suggest that if growth stabilises and does not cycle the
unemployment will also stabilise.
The aim was to obtain a well-specified, stable equation that could
explain 1970Q1-1989Q4. This could not be achieved in every case, and
consequently some equations have been estimated over shorter time
periods.
Table 1 lists the final equations for each country. The equations
for Japan, France and the United Kingdom have been estimated from
1970Q1, the equation for Germany from 1974Q1, the equations for Canada
and the United States from 1976Q1 and the equation for Italy from
1978Q1. In all cases apart from Italy the coefficients appear
well-determined. Although the coefficients in the italian equation are
not significant, the equation satisfies tests for white noise errors and
structural stability, and also has desirable simulation properties.
Apart from Canada all equations satisfy tests for white noise
errors at the 5 per cent significance level. All the equations pass
tests for the restrictions imposed from the general model. Apart from
the United Kingdom all the restrictions imposed were setting
coefficients on dynamic terms to zero. In the United Kingdom the
coefficient on lagged unemployment level was poorly determined, and it
proved acceptable to impose a value of 0-01, which was more negative
than its unrestricted estimate. None of the equations revealed
significant structural instability as measured by the predictive failure
and Chow tests, although the equations for Canada and the United States
reject the null hypothesis of constant variance at 5 per cent
significance levels.
In four of the equations it proved possible to restrict the
coefficients on lagged changes in unemployment to zero. The exceptions
were Germany, Canada and the United Kingdom, where the coefficients on
the first lag proved significant with values of .55, .49 and .89
respectively. The coefficient of .89 in the United Kingdom is
especially high and may prove problematic if it is incorporated in the
model.
The new equations contain a long-run solution for the unemployment
rate in terms of the rate of growth. Table 2a shows the average
growth-rate and average unemployment rate over 1970-89 for each country,
together with the long-run solution of the unemployment equations for
the average growth-rate. The long-run solutions are reasonably close to
the historical averages for the United States, Japan, UK and Canada, but
over-predict for Germany, France and Italy. Table 2b shows the same
comparison for the period 1980-89. The long-run solutions for Germany,
France and Italy still over-predict, but by less than in Table 2a, while
the solution for the United Kingdom under predicts the period average.
However mean lags in these equations are very long, implying
considerable hysteresis in the unemployment rate, and hence a slow
convergence on the implied long-run solution.
In both forecasts and simulations the steady-state growth rate is
determined by other equations in our model. The model has a tendency to
settle down to a stable rate of growth, and this will be associated with
a stable level of unemployment. The interaction of demand equations and
price equations ensure that if demand is growing too rapidly then
inflation rises which crowds out excess demand growth. Similarly if
demand is growing slowly, inflation falls, and this generates extra
demand through the effects of lower prices in raising real wealth. Table
3 shows the rate of growth and the level of unemployment generated from
extending our forecast until the year 2005. The table is remarkable both
for the diversity of levels of unemployment in various countries and
from the tendency of the level of unemployment to stabilise. The former
feature flows largely for institutional differences, the latter from the
fact that our forecast, which extends to 2005, does not contain cycles.
BOX A. MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY DEVELOPMENTS IN THE MAJOR 7
ECONOMIES Table Al provides indicators of monetary and fiscal policy
stance for the major 7 economies for the last three years. We have
chosen to assess monetary policy stance in terms of the ex-post real
interest rates, and fiscal policy stance by the ex-post general
government financial balance. Both measures show actual outcomes of
policy decisions rather than expected outcomes, and hence unanticipated
developments in the economy will have resulted in the measured policy
stance being tighter or looser than the intended policy stance. These
measures do not therefore reflect just the discretionary element of
monetary and fiscal policy, but indicate how policies combined with
contemporary developments in their impact on the economy.
Changes in real interest rates suggest that the monetary stance was
loosened in all major 7 economies in the first half of 1988, following
the stock marketcrash in October 1987. In the second half of 1988 and
the first half of 1989 real interest rates increased in all economies
except Japan, and further increases followed in the second half of 1989
in all countries except the United States, where there was a substantial
decrease. Between the first half of 1988 and the second half of 1989 the
largest real interest-rate increases occurred in the United Kingdom,
Germany and Canada. Real interest rates remained high in the four
European countries in 1990, but fell significantly in Canada, and rose
in both Japan and the United States. In the first half of 1991 there
appear to have been significant increases in real interest rates in
italy and Japan, and significant decreases in the United States and
United Kingdom.
The cyclically adjusted financial balances show that fiscal policy
was contractionary in 1988 in the United Kingdom, Japan and Canada and
expansionary in Germany, France and italy. In 1989 fiscal policy was
contractionary in Germany, Italy and Japan, expansionary in Canada and
broadly neutral elsewhere. In 1990 there was an especially large
expansion in Germany caused by additional expenditure following monetary
union, expansion in the United Kingdom and France, and a broadly neutral
stance elsewhere.