The world economy.
Barrell, Ray ; Anderton, Bob ; Veld, Jan Willem in't 等
Recent developments and short-term prospects Business cycle
developments in the major seven economies have not been particularly
well synchronised in the last two years. The US, Canada and the UK have
been in recession, whilst Germany and Japan have been growing strongly.
We are predicting that this asynchronicity will continue over the next
eighteen months, with growth slowing in Japan and Germany whilst a mild
recovery takes place in the English speaking world. However there are
some signs that the recovery, at least in the US, is likely to be rather
slower than we had anticipated in our August forecast. The Federal
Reserve in the US has clearly been concerned about the most recent
signals from the American economy, and it encouraged a cut in interest
rates on 6th November. The Japanese authorities have also cut interest
rates in this quarter, and we anticipate that there will be no
substantial increases in German interest rates.
The rapid response of the US authorities is a major factor in the
construction of our forecast which is set out in table 1. Our forecast
for 1991 is based on three quarters of data for the US and two quarters
for each of the other major economies. It would appear that it will be
difficult for the US to avoid a year on year recession in 1991 with
growth of -0.2 per cent, although some recovery is underway. The first
half year has been strong in both Germany and Japan, but this in part
reflects some measurement difficulties which make the seasonally
adjusted first quarter data for these countries difficult to
interpret.(') However, we are expecting growth to slow sharply in
Japan and in the fourth quarter in Germany we expect that output will
only just regain its first quarter level. The quarterly output paths for
the 4 major economies are given in chart 1, which includes our forecast
up until the end of 1992.
Capacity utilisation rates have been falling in the major 4
economies. The US reached its peak in 1989, and as chart 2 shows, the
index has declined 10 per cent in the last two years. French capacity
utilisation peaked rather later, but as with the US its peak can be seen
as a clear cyclical turning point. The German and Japanese indicators
reached their peak more recently, and in both cases the interpretation
of the signs has been harder. Investment growth in Japan averaged almost
15 per cent a year from 1988 to 1990, and this has inevitably raised the
capacity ceiling. German business investment growth has also been
strong, and it will probably average over 9 per cent a year over the
period 1989-91.
The slowdown in activity in 1991 has not been confined to the major
three economies. Growth in France is predicted to be in the range 1 to 1
1/2 per cent this year, and our forecast for Italy suggests that growth
there could fall below 1 per cent. Growth in the UK and Canada is likely
to be negative in 1991. As a result of these widespread developments we
are expecting growth in the major seven to slow down from 3.2 per cent
in 1989 and 2.4 per cent in 1990 to only 11 per cent in 1991. We do
expect some recovery of growth into 1992, and output in the major-seven
is expected to grow by 2.2 per cent, whilst in the major four it will
grow by 2.3 per cent. Both are below the average growth rate experienced
over the period 1982 to 1987, indicating the slow pace of the
anticipated recovery. Growth in most of the major economies is expected
to be stronger in 1993 and 1994.
Our current forecast of growth for 1992 is more pessimistic than
that published in our August Review. We have revised down our projection
for major seven growth by over 1/2 a per cent. A longer.. although
shallow, period of below capacity output has led us to revise down our
inflation forecast for both 1991 and 1992. Chart 3 plots recent
inflation rates in the major four economies. These appear to have passed
their cyclical peaks in the US and France (and less clearly so in
Japan), but tax changes introduced in Germany in July have kept the
inflation rate high in that country. We are forecasting an inflation
rate of around 3 per cent a year in the major 4 economies in 1992 and
1993. The major seven also includes some of the more inflation prone
countries, and the average rate in this larger group will fall to around
3 1/2 per cent a year.
The slowdown in output growth is reflected in the other aggregate
statistics in table 1. OECD industrial production is inevitably
considerably more cyclical in its behaviour than is total output and we
are expecting a fall in industrial production in 1991 followed by a
rather more rapid recovery than that displayed by total output. World
trade growth, however measured, is also more cyclical than output. World
trade in manufactures (as measured by OECD exports at least) grew at
around 9 per cent a year in 1988 and 1989, whilst total trade of market
economies grew by more than 8 per cent a year over this period. We are
expecting manufacturing trade growth to slow to around 2 1/2 per cent in
1991, and to recover only slowly thereafter. Total world trade growth as
measured by the UN index of exports and imports of all market economies
is likely to grow slightly more rapidly. These indices are not
consistent with that now published by the IMF. The September World
Economic Outlook forecast total world trade growth of only 1 per cent in
1991. The new IMF index now contains intra-eastern bloc trade, and the
disbandment of COMECON and the collapse of planned trade flows has
distorted the IMF measures considerably.
We expect world trade growth to recover only slowly. This in part
reflects the sluggish nature of the upturn in output, but also reflects
developments outside the OECD. We estimate that the imports of the
formerly centrally planned economies fell in 1990 and early 1991, and
will rise slowly over the next two years. This growth in part reflects
the opening up of the smaller eastern European economies, and also
depends upon an increase in grain deliveries to the former USSR. In the
longer term we anticipate that the former centrally planned economies
will be major recipients of capital, and this will allow their imports
to grow more rapidly than their exports. We are forecasting import
growth rates of over 10 per cent a year from 1993 onwards. However, this
cannot be seen as a major support for world trade growth in the next
five years. Developments elsewhere are more important. OPEC imports also
appear to have been low in 1990 and 1991, in part because of the
disruption caused by the Gulf war. The only strong source of trade
growth outside the OECD appears to be the Far East. Both China and the
rest of the Pacific Rim have been growing rapidly in recent years, and
import growth has been strong at around 10 per cent a year. We expect
that this rate of growth will continue, and that this will help world
trade growth to recover.
