Macroeconomic convergence in Europe.
Anderton, R. ; Barrell, R. ; Veld, Jan Willem 等
Economic convergence within the EMS member states is a precondition for further moves to economic and monetary integration. The Delors
Report has set out a path toward EMU in three stages, where transition
to the next stage depends on some degree of convergence being achieved
in the previous stage. In October 1990, the European Council in Rome
agreed that 'in order to move on to the second phase (of economic
and monetary union), further satisfactory and lasting progress toward
real and monetary convergence will have to be achieved' (Press
communique, European Council, Rome, 28 October 1990). The draft treaty
text for the Maastricht summit states that before the start of the
second phase in January 1994, the council shall assess the progress made
with regard to economic and monetary convergence, and in particular with
regard to price stability and balanced public finances.
Before transition to the third stage, and not later than December
1996, progress made in economic convergence must be reassessed. On
October 28th the Dutch released a draft Treaty text for the Maastricht
Summit (to be held on 8th and 9th of December) which stated four
criteria for transition to the third stage relating to inflation
performance, budget positions, exchange-rate stability and interest-rate
convergence. The draft treaty text was accompanied by separate protocols
laying down the criteria for economic convergence. Financial Times,
October 29th 1991). First, each prospective member state must have
'a price performance that is sustainable and a rate of inflation
observed over a period of one year before the examination that does not
exceed that of the, at most, three best performing member states in
terms of price stability by more than 1.5 percentage points. inflation
shall be measured by means of the consumer price index (CPI) on a
comparable basis'. The protocol states that the government
budgetary criterion shall not be met if there is a council decision that
an 'excessive' deficit exists for the member state concerned.
Another protocol stipulates that the deficit should not exceed 3 per
cent of GDP and the debt to GDP ratio should not exceed 60 per cent.
This criterion refers to the general government, that is, central,
regional and local government and social security funds. The third
criterion relates to a country's record in the ERM. Any prospective
candidate for the third stage must have respected the normal, that is,
narrow, fluctuation margins in the ERM without severe tensions for at
least the last two years before its examination', ruling out
devaluations. The fourth criterion states that nominal long-term
interest rates must not have exceeded that of the, at most, three best
performing member states in terms of price stability by more than 2
percentage points in the last year before examination.
The analysis of convergence
In this note we will discuss the convergence achieved so far in
Europe and assess the prospects of further convergence in the coming
years.(1) In general terms convergence can be defined as the narrowing
of international differences in the development of certain economic
variables. As a requirement for a system of stable exchange rates, a
distinction must be made between nominal convergence, which is the
convergence of the development of costs and prices and their underlying
determinants, real convergence of working conditions and living
standards and the convergence of economic institutions or structures.
Real convergence is one of the fundamental objectives of a fully
intergrated Europe, but it is a long-term process and it is not a
necessary condition for a successful transition to an economic and
monetary union. The note by Begg and Mayes in this Review analyses the
issues around real convergence. This note is mainly concerned with
nominal convergence but the convergence of economic structures is also
briefly discussed.
In a monetary union inflation rates must be similar, and hence it
is prudent to insist that countries demonstrate that they are willing
and able to converge in this respect before the union is finalised. This
demonstration involves getting inflation rates into line, and doing so
without strain. The strain would show up in indices of competitiveness,
in unemployment and in external balance. Lack of strain implies some
conditions, on underlying economic variables, such as fiscal and
external balances. Convergence of price performance can only be
maintained when such underlying factors do not put pressure on prices to
diverge again.
This does not of course mean that fiscal and current account
balance are required, rather that they must be consistent with internal
and external equilibrium.