Export-led recovery has been predicted for most of the European
economies. However, these predictions (2) are difficult to reconcile
with the forecasts produced using large scale multicountry models such
as NIGEM. It is possible that Europe could experience such a recovery,
but this seems rather unlikely in the current conjuncture. Import growth
in 1992 is likely to be weak in North America and Japan, and European
trade with the Pacific Rim is limited. An export led recovery could also
be generated if the European economies were either gaining world trade
share because of increased competitiveness or because they have a
tendency to gain share in the long run. The former source of growth is
unlikely to be available, whilst research at the National Institute,
reported in Box A, suggests that amongst the major seven the UK,
Germany, Italy and Canada are the only countries that have ever had a
tendency to autonomously gain world trade share. interest rates and
exchange rates Interest rates have been easing in recent months,
especially in the US and Japan. Chart 4 plots recent 3 month rates on a
weekly basis for the last year, and the recent reduction in the US is
particularly noticeable. A wide gap has opened up between rates in the
US and in Germany. This in part reflects the policy worries of the
authorities, but it also indicates the scale of the increase in the
demand for capital in Germany that has emanated from unification with
the former GDR. The authorities in the US have been concerned with
failing output, whilst those in Germany have been worried about rising
inflation. German rates have therefore risen. As table 2 shows, rates in
France (and in the rest of the 'hard' EMS countries) have
risen in line with those in Germany. We are forecasting that French (and
Belgian) interest rates will be the same as those in Germany by the
second quarter of next year. This strong coupling of interest rates,
which is discussed in Anderton, Barrell and in't Veld in this
Review, now extends to the Netherlands, Austria and Denmark. It results
from the commitment of these countries to a fixed parity with the D-Mark
and to a potential monetary union in Europe. It does however make the
German authorities' task more difficult.
Our model suggests that the deflationary impact of this rise in
interest rates will come through two channels, directly through demand
and indirectly through the exchange rate First it will reduce domestic
demand directly. Consumption may fall, as might housing investment. If
long rates rise then business investment would fall. All these channels
are present on NIGEM, but they are rather weak for Germany. A rise in
nominal short-term interest rates accompanied by a rise in long rates
would cause bond prices and equity markets to be lower than they
otherwise would have been, and this would reduce net financial wealth.
This in turn would reduce consumption. Once again these channels are
present on NIGEM, but as Barrell, Gurney and in't Veld (1991)
demonstrate they are weak in Germany. This would suggest that in order
to produce a given fall in inflation the German economy requires a
larger rise in interest rates than its European partners.
If the D-Mark were not tied into the Exchange Rate Mechanism then a
rise in interest rates would be expected to cause the currency to
appreciate. This would directly reduce inflation through its effects on
import prices and indirectly reduce it through the effects on aggregate
demand of lower exports and higher imports. The ERM prevents the D-Mark
floating up against its close trading partners because interest rates
have become strongly coupled. Although, as chart 6 shows, the D-Mark has
appreciated over the last two years it is now 5 per cent above the level
achieved in mid 1989.
The combination of a hard ERM and high German interest rates has
been a major factor behind the slowdown in Europe. We argued in the
February 1991 Review that the effects of the high level of German
interest rates more than outweighed the effects of unification which led
to strong demand for exports throughout Europe. Our conclusions were
that tighter German monetary policy in the last year has reduced growth
in the rest of Europe by almost a full per cent, whilst the demand
stemming from unification raised it by only 1/4 of a per cent.
The exigencies of the current ERM regime do, however, bring
benefits for its members. if, as we anticipate, the Maastricht summit in
early December 1991 produces a plan for monetary union, then in most
European countries the prospects for inflation will improve. Our medium
term forecast for exchange rates, which is set out in table 2, is
predicated on a belief that exchange rates will become irrevocably fixed
within a few years. We still believe that the italian authorities will
be forced into one more realignment before 1995, but thereafter exchange
rates will be fixed. By 1997 a monetary union with a common currency is
assumed to be in place. This assumption in turn has implications for our
forecast of long-term interest rates. In a monetary union (or indeed in
any fixed exchange-rate system without capital controls) the rate of
interest, net of individual specific risk premia, must be the same
everywhere. Hence long rates must be the same everywhere in Europe.
Convergence of long rates has to proceed more rapidly than that of short
rates. Long rates are the forward looking weighted average of expected
future short rates (plus a liquidity premium). Hence if short rates are
expected to converge monotonically then long rates should be seen to
converge. As Anderton, Barrell and in't Veld in this Review
demonstrate, long rates have not yet converged in Europe. The difference
between 5 year and 10 year long rates of interest currently indicate the
expected short rate differentials between 1996 and 2001. Short rates are
expected to be the same over this period in Germany, France, Belgium,
the Netherlands, Denmark, Austria and even in ireland, whilst it is not
currently clear that this is the case for the other ERM members. Our
forecast in this instance departs from that of the average market
participant in that we believe the Italian and UK short rates will have
converged by the end of the century, and hence these countries will for
some time benefit from lower long rates than the markets currently
predict.
Long-term interest rates contain a great deal of information about
the future, and the rise in long rates in the last quarter of 1989 is
particularly significant in the analysis of the evolution of real
interest rates. The ramifications of the collapse of the centrally
planned economies are still being digested, but by the 9th of November
1989 (when the Berlin Wall fell) it was clear that in the longer term
large scale capital flows would be required in order to enhance the
process of redevelopment in the east. The timing of these flows remains
uncertain, but we have estimated (National Institute Economic Review no.
137 pp. 40-41) that the scale of flows required will only be forthcoming
it real interest rates in the rest of the world rise by around 1/2a per
cent. This will reduce investment and consumption in the advanced world.
This is necessary if the level of saving transfer required is to be
forthcoming. Long-term interest rates are very forward looking, and we
judge that they already embody the interest-rate increases that will be
required. The implications of this 'jump' in long interest
rates is only slowly being taken into account, and we believe that it is
a significant factor behind the slowdown in the advanced economies.
Although in the long run they will benefit from the expansion of
activity and markets, in the short run the higher cost of capital causes
some temporary disjunction throughout the world economy.
Our exchange-rate forecast is, as usual based on the assumption
that the nominal exchange rate will follow the open arbitrage path. We
are expecting interest rates (and inflation) to be lower in Europe in
the 1990s than they are likely to be in North America. As a result the
dollar is expected to depreciate in nominal terms over the next decade.
In Barrell and in't Veld (1991) we calculated that the dollar was
currently near its real equilibrium level, and we do not foresee any
major real realignments between Europe and North America over the next
10 years.
Oil Markets and Commodity Prices
The price of crude oil has risen from its summer low of $17 per
barrel to around $21 to $22 per barrel, and forward markets suggest that
this level of prices will be maintained throughout 1992. Given the
slowdown in world activity it is a little difficult to interpret this
rise in prices. There appear to be two major factors behind the strength
of prices, both of which are increasing stockbuilding. First, the OPEC
producers, apart from Kuwait and iraq, are producing to full capacity,
and second, there are considerable worries about the continued flow of
oil and gas exports from the former USSR.
Preliminary estimates suggest that OPEC oil production reached 24.7
million barrels a day in September. This is well above the level of 24.3
million barrels per day achieved in the first half of 1990, despite the
loss of Kuwaiti and Iraqi output. The Saudis have increased their output
from 5.6 million barrels per day in the first half of 1990 to around 8.5
million barrels per day in the third quarter of 1991. This brings their
production up to their estimated sustainable capacity output. High
levels of capacity use are also seen in Iran, the Emirates and
Venezuela, and no OPEC country appears to be producing below capacity.
As a result market participants may feel that stocks in the OECD need to
be built up to replace the usual margin of spare capacity that would
have acted as a substitute for holding stocks.
Production in the USSR has fallen from its 1987/88 peak of 12.5
million barrels per day to an estimated 10.5 million barrels per day in
the third quarter of 1991. This output fall, and increasing transport
and distribution difficulties, have led to fears that exports will be
significantly curtailed. Soviet exports of oil and products fell in 1990
to 85 per cent of their 1988 level, but evidence for the first quarter
of 1991 suggests that exports have stabilised. After the disintegration of the Union it is not clear that exports can be maintained at 1.6
million barrels per day throughout 1992, and commercial stocks in the
OECD are being built up in anticipation of the short-fall.
Our forecast is in line with forward markets and we expect prices
to stay high into 1993. By then the world economy should be recovering,
and demand will be rising, and this will help absorb Kuwaiti and Iraqi
output. We therefore expect real oil prices to stay firm, and to rise
from around 1993 by 2 to 3 per cent a year. Table 4 contains our oil
price forecast.
Other commodity prices have been weak during 1991. Our indices are
plotted in Chart 7 and longer-term real prices are in Chart 8 and our
forecast is set out in table 4. Metal prices have been generally weak,
partly because the USSR is expected to increase its exports of high
value metals such as nickel and zinc in order to obtain hard currency.
Although tungsten dumping by the Chinese has been somewhat curtailed in
the last year prices are still weak. Forward markets indicate that
prices are generally expected to continue to fall over the next year.
The major exception is in the copper market, where stocks are low and
strikes have curtailed output. Agricultural raw materials prices have
also been falling, in part because Australia, New Zealand and South
Africa have all recently abolished price support schemes for wool.
Food prices have generally been weak, but in recent months wheat
prices have picked up sharply, and they are expected to rise sharply up
to the next harvest. This is in part due to the expected scale of
deliveries to the USSR, but it also reflects the expected reduction of
40 million tonnes in world output in 1991/92. The majority of the
shortfall comes from the US where output reduction schemes have been
particularly successful. Sugar and coffee prices have been weak in 1991,
with non-cane production of sugar rising. in general none of the food
commodity markets are expecting an upturn in demand, and forward markets
suggest that prices will continue to decline.
Longer-term prospects and convergence in Europe
We are presuming that a European Monetary Union will be formed
sometime around 1997 to include all Member States except Greece,
Portugal and Spain. The drafts to the Maastricht Summit agreement
define, very precisely, what convergence criteria must be met for this
to happen. In advance of the Summit meeting however, we do not know
exactly how the criteria will be set. We can however, reasonably claim
that monetary union will only take place if the following broad
guidelines are met. There are four essential parts to the analysis of
nominal convergence in Europe. First interest rates must converge,
second inflation rates (and price levels) must achieve some sort of
long-term relationship. This long-term relationship is only likely to be
possible if, thirdly, fiscal deficits are kept within bounds, and
fourthly if the costs of convergence in terms of unemployment are not
excessive. The degree of convergence achieved so far is discussed in
Anderton, Barrell and in't Veld in this Review.
Our forecast of the medium term assumes that governments in the
Community are serious about their long-term commitment to union. We are
assuming that interest rates in Europe converge by 1997. This alone will
produce some degree of inflation convergence as the resulting system of
fixed exchange rates will put pressure on wages and prices in the traded
goods sector of the inflation prone economies. Chart 9 plots our
projections for inflation in the major four economies. We are
anticipating that UK and French inflation will be consistently below
that in Germany over the next decade.
in Barrell and in't Veld (1991) we argued that the D-Mark was
undervalued, and that this problem could only be ameliorated either by a
revaluation or by faster inflation in Germany than in its partners. We
believe that the second path is the more likely. The effects of German
unification have loosened the German fiscal stance and have raised the
rate of inflation in the Federal Republic. We expect that inflation will
remain moderate in Germany, but that lower rates will be achieved in
France and the UK. This is in part the effect of the initial small
misalignment of the ERM system. if France and the UK are overvalued then
exports will be lower than they otherwise would have been, imports will
be higher, and the resulting balance of payments deficit will be causing
real wealth to drop increasingly far below its equilibrium trajectory.