If a region is far away from its non-accelerating inflation rate of
unemployment, NAIRU, or its fundamental equilibrium exchange rate, FEER,
then this cannot be a sustainable situation and some sort of adjustment
toward equilibrium will take place. A prolonged overvaluation of the
real exchange rate associated with a current account imbalance is not
sustainable. Such a situation will lead to lower exports, higher imports
and the gradual decumulation of wealth. These will all lead to lower
demand and this will put downward pressure on prices. Of course, current
account deficits will be easier to finance in a fully integrated Europe
with free capital flows, but this will be at the cost of higher interest
payments. Such a situation does not rule out an economic and monetary
union, but it has implications for the costs of adjustment. An economy
cannot continually diverge from its NAIRU and FEER because the automatic
stabilising mechanisms in the economy will eventually produce
adjustment. The further a country is away from equilibrium, and the
longer this lasts, the more painful will be the adjustment. (2)
The transition from high to low inflation also involves reducing
nominal interest rates and (in some cases) reducing fiscal deficits. It
is arguable that this transition should be made before joining EMU.
Fiscal balance is not required for all countries, nor a full convergence
of public debt positions. But it is generally accepted that a situation
of prolonged fiscal deficits and a rising debt to GDP ratio is not
sustainable. The increasing burden of servicing the public debt reduces
fiscal flexibility. If countries are not in a monetary union this burden
may put upward pressure on real interest rates, and may ultimately lead
countries to resort to monetary financing or inflation as methods to
reduce the real debt stock. Once inside a union individual countries
face fewer financing problems, and hence they may feel some relaxation
of the pressure to observe fiscal discipline. A minimum political
requirement for transition to EMU may well therefore be that all
countries are on a sustainable debt path. This rules out countries that
have not managed to bring the medium term trend of public debt under
control. For this trend to be stabilising, the primary surplus, the
overall public sector balance excluding interest payments, must exceed
the product of the desired, or initial, debt to GDP ratio and the
difference between the long-term nominal interest rate and nominal
growth rate (3). We will show below that not all Community countries
have achieved this target.
In the following we will review the progress that has been made so
far in the European Community in achieving the necessary convergence of
the most important economic variables. We consider not only the
countries that are members of the EC at present, but include Austria in
our comparison, as Austria has de facto followed the D-Mark over the
last 10 years and has arguably achieved closer convergence to Germany
than many ERM countries. We will first discuss the exchange-rate
developments and the realignments in the ERM. Next we review consumer
price indices, as well as different cost measures and measures of
competitiveness and real exchange rates. We will also look at the
performance of monetary variables such as short and long-term interest
rates. We will then consider measures of external and internal
imbalances.
Exchange-rate developments
Since its inception in 1979, the ERM has seen 12 realignments. The
first years were characterised by frequent tensions within the system
and some large realignments. These were partly caused by large
differences in countries' external positions but mainly by
continuing inflation differentials, which were a reflection of divergent
economic performances. These divergences provoked expectations of
exchange-rate realignments and speculative capital flows that put
irresistable pressure on the system to realign. Table 1 shows all the
changes in parities that have taken place since 1979. Only after 1983,
when several countries' domestic economic policies changed, did a
stable exchange rate in the EMS became the objective for monetary
policy. Only then were serious efforts made to achieve the nominal
convergence needed for exchange-rate stability. it is often said that
the ERM became hard at that time. During the first 10 years, the Italian
lira participated in the ERM in wider fluctuation margins of 6 per cent
around bilateral central rates and only since 1990 has adopted normal
margins of 2-25 per cent. Spain and the United Kingdom joined the ERM in
1989 and 1990 respectively and have opted also for the wider fluctuation
margins of 6 per cent. Over the last decade, the italian lira has
devalued most, by more than 40 per cent, followed by the French franc
and the irish pound. The Dutch guilder has continually shadowed the
D-Mark closely and has only devalued by 2 per cent in 1979 and 1983
against the D-Mark. The Austrian schilling has depreciated only 10 per
cent against the D-Mark over the period 1979 to 1991, and has been
virtually pegged to the D-Mark since 1981.
Prices and costs
The general trend of the last decade suggests an emerging nominal
convergence among ERM members. In particular, consumer price inflation
differentials have narrowed dramatically over the 1980s. Table 2 and
Charts 1 to 2 show that the Netherlands and Belgium, and more recently
France, ireland and Denmark, have achieved the greatest inflation
convergence towards German rates in absolute terms. Inflation in the
Netherlands has actually been lower than that in Germany since 1987 and
Austria has also achieved close convergence to German rates. France,
Denmark and Ireland have managed to bring their inflation rates down to
close to the German rate after having all experienced very high
inflation during the first half of the 1980s. ireland in particular has
seen a dramatic decline in its inflation rate from a peak of 19 per cent
in 1981 to below 4 per cent in the second half of the decade.
Chart 3 shows the inflation rates of the ERM countries that had not
achieved convergence to German rates by the end of last year. italy has
reduced its inflation differential vis-a-vis Germany from 15 percentage
points in 1980 to 3 points at present. Spain has achieved a similar
inflation differential. The United Kingdom has, after a diverging inflationary trend in recent years, achieved closer convergence since
the beginning of this year. it should be noted that although this
general disinflationary experience is also common among many non-ERM
countries, their experience has not been so strongly associated with
shrinking inflation differentials. However, there is no doubt that the
recent inflationary upsurge in the newly unified Germany has exaggerated
the impression of inflation convergence. Much of the achieved
convergence can be attributed to the increase in the rate of inflation
in Germany from around zero to 4 per cent. Furthermore, our latest
forecast given in Chapter 2 of the Review suggests that a high inflation
rate in the newly unified Germany will persist for the next few years.
Price inflation convergence in several ERM member countries has
been associated with the steady implementation of austerity packages
with the process beginning around 1982. Since the election of a new
coalition government in the Netherlands in 1982, both the real minimum
wage and the ratio of unemployment benefits to average earnings have
been reduced, followed in 1984 by cuts in nominal public sector
wages(4). In 1982 Belgium introduced a corrective policy package of
increased taxes, reduced public expenditure, suspension or elimination
of wage indexation and the freezing of some prices(5). Also in 1982,
Denmark implemented measures consisting of 'tight fiscal policy,
wage guidelines, suspension of wage indexation ..... and a fixed
exchange-rate policy' (Anderson and Risager (1988)). According to Dornbusch (1989), in 1982 ireland adopted a policy of higher tax rates
and tighter money, froze special pay increases in the public sector and
'hardened-up' on the exchange rate. Also in 1982, France
introduced a temporary freeze on prices and wages and announced a
reduction in budget deficit plans(6). Italy began the process of
dismantling wage indexation (the Scala Mobile) in 1983 (7).
As table 3 shows, the above measures helped to reduce the rate of
increase in unit labour costs, relative to Germany, for many ERM
countries. However, Italy has been less successful in this respect.
Non-convergence of Italian unit labour costs has been associated with
falling export profit margins. This seems to support the hypothesis
that, due to greater exposure to foreign competition, prices in the
traded-goods sector are under more pressure to converge than the
non-traded sector. Further evidence of this is contained in the
1990/1991 OECD Country Survey on Italy (page 88) which demonstrates that
the price of Italian services are rising rapidly compared to other
sectors and Italy seems to be an outlier' in this respect compared
to other ERM members(8) . Chart 4 gives a comparison of French and
Italian manufacturing export profit margins. The slower growth of French
unit labour costs seems to have allowed France to converge in terms of
manufacturing export prices without severely squeezing profit margins.