This will put downward pressure on demand in the overvalued countries,
even if the deficit is easily financible. Chart 10 plots our projections
for the balance of payments of the four largest ERM members over the
next decade. The pattern of deficits does not appear to be a potential
source of stress in the Community.
The convergence of inflation will inevitably mean a gradual change
in fiscal stance in some Community countries. The current version of
NIGEM contains wealth effects in consumption, a full set of capital
accounts and a set of public sector models for the major economies. This
allows us to forecast public sector deficits in Europe over the next
decade. Chart 1 1 plots the deficits in the major 4 economies. The
public sector deficit in France is not currently excessive, and we
expect consolidation to continue. Both the UK and West Germany have
suffered recent deteriorations in their public sector balances and both
might fail the Maastricht test next year. The deterioration in the UK is
largely the result of the sudden downturn in activity, whilst that in
Germany is the result of the costs of unification. Both countries can be
expected to reduce their deficits in the medium term.
The italian situation is somewhat different. We are assuming that
the process of fiscal consolidation that has been underway since 1985
will continue. As a result the italian deficit including interest
payments (as a per cent of GDP) will fall from the current level of 9.5
per cent, and from its peak of 14 per cent in 1985, to the more
manageable level of 2 per cent by 1999. This is a brave assumption,
because we believe that this will only be possible if direct taxes are
progressively raised. However the authorities are committed to reducing
the deficit. In this forecast we are assuming that both public
absorption of resources and public transfers will fall by 1 1/2 per cent
of GDP each whilst direct tax revenue rises from 25 1/2 per cent of
personal income in 1990 to 27 in 1999.
Chart 12 plots our forecast of unemployment in Europe, and in some
countries it stays stubbornly high throughout the decade. These
economies may eventually return to full employment but the transition
costs are not negligible. The italian authorities believe that low
inflation is a prize worth gaining, and high unemployment is a price
worth paying. Our model, NIGEM, now has a complete model of the Italian
personal and public sectors, and this allows us to quantify the effects.
We have undertaken a simulation of our model where we do not tighten
fiscal policy. This would make union impossible, and inflation and
interest rates would have to be higher. A looser fiscal stance in italy
would over the medium term raise growth by 1/2 of a per cent a year,
inflation would be 1 per cent higher and unemployment would be slightly
lower. In the long run, however, we believe that the real equilibrium of
the economy may be little affected.
The United States
The US recession appears to have ended in the third quarter of
1991, but the signals on the strength of the recovery are very mixed.
Real GNP grew at an annual rate of almost 2 1/2 per cent in the third
quarter, after three successive quarters of decline. Consumer spending has been rising for two quarters, and it is estimated to be 3 per cent
above the level of the first quarter. Durables expenditure was
particularly strong in the third quarter, with motor vehicle sales in
the quarter rising for the first time in a year. Investment also rose
strongly, the first increase for two years, and residential investment
was 5 per cent above the level of the previous quarter but still 7 1/2
per cent below the level of 1990Q3. Business investment was 1.6 per cent
above the level of the first quarter but remained 2 1/2 per cent below
its level in 1990Q3.
imports of goods and non factor services continued to rise
strongly, whilst exports were weak. Domestic demand grew by over 1 per
cent in the third quarter, but the combination of a declining balance in
goods and services and the effect of the appreciation of the dollar on
the value of net property income from abroad produced GNP growth of only
0*6 per cent in the quarter. The dollar has appreciated some 10 per cent
in the last year and the effects on trade have begun to become apparent.
The durability of the recovery will., it appears depend to a large
extent on the strength of consumers expenditure. This increases the
significance of the sharp drop in consumer confidence in October. The
Conference Board of New York index has been falling for four months, and
in November it had almost dropped to its Gulf War level. Consumer credit
outstanding has also been falling since at least May. it appears that
the prospects for increased consumption expenditure are not good, and
other indicators point to a slow recovery. The index of leading
indicators fell in September, and had been flat for the two previous
months. Private housing starts also fell in the same month and are 6 1/2
per cent below the level of a year ago. The unemployment rate rose in
October, reflecting in part the lack of any increase in industrial
production and manufacturing employment dropped 32,000 in the same
month. Capacity utilisation eased down a little in September, although
it is still above the cyclical trough achieved in March 1991. The widely
quoted National Association of Purchase Managers Index also fell in
October and it is just above its 9 year low point.
All the signs are that the recovery is faltering and the Federal
Reserve has reacted promptly. The discount rate was cut by 1/2 a per
cent to 4 1/2 per cent on the 6th of November. Commercial Banks cut
their prime rates at the same time. This response also reflects worries
about the slow growth of the broader monetary aggregates in recent
months. We believe that the response of the Federal Reserve should be
sufficient to stave off a second recession, but we have incorporated
some of the recent pessimism into our forecast judgments. Chart 13 plots
the residuals on our consumption, business investment and housing
investment equations. In each case we set the value of the residual over
the medium term approximately equal to its historical value, but in the
short term we believe outturns will be worse than an equation based
prediction would suggest.
Output in the US grew by 21/2 per cent in 1989, well below its peak
in 1988, and the slowdown continued into 1991. We are expecting this
slowdown to be reversed. Our forecast for US GNP and its components is
set out on table 5. We expect output to grow by 21/4 per cent in 1992,
largely driven by domestic demand. We expect growth in both housing and
business investment. Short interest rates are expected to stay around 5
per cent for much of 1992 and should rise only slowly there after and
long rates can be expected to fall if our short rate predictions are
correct. A lower long rate should raise the value of net financial
wealth and hence stimulate consumption indirectly as well as having a
direct effect on business investment. Lower short rates should help to
raise demand in housing markets.