Although inflation differentials have narrowed, they have not
disappeared. As a result price levels for many ERM members are
continually diverging. Given that no substantial currency realignments
have occurred since 1987 this means that real exchange rates have
appreciated for several ERM countries. In particular, in CPI terms, the
Italian real exchange rate has increased by over 15 per cent since 1987
and, in its brief period of EMS membership, Spain has experienced a 10
per cent real appreciation. Ireland, Denmark and France have also
experienced less severe real appreciations. There seems little change in
fundamentals to justify these real appreciations. On the contrary, in
the August Review we argued that France and Italy have experienced a
depreciation of their FEERs over the 1980s(9). The real appreciation
will make future adjustments more difficult. Charts 5, 6 and 7 plot
relative normalised unit labour costs which are commonly used as a
measure of the real exchange rate. Once again it is possible to divide
these countries into three groups with Denmark, Germany and the
Netherlands experiencing real appreciations since 1985. These reflect
the nature of their economies rather than the emergence of structural
problems. The second group consists of Austria, Belgium, France and
ireland where real exchange rates have been constant in recent years.
The third group contains the UK, italy and Spain. All have previously
used the nominal exchange rate to overcome the effects of inflation
differentials. Since they have eshewed the use of this instrument they
have appreciated in real terms, reflecting emerging competitiveness
problems.
Although not members of the ERM, Greece and Portugal belong to the
EC and may participate in a future monetary union if sufficient economic
convergence is achieved. However, tables 2 and 3 reveal that substantial
adjustment is required within these countries if acceptable growth rates for prices and unit labour costs are to be attained.
Interest rates
Short term interest-rate differentials have narrowed considerably
among ERM members. The Netherlands have followed the most credible
policy since the inception of the ERM with the Dutch Guilder virtually
moving in line with the D-Mark. As a consequence, the Dutch/German
interest-rate differential is now almost zero and has been for some
time. The same can be said of interest rates in Austria. Chart 8 plots
interest rates in these countries along with that in Germany. Throughout
the rest of the ERM member countries, interest rates that were almost
double that of Germany in the pre-ERM period are now within 1 or 2
percentage points of the German rate. These remaining ERM countries can
be divided into two distinct groups, those where interest-rate
convergence has recently taken place, and those where it has not. This
latter group consists of Italy, Spain and the UK. Even though the
differential has been cut to around 2 percentage points this has been at
least in part the result of rising rates in Germany rather than failing
rates in the UK, Spain or Italy. German short rates are 6 points higher
than in the middle of 1988 whilst rates in the UK are only 2 points
higher. Chart 9 plots interest-rate differentials for these three
countries against Germany.
The third group of ERM countries form a central lane in contrast to
the fast and slow groups described above. As Chart 10 shows, interest
rates in France and Belgium, and to a lesser extent in Ireland, have
been moving together for some time, and in the last two years the
differential against Germany has narrowed from around 1.5 per cent to
approximately zero. Some of this narrowing has been associated with
policy announcements. A good example is the effects of the Belgian
announcement in March that they would peg the BFranc to the D-Mark. The
interest-rate differential against the D-Mark disappeared almost
immediately. In recent months Dutch, Belgian, Danish and Austrian short
rates have all been within 1/3 of a per cent of German rates, whilst
French and Irish rates have recently moved to within 1/2 percentage
point of German rates. it is even possible that French rates may fall
below those in Germany in 1992. Short rates in the UK and Italy remain
about 1 1/2 to 2 points above those in Germany, whilst Spanish rates
(buoyed up by capital inflow controls) have maintained a differential of
over 3 percentage points. This period of interest-rate convergence has
been combined with the virtual elimination of substantial capital
controls, and France and Italy have virtually eradicated
onshore/offshore interest-rate differentials.
The draft Maastricht treaty makes great play of the role of
convergence of long-term interest rates. Longer term interest
differentials have not shown such clear evidence of convergence as
short-term rates especially for italy, Denmark, Spain and the UK. Table
4 gives long-term interest rates for the EC countries, and Chart 11
plots long rates on a quarterly basis for the major four over the same
period. Long rates embed expected future short rates, and hence if short
rates are expected to converge (as is necessary in a Monetary Union )
then long rates must already show signs of doing the same. The evidence
from recent changes in long rates suggests that short rates are expected
to converge in Germany, France, Belgium, Netherlands, Austria and even
Ireland. However, UK, Italian and Spanish long rates show fewer signs of
an expected convergence in short rates. This may not only be due to
expectations of future higher inflation but, for countries such as
italy, the situation may be exacerbated by large government debt/GDP
ratios. Nevertheless, if long rates do not converge it is a clear sign
that markets are not expecting a union to be formed.