Our short-term interest-rate forecast reflects our view on
inflation. The consumers expenditure deflator rose by less than 1 per
cent in the third quarter. This is well below its peak rate increase in
1990, and below the 5 per cent increase in 1990 as a whole. We are
expecting the inflation outturn for 1991 to be below 4 per cent. This
reflects weak wholesale prices, a strong dollar, and the rather limited
growth in the pressure of demand. We are forecasting that inflation will
fall further in 1992, and interest rates will be held low. Given the
slow speed of response of output to interest rates we do not expect
strong growth next year, although the average from 1992 and 1993 is very
close to our estimate of long-term output potential growth.
Our forecast for the US current balance and for trade is set out in
table 6. The US current balance deficit is likely to be only around $15
billion in 1991. This reflects in part the large scale of transfers to
the US from Germany, Japan and the Saudis. These transfers are a payment
for the Gulf War and probably exceed $35 billion dollars. Although, as
Keynes stressed in the 1920s, transfers on this scale are always hard to
make effective, the openness of capital markets and the lack of exchange
controls should mean that there is little effect on the exchange rate.
Net property income from abroad has also been strong in 1991, and we
have projected part of this increase in our forecast of the rate of
return on assets. This should help sustain the US current account. We
are forecasting that the IPD balance will remain positive until 1994,
and then cumulating current account deficits will push it into deficit
itself. The improvement in the current account is expected to be
sustained, and we do not expect the overall deficit to return to its mid
80s levels. The slow recovery from recession will keep the deficit below
1 1/2 per cent of GNP until at least 1994, and we do not expect it to
rise above 1*8 per cent in the foreseeable future. This level of deficit
is, we would judge, financible.
Our public sector forecast is given in table 7. Our forecast for
the deficit uses our model of the US public sector, and our equations
are based on data from the National Income and Product Accounts. The
forecast deficit therefore excludes any temporary or permanent
additional borrowing directly necessitated by the collapse of the
Savings and Loans Institution.
We expect that the Federal and total Public Sector deficit on an
NIPA basis will expand in 1992 to $188 billion and $175 billion
respectively. The public sector deficit will reach 2.9 per cent of GNP
in 1992, its highest level since 1986. However during a recession some
deterioration in the balance, and especially the balances of states and
local authorities, can be expected. We expect the slow reaping of the
peace dividend to reduce the level of spending over the medium term, and
by 1997 we are expecting the public sector deficit to drop below 1 per
cent of GNP.
Japan
Forecasts of output growth over the last 4 years in Japan have
generally been lower than the eventual outcome. (3) We have had to
slightly revise up our forecast for 1991 in the light of the albeit weak
second quarter data, but we have revised down our forecast for 1992, in
part because we are expecting a less favourable external environment but
mainly because domestic prospects appear to have deteriorated. The
Japanese authorities have been worried about rising inflation, and
interest rates have been progressively raised. High short and long rates
appear to be affecting both consumption and investment.
Real GNP rose 1/2 a per cent in the second quarter, and in the
first half of 1991 it was 5 1/2 per cent higher than in the same period
a year previously. Housing investment has been the weakest component of
domestic demand and in the second quarter it was over 10 per cent below
the peak it reached in the third quarter of 1990. Business investment
was also lower in the second quarter than in the first, but it has been
very strong recently. We are expecting GNP growth to slow in 1991 to
just over 4 per cent. This will largely be driven by domestic demand
which is forecast to grow at only 3 1/2 per cent in 1991.
Current indicators suggest that the prospects for 1992 are not
good, and although we expect the Japanese economy to avoid a recession
(by Japanese definitions this means growth below 2 per cent) we are
expecting the lowest growth in GNP since the early 1980s. This forecast
of 2 1/2 per cent growth follows largely from an automatic setting of
residuals at their historical averages, and it reflects the large but
slow acting effect of high interest rates on the Japanese economy.
However, the forecast is supported by short term indicators. The index
of leading indicators fell in August to its lowest level for 15 years,
and has been below 50 for twelve months. Capital expenditure is expected
to slow sharply, partly in response to high interest rates and the
slowdown in activity, but also because equity financing has become more
difficult since the fall in the stockmarket in 1990 and because BIS
reserve ratio rules on banks has limited their capacity to lend. The
generally reliable Bank of Japan survey in August suggested capital
spending would rise 8 per cent in the current fiscal year compared to 17
per cent in fiscal 1990/91. Intentions are particularly low in small and
medium size firms.
Our forecast for output prices in the Japanese economy is given in
table 8. We have seen a small reduction in interest rates this year, and
we expect furtherfalls into 1992. We therefore expect some sort of
recovery in housing investment but this will be mild, and it will not be
sufficient to offset the projected decline in investment growth.
Stockbuilding was high in the second quarter of 1991, but we expect that
the unplanned component of stocks will be reduced in the near future,
and as a result the growth of domestic demand is expected to be reduced.
In the longer term we expect growth to increase to around 3 1/2 per cent
in 1993 and to just above 4 per cent thereafter. We expect that the
recovery will be generated by lower interest rates and by a faster rate
of growth of public spending. As far as we can ascertain the Japanese
public sector as a whole has been running a surplus for some time, and
taxes on business are being increased to pay for the Japanese
contribution to the Gulf War. However, in the longer term we expect the
budget surplus to decline slowly.
The tight fiscal and monetary stance has reflected fears about
rising inflation. The consumers expenditure deflator was flat in 1987
and 1988, and then rose increasingly rapidly to a forecast peak of 2.7
per cent in 1991. Consumer price inflation has been higher, and the
index is likely to have risen by 3.3 per cent in 1991. These figures are
high by Japanese standards and in combination with a tight labour market
they were seen as seriously worrying. However, labour market pressures
have begun to ease, and unemployment rose to 2.2 per cent in September
from its low point of 2 per cent in May. Employment has fallen below its
peak of 64.8 million in June, and the ratio of unfilled vacancies to job
seekers has fallen from its 16 year peak of 1.47 to around 1.34. The
prospects for inflation look better. Wholesale prices fell in September,
as did import prices. However these falls have in part been the result
of the strength of the Yen, and this in turn has added to the
deflationary pressure on demand. We are forecasting that wholesale
prices will rise by 2.3 per cent in 1991 and by less than 1 per cent in
1992. Consumer price inflation will slow to 2 1/2 per cent and the CED is expected to increase by less. The short, sharp slowdown will have
successfully reduced the rate of inflation.
The slowdown in activity will contribute to a notable improvement
in the current account in 1991. This in part also reflects a J curve
effect from the real appreciation of the Yen that took place between the
second and fourth quarters of 1990, and it is despite the scale of
transfers to the US. The current account is expected to show a surplus
of $65 billion in 1991 despite the fact that export volumes are expected
to fall and import volumes are expected to rise. The improvement in the
surplus is expected to be largely sustained as the real exchange rate is
forecast to stabilise at around its current level. The continuing
pressure to open up the economy will, we expect, produce faster growth
of imports than exports, and especially of imports of services. This
will cause the surplus to stabilise, but the cumulating stock of
overseas assets and the resulting income flow will impede the fall in
the current account as a per cent of GNP.
Work reported in Box A in this chapter and in the World Economy
Chapter of the August 1990 Review suggests that the nature of Japanese
trade has changed. Up until the mid 1980s the Japanese appear to have
been gaining world trade share at constant competitiveness. Since then
they have not been doing so. Import demand, both for goods and for
services appears to have changed structure in the late 1980s producing a
more rapid growth in import penetration. These long run trends are
likely to reduce the Japanese current account surplus to around 1 per
cent of GNP in 1990. This does not mean that Japanese firms are losing
market share, but rather that they have been moving their plant to low
cost locations around the Pacific Rim and also into areas such as the
European Community in order to avoid tariff and non tariff barriers to
trade.
Germany
The process of unification has given a strong boost to growth in
Germany. The 1980s were a period of low growth and low inflation in the
Federal Republic. Domestic profitability was low and the government ran
only small deficits. As a result saving flowed abroad and the current
account was in persistent surplus. Germany shared in the world upswing in 1988, and GNP growth rose to 3 1/2 per cent. However much of the
upswing was externally generated, and the balance of payments improved
to a surplus of 4.2 per cent of GNP. Growth accelerated to 3.8 per cent
in 1989 despite a slow down in domestic demand. The current account
surplus improved to 4.8 per cent of GNP.
The shock of unification began in 1990, and it produced a surge in
domestically generated growth. The current account deteriorated to 3-2
per cent of GNP and domestic demand rose by 5.2 per cent, whilst GNP
grew by 4.7 per cent. This marked change in the mainspring of German
growth was accompanied by a sharp deterioration in the public sector
accounts. The complete public sector displayed a small surplus in 1989,
but this deteriorated to a deficit of 3.5 per cent of GNP in 1990. Most
of this deficit occurred in the second half of 1990, and it was driven
by large transfers to the East. Domestic investment also grew very
strongly in 1989 and 1990. As a result of the increase in demand
generated by unification the German economy was operating near its
capacity ceiling, and investment grew in part to relieve the pressure of
capacity shortage.
Inevitably the domestically generated growth began to put pressure
on prices in Germany and inflation started to accelerate, and the
Bundesbank began to become concerned about inflation. interest rates
rose from 4.25 per cent in 1988 to 7.1 per cent in 1989, and they
continued to rise throughout 1990. By the end of the year interest rates
had risen to 8.8 per cent, and ex post real interest rates were 6.2 per
cent. These high interest rates were a reflection of worries about
emerging inflation, rather than a response to high inflation. Rates rose
further through 1991 to peak at around 9 1/2 per cent in the fourth
quarter. The rate of inflation has risen in 1991, but this in part
reflects the increase in indirect taxation that took place in July. Wage
increases were seen as more worrying. Economy wide compensation per head
rose by 3.2 per cent in 1989, by 4.7 per cent in 1990 and are expected
to rise by 6.6 per cent in 1991. Manufacturing earnings growth has also
accelerated from 3.8 per cent in 1989 to an anticipated 5 per cent in
1991.
The Bundesbank's increasingly tight monetary policy had been
having very little effect until the last six months. Fiscal expansion
was in part offsetting the effects of high interest rates and as we have
noted above the German economy anyway responds rather weakly to high
rates. However, the Ketchup appears to have just come out of the bottle
(4) and after a very strong set of first quarter GNP figures we are
expecting GNP to fall in the third quarter and only return to its first
quarter level in the last quarter of the year.
There have been a number of signs of this slowdown. Industrial
production fell in every month between June and September. Export volume
growth has been very low. Unfilled vacancies have fallen from a peak of
344,000 in May to 320,000 in October. Capacity utilisation in
manufacturing fell to 87.9 per cent in the second quarter. Although this
is still relatively high, it is below the peak level of 90 per cent
recorded in the fourth quarter of 1990. Business surveys by IFO suggests
that order books are expected to shorten, and business confidence
surveys undertaken by regional Chambers of Commerce indicate a marked
weakening.
it is very difficult to interpret the second quarter data because a
marked seasonal pattern appears to have crept into the Bundesbank's
seasonally adjusted data. German research institutes, such as DIW and IW
Kiel, seasonally adjust the raw data themselves. The Kiel interpretation
of the second quarter data suggests that consumption growth slowed to
around 2 1/2 per cent at an annual rate, and he growth of investment in
equipment slowed to 2 per cent at an annual rate. Only construction
continued to grow strongly in the second quarter. Their adjusted data
has GNP rising by 3 1/2 per cent at an annual rate in the second
quarter, whereas the Bundesbank adjusted data shows a fall.