Long rates strongly suggest that Portugal and Greece are not
expected to participate in a monetary union in the near future.
Government debt
In recent years, government primary balances have switched from
deficit to surplus in France, Ireland, Denmark, Belgium and the UK. In
contrast, primary deficits have been consistently recorded over the past
decade for Italy , Greece and the Netherlands with Germany joining this
group only recently. The sustainability of these positions depends upon
whether the net government debt to GDP ratio is stable (although
consideration should also be given to the absolute size of the net
debt/GDP ratio). Chart 12 shows that, although very high, Ireland's
net debt ratio is decreasing as are the smaller debt ratios of Denmark
and the UK. Chart 13 reveals that the Netherlands, Belgium and italy
have substantial debt ratios, although Belgium seems to have reversed
the deterioration whereas Italy and the Netherlands seem to be on a less
stable path. As can be seen from Chart 14, sustainable net government
debt positions seem to have been achieved by Germany, France, Spain and
Austria. Consequently, taking into account both the absolute size and
trajectory of debt ratios, convergence conditions require corrective
fiscal action in Italy, Belgium, Ireland Greece, Portugal and, perhaps
to a lesser degree, the Netherlands(10). However, the link between
'unsustainable' debt positions and real interest rates is
somewhat tenuous-Italy and France have had very similar real interest
rates over the past five years even though their fiscal positions have
diverged substantially.(11)
External balance
From the viewpoint of external balance, Charts 15 to 17 show that
Belgium, Denmark, Germany, France, ireland, Italy, Austria and the
Netherlands seem to be in sustainable positions. However, this external
equilibrium has been a fairly recent phenomena for some countries and
provides some tentative evidence of convergence; Denmark and Belgium
registered current account deficits of over 5 per cent of GDP in the
1980s and Ireland began the decade with a 14 per cent deficit. Italy may
be in a less favourable position than the chart suggests, as she has a
small but deteriorating overseas deficit which may worsen due to the
high Italian real exchange rate and narrowing of export profit margins.
Germany has recently moved into current balance deficit and it should be
remembered that the unusual temporary position of high demand for
imports by Germany (because of re-unification) has optimistically overstated the sustainability of the trading position of some ERM
members. Chart 17 shows that Spain and the UK may have structural trade
problems which may only be solved by real devaluation or relatively
slower growth (12). However, capital flows are now more mobile and
substantial deficits relative to GDP can be sustained for long periods.
Obviously, both fiscal and current balance deficits will be more
easily sustained once monetary union occurs. Therefore, rapid
convergence of these factors may not be so necessary as other
macro-variables.
Unemployment
Both Italy and, in particular, Ireland currently have unemployment
rates well above 10 per cent (and also reached higher levels in the
process towards inflation convergence). But France, Belgium and Denmark
also have high unemployment rates around 9 per cent. The newcomers to
the ERM, Spain and the UK, already have substantial unemployment rates
of around 16 per cent and 9 per cent respectively (see table 5). The
average unemployment rate within the ERM for 1990 of around 10.5 per
cent compares unfavourably with the USA and Japan at 5.5 per cent and 2
per cent respectively. There is of course no reason to expect that all
countries would have the same level of unemployment when they are at the
NAIRU.
High unemployment rates seem to be partly the result of achieving
nominal convergence with Germany via the implementation of deflationary packages.(13) The output/unemployment cost of these deflationary
policies partly depends upon the credibility of the particular
government's commitment to the exchange-rate parities of the ERM.