The interpretation of recent data is difficult but it is clear that
the economy of western Germany is slowing down rapidly. Table 10
contains our forecast for national income. We are expecting growth to
slow to 3.3 per cent in 1991 and to 2.3 per cent in 1992. Much of this
slowdown is generated by a sharp slowdown in business investment growth.
This is in part a response to high interest rates, but it also reflects
the high short term elasticity of investment with respect to output. Our
equation residual has been set below its historical average to reflect
poor confidence, and our slowdown in Germany is not entirely generated
by our model.
The slowdown in activity will, we believe, inhibit the Bundesbank
from raising interest rates further, and as is shown in table 3, we
expect them to be putting downward pressure on German interest rates
from the middle of next year. in the medium term we expect growth to
pick up again in Germany as output and demand grow in the east, and we
are forecasting GNP growth in excess of 3 per cent in 1993 and for
several years thereafter. This strong growth is forecast to be
accompanied by stable inflation of around 3 1/2 per cent a year. This
may seem high given the Bundesbank predilections, but it is only the
German average for the last 20 years, and it should ease the transition
to monetary union in Europe.
The German balance of payments deteriorated sharply in 1991, and we
are forecasting a deficit of $21 billion, or 1 1/2 per cent of GNP. This
reflects in part the Gulf War transfers to the US, but it was mainly
caused by the extremely rapid growth of imports. Our forecast of the
German balance of payments is given in table 11. Our trade volume data
is still based on west German national accounts, but the overall balance
is based on all Germany data. The inconsistencies now mainly show up
through the invisibles, and we have made some allowance for this in our
forecast. The recovery in the east (discussed in Box B) should limit the
growth of imports in the medium term, and we are expecting the slowdown
in activity to produce a return to current account surplus by 1994.
Increasing export profitability is likely to help maintain export
growth, and the process of monetary union through exchange rate
discipline should help restore some of the German current surpluses
observed in the 1980s. Our long term forecast for the German current
account is given in chart 10 above.
Monetary union in Europe will require a tightening of fiscal
policy, but we believe that developments in the east, along with the
announced higher taxes in 1993 would enable the Germans to meet the
draft Maastricht rules with ease. Table 12 contains our model based
German public sector forecast. Transfers to the east are mainly
encompassed by miscellaneous expenditures. These rose from 140 billion
D-Mark in 1989 to 368 billion D-Mark in 1991. They are forecast to
stabilise at this level, and hence the normal effects of nominal and
real GNP growth on revenue, plus the announced rise in indirect taxes in
1993, should be sufficient to reduce the public sector deficit to 1.3
per cent of GNP in 1999.
France
Output growth in France has reflected the pattern in the rest of
Europe. Growth accelerated from 2*3 per cent in 1987 to 4.2 per cent in
1988, with much of the stimulus coming from external demand. Growth was
also strong in 1989, and it slowed a little into 1990 as net exports
grew less rapidly. The commitment to the ERM has meant that short
interest rates rose in line with those in Germany from 7.9 per cent to
10.6 per cent in the first quarter of 1990. The rise was an important
factor behind the slowdown in activity in 1990. High interest rates
caused the ERM block to appreciate against the dollar, and the
subsequent loss of competitiveness exacerbated the slowdown.
The reduction in growth in 1991 is not expected to be as severe as
that seen in either the UK or in italy. French inflation has been around
2 1/2 to 3 1/2 per cent for some years, and unit labour cost increases
have been moderate. This has meant that the effects of the real
appreciation of the ERM block have been ameliorated somewhat. French
inflation has indeed fallen below that in Germany recently, as can be
seen from Chart 9, and this has been one of the factors that have
allowed the French authorities to cut their interest rates from 10.6 in
the first quarter of 1990 to 9.6 in the second quarter of 1991. We
expect that they will rise slightly in the fourth quarter and then
converge on German rates in early 1992. The reduction of interest rate
pressure has aided the economy, and it has reduced the severity of the
slowdown.
The increase in credibility and the resultant fall in interest
rates has not prevented a slowdown in activity, rather it has just
ameliorated it. GDP in the first quarter was at the same level as in the
third quarter of 1990. Real GDP rose by almost a per cent in the second
quarter. Consumer spending remained weak, but net exports and investment
recovered somewhat. The recovery in investment was largely in
construction and this sector has been aided by lower interest rates.
Industrial production rose by 0*8 per cent in July/August, but was still
0*9 per cent lower than a year ago. Manufacturing production also rose,
but was 2.7 per cent lower than a year previously. There are signs that
a recovery is under way, but it is unlikely to be strong. Unemployment
generally lags behind output during the cycle. It rose to 9.5 per cent
in August, up from 8.9 per cent at the beginning of the year. We are
expecting unemployment to stabilise at around 9.6 per cent in 1992 and
1993.
The May INSEE investment intentions survey saw firms revising their
plans down by 7 per cent in value (and 6 per cent in volume terms).
Capacity utilisation dropped in the third quarter to its lowest level
since the end of 1987, and it is 5 per cent below its peak in the second
quarter of 1990. These factors reinforce our forecast of virtually flat
investment in 1991, with a small rise in construction offset by a small
fall in business investment. We do, however, expect output to recover in
the third and fourth quarters. This view is supported by the INSEE
October survey of activity which suggested a rise in activity in the
third quarter of the year.
Inflation has been below 4 per cent for around five years. It rose
a little toward the end of 1990 and in the second quarter of 1991
consumer prices were 3.3 per cent higher than a year previously. High
interest rates and a decline in output growth have produced a degree of
spare capacity, and inflation is now falling. We expect consumer prices
to rise by 3 per cent in both 1991 and 1992. Manufacturing earnings grew
by 4 1/2 per cent in 1990, but rising unemployment will help put
pressure on wages, and we are expecting increases of no more than 4 per
cent this year.