By adopting credible policies consistent with the ERM exchange-rate
bands, a government can borrow' the anti-inflation
'reputation' of Germany and reduce inflationary expectations.
Studies such as Weber op cit argue that reputation and credibility were
not attained for the majority of the ERM countries until the later 1980s
(around 1987) which may partly explain the high rates of unemployment
prevalent in the last decade within the ERM(14). Artis and Nachane
(1987) claim that price expectations were shifted downward in the ERM
period. They find that price expectations for ERM countries in the
1980s, relative to the 1970s, were more influenced by German inflation.
Barrell (1990) shows that wage and price behaviour in some ERM member
countries has undergone structural change in the last decade. However,
although this change in structure has reduced the output costs of
deflationary policies, it is possible that the fall in inflation has
cost 700,000 and a million job losses in France and Italy respectively.
(15)
The completion of the internal market program in 1992 also has
important implications for the labour market. Integration of the goods
market in Europe should result in greater product price elasticity (as
monopoly suppliers diminish) and hence a more price elastic demand for
labour. Either wage setters will become more responsive to the new
conditions in the labour market or unemployment will rise further. It
should be noted that the whole process of European integration, since
the formation of the EEC, has been associated with rising unemployment
in Europe relative to outside the EEC. One would expect the reduction of
internal tariffs, greater cooperation and integration to actually
decrease unemployment.
Conclusions
It is evident that substantial progress has been made towards
nominal economic convergence among the ERM member countries. However,
countries such as the UK, Spain and Italy are finding it more difficult
to control price inflation and maintain competitiveness. Furthermore,
countries such as France, Belgium, Denmark and Ireland have achieved
inflation convergence vis-a-vis Germany only at the cost of
substantially higher unemployment. Indeed, the ERM could be described as
a low inflation-high unemployment regime. Conversely, the other members
of the EC, Greece and Portugal, have not attained nominal convergence
but have experienced relatively lower unemployment. It is worth noting
that the best macroeconomic performance over the period analysed was
achieved by a non-ERM country, namely Austria.
Two major factors have had a favourable influence upon nominal
convergence. First, most of the last decade has been associated with
virtually worldwide macroeconomic stability. Convergence may have been
more difficult to achieve if the ERM countries faced, for example,
another substantial adverse oil price shock. Second, the inflationary
impetus in Germany caused by re-unification has given a flattering
impression of convergence. However, compared to the past, German
anti-inflation discipline is expected to be somewhat weaker for some
time, therefore convergence may be further enhanced. But this does
expose the fact that the ERM reputation of providing stable, and low,
price inflation does depend on the ability of one nation to maintain
control over price inflation.
The convergence of economic structures is an important factor
influencing the sustainability of a monetary union once it has been
formed. Inflation rates can be made to converge, and eventually it
should even be possible for all economies in a union to operate at full
employment with low inflation as long as no external shocks hit the
system. Diversities in economic structures may well engender differing
responses to external shocks, and differential experience of common
events may make it politically impossible to hold a union together. Some
differences in structure, such as those stemming from natural resources
or from culture may be immutable.
The UK, Norway and the Netherlands are energy producers and hence
their response to an oil price shock will differ from that of the rest
of the Community. Trading patterns, and in particular the Uk's
links with the US, inevitably depend on culture. The effect on the
Community of developments in the US will depend on trade patterns, and
shocks to the US will feed through differentially. The effects of such
shocks are inevitably asymmetric, and their implications are analysed in
Barrell (1990a).
In Barrell (1990b) we argue that other differences in structure
such as those in labour markets may be more malleable. Labour market
structures depend in part on the institutions that have been developed
to deal with inflation and bargaining. Some countries, such as Italy and
the UK, appear to react rapidly to inflationary shocks, whilst others
such as Germany respond only slowly. These differences will amplify the
effects of common shocks. Even if a shock to the union is in the long
run symmetric in its effects, differences in the dynamic patterns of
response may make effects asymmetric in the short run. As Barrell,
Gurney and In't Veld (1991) argue these asymmetries may make a
union difficult to sustain.
A successful union would be more likely if a shock had only small
effects on the location of the new equilibrium for the exchange rate and
unemployment in the economies of the union. This may require some
convergence of structures and institutions. The mere existence of the
union may help produce such convergence of structures. Labour market
institutions will evolve in relation to the more stable environment.
This process can be speeded up in various ways. The single market
programme should increase competition within Europe, and this will
produce pressures on wage bargainers to act in the same way throughout
the Community. it will also increase the sensitivity of trade flows to
competitiveness, and as Barrell and In't Veld (1991) show this will
reduce the effects of shocks on the location of the equilibrium exchange
rate. However, institutional adaption without political assistance can
be very slow.
As Europe moves closer towards a full economic and monetary union
the whole issue of convergence becomes more complicated. If the date for
union is known, this opens up the possibility of devaluations
immediately before exchange rates cannot be changed. This action would
be beneficial for the devaluing countries in terms of short-term price
competitiveness and reductions in the real value of government debt, but
it might harm the anti-inflation reputation of the counties concerned.
For this reason, some authors (for example, Froot and Rogoff (1990))
argue that convergence has peaked as expectations of the- above scenario
will cause prices and interest rates to diverge now. Conversely, the
prospect of irrevocably fixed exchange rates may provide extra policy
credibility and enhance the process of convergence.
REFERENCES
AMEX Bank Review (1991),18 September 1991, vol.18, no.7.
Alogoskoufis, G., Papedemos, L. and Portes, R, External constraints
on macroeconomic policy: the European experience.
Andersen, T., and Risayer, 0. (1988) Stabilisation policies,
credibility and interest rate determination in a small open
economy,' European Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 32 pp.
669-673.
Artis, M.J. and Nachane, D., (1990), Wages and prices in Europe, a
test of the German leadership hypothesis', Weltwirtschaftliches
Archiv 126 pp. 59-77.
Barrell, R.J. (1990a) 'European currency union and the
EMS', National Institute Economic Review no. 132 May.
Barrell, R.J. (1990b) Has the EMS changed wage and price behaviour
in Europe?' National Institute Economic Review no. 134 November.
Barrell R., A. Gurney and J.W. in't Veld (1992), The real
exchange rate, fiscal policy and the role of wealth: an analysis of
equilibrium in a monetary union', Journal of Forecasting,
forthcoming.
Barrell R., and J.W. in't Veld (1991), FEERS and the path to
EMU', National Institute Economic Review, no. 137.
Barro, R.J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1990), World real Interest
Rates,' National Bureau of Economic Research Macro-economics Annual
1990 pp. 15-74.
Chan-Lee, J.H., Coe, D.T., and Prywes, M.(1987) Macroeconomic
changes and Macroeconomic wage Disinflation in the 1980s', OECD
Economic Studies no. 8, Spring pp. 121-157.
Commission of the European Communities (1990), 'One market,
one money: an evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming
an economic and monetary union', European Economy, no. 44 October.
Commission of the European Communities, (1989), 'Economic
convergence in the Community: a greater effort is needed', European
Economy, no. 41.
Commission of the European Communities, (1990), Annual economic
report 1990-91', European Economy, no. 46, 1990.
Dornbusch, R. (1989), Credibility, Debt and Unemployment;
Ireland's failed stabilisation,' Economic Policy, no. 8
(April)
Dornbusch R. (1991),'Problem of European monetary
integration', in A. Giovannini and C. Mayer (eds): European
Financial Integration, Cambridge University Press.
Froot K.A. and Rogoff K. (1991), The EMS, the EMU, and the
transition to a common currency', NBER Working Paper no. 3684,
1991.
Kremers, J. (1990), Gaining policy credibility for a disinflation:
ireland's experience in the EMS', IMF Staff Papers, vol. 37,
no.1.
Layard, R., Nickell, S. and Jackman, R. (1991), Unemployment:
Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market, Oxford University
Press.
Mehta, F. and Sneesens, R. (1990), Belgian unemployment: the story
of a small open economy caught in a worldwide recession',
Europe's Unemployment Problem edited by Bean, L.R. and Dreze, J.H.
MIT Press.
Ungerer H., Evans, O., Mayer, T., Young, P. (1986), The European
Monetary System: recent developments', Occasional Paper 48,
international Monetary Fund, Washington D.C.
Ungerer H., Hauvonen, J.J., Lopez-Claros, A., Mayer, T.(1990), The
European Monetary System: developments and perspectives,'
Occasional Paper 73, International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C., 1990.
Weber, A. (1991), Reputation and credibility in the European
Monetary System', Economic Policy, no. 12 (April).
NOTES
(1) For other studies of convergence in Europe see Ungerer et
a/(1986,1990), European Economy (1989,1990), Froot & Rogoff (1991)
and AMEX Bank Review (1991).
(2) In Barrell, Gurney and in't Veld (1992) we demonstrate
that the process of real exchange-rate adjustment may be very protracted and the adjustment costs are unequally shared, which could cause severe
strains to be put on the union.
(3) The requirement for a debt/GDP ratio to stabilise at its
present level is p = (i-g).d where p is the primary balance, i the
nominal interest rate, g the nominal growth rate and d the desired or
present debt/GDP ratio. This simply states that the non-interest surplus
must be large enough to off set the increase in the debt/GDP ratio due
to interest payments on debt. This condition can be modified to allow
for taxation of interest payments on debt, valuation changes on existing
debt and money financed borrowing.
(4) Chan-Lee et al (1987) point out that the Netherlands
'reduced nominal minimum wages for workers under 23 by 10 per cent
in 1983'.
(5) See Mehta and Sneesens (1990) for further details.
(6) Weber (1991) makes it clear that the French austerity
programme really began in earnest after the March 1983 realignment of
the French Franc.
(7) Barrell (1990) gives details of the Scala Mobile and shows that
in 1983 the degree of wage indexation was reduced from 1 to 0.85.
However, he states that the most significant reforms of the italian
indexation mechanism occurred in 1985.
(8) The OECD report goes on to state that 'the level of wages
for both private and public sector services (in italy) has continued to
exceed that in the exposed sector, suggesting that both employers and
employees share the economic rent caused by the lack of competitive
pressure'.
(9) See Barrell and in't Veld (1991).
(10) For calculations of the required primary surplus for debt
sustainability for the ERM countries see European Economy: One Market,
One Money.
(11) Barro (1990) estimates reduced-form models for expected real
interest rates for ten OECD countries and generally finds fiscal
variables to be an unimportant determinant of real interest rates.
(12) Alogoskoufis et al (1990) provide a thorough examination of
external constraints for European economies.
(13) in contrast, the failure of Greece and Portugal to achieve
nominal convergence has been associated with relatively lower
unemployment rates.
(14) Opinions differ here as to the role of credibility. For
example, Dornbusch (1989) argues that irish inflation convergence was
attained via old fashioned deflationary policies with no extra
credibility effect, whereas Kremers (1990) argues that extra ERM
credibility may have decreased the unemployment cost of reducing
inflation in Ireland.
(15) The necessity for persistently high unemployment rates within
the ERM in order to reduce inflation is a controversial issue. For
example, in 1988 the long-term unemployed accounted for more than 60 per
cent of the unemployed in Belgium, Ireland, italy and Spain (see page 51
of Layard, Nickell and Jackman (1991)). As the long-term unemployed are
generally thought to contribute very little to the disinflationary
process, the inflation cost of re-employing them may be negligible.