Our forecast for the French economy is set out in table 13. We
expect output growth in 1991 to be 1.3 per cent, after 2.8 per cent in
1990. Industrial production for 1991 as a whole will be the same as in
1990. Lower interest rates should eventually aid a recovery in business
investment, and we are expecting domestic demand to grow by 2.2 per cent
next year. The recent appreciation of the dollar along with the weakness
of the Franc within the ERM have produced a small real depreciation in
1991, and this will aid net exports, and GDP growth in 1992 is expected
to be 2.4 per cent, slightly above the growth of domestic demand. We are
forecasting that the French economy will return only slowly to its
equilibrium growth rate of almost 3 per cent. Falling interest rates
will sustain the recovery, but the ramifications of slow growth
elsewhere will be an impediment.
Moderate inflation and a slow recovery should produce an
improvement in the balance of payments in 1992. Our forecast for the
current account is set out in table 14. Export market growth is likely
to be slow in 1991 and 1992, and exports of goods are rising less
rapidly than demand. import growth has also been low, and as a result
the visible balance has improved in 1991, and is expected to improve
again in 1992. The removal of capital controls in mid 1990 has led to
large gross capital flows to countries with less regulated banking
sectors, and a large amount of French financial business is now being
transacted through Luxembourg. This has caused a slight deterioration in
the net balance on interest profits and dividends because the spread
between borrowing and lending rates enters the accounts as an IPD debit.
in the longer term we expect the French current deficit to stay below
1/2 a per cent of GNP. This will in part be driven by sluggish growth.
The commitment to the ERM and to Monetary Union requires a process of
gradual government budget consolidation. This not only puts downward
pressure on demand but it also changes the composition of financial
wealth. A reduction in the stock of government debt as a per cent of GNP
will induce wealth holders to increase their stock of assets held
overseas and this requires an improvement in the current account. Wealth
effects in France on NIGEM are relatively strong, as is shown in
Barrell, Gurney and in't Veld (1991), and these portfolio effects
are at work in our forecast.
Italy
The Italian economy grew by only 2 per cent in 1990, well below the
average of 3 1/2 per cent over the previous three years. This slowdown
in activity was common to all of the European economies outside Germany.
Charts 9 to 12 above give some details of developments in Italy over the
1980s, and our forecast for the 1990s. The Italian authorities have had
a strong commitment to the ERM, and although they have continually
realigned they have allowed the real exchange rate to rise over the
decade. This had led to an increasing balance of payments deficit. In
1987 the balance of payments was in surplus, but in each year up to 1989
it declined by half a per cent of GDP to reach a 1.3 per cent deficit by
1989. The real effective exchange rate rose by 10 per cent over the same
period despite two realignments within the ERM.
The commitment to the ERM has been a major tool in the hands of the
authorities in combating inflation. Until 1983 most Italian wages were
reindexed once a quarter, and it was only in 1985 that full automatic
indexation was removed. Since then italian wage growth, at least in the
traded goods sector seems to have moderated, but competitiveness has
still continued to decline. By the first quarter of 1991 the IMF measure
of trend adjusted relative unit labour costs was 20 per cent above its
1986 average. Wage inflation may have moderated, but not yet
sufficiently to pull Italy into line with its competitors. in the August
1991 Review in Barrell and in't Veld we calculated that the italian
economy was 10 to 15 per cent above its equilibrium real exchange rate,
and that the situation is deteriorating.
Manufacturing earnings rose by an average of 6 1/4 per cent a year
between 1986 and 1989, but they accelerated to 7-3 per cent in 1990, and
we are forecasting that they will grow by 8.4 percent in 1991. Over the
same period average earnings in the economy as a whole were rising more
rapidly. Between 1986 and 1989 they rose by almost 9 per cent a year,
and they rose by 10 per cent in 1 990. This disparity partly reflects
wage rises in the public sector and in nationalised industries. The
difference between wages in the traded and non traded goods sectors in
Italy is becoming quite marked, whilst labour productivity has been
growing slowly in services sector. The OECD Economic Survey of Italy for
1991/92 (page 80-86) makes great play of this increasing disjunction.
The increasing competitiveness pressures on the Italian economy are
significant when analysing our forecast, which is set out in table 15.
The economy has slowed down in 1991, and we are forecasting that growth
will fall to .8 per cent. This slowdown has happened despite the fall
in interest rates since the abolition of capital controls. Rates are now
1 1/2 percentage points lower than they were in the first quarter of
1990, just before the abolition of controls. However, we believe that
the authorities will have to raise interest rates in the near future,
and this affects our forecast for 1992. The economy appears to have
reached a relative trough at the end of the first quarter. industrial
production in the second quarter was 6 per cent below the peak reached
in the last quarter of 1989, but it has been growing slowly in recent
months. However business confidence indicators, which strengthened in
the Spring, have turned down again, and by August prospects for the
whole economy were just as poor as they were toward the end of 1990.
We are forecasting private sector investment growth of only 1% per
cent in 1991, and although there are signs of stronger consumption
growth supported by rising earnings we expect consumption to rise by
only 2 per cent in 1992. As a result GDP is expected to grow by only 1
1/4 per cent in 1992. In the longer term we expect a slow recovery in
the Italian economy as competitiveness pressure and slow world trade
growth will initially hold down exports. In the medium term the process
of budget consolidation is expected to be resumed. The public sector
deficit has fallen from 15 per cent of GDP in 1985 to under 10 per cent
in 1991, and we expect income taxes to be progressively raised and
spending growth curtailed in order to bring the deficit down further.
However, in the short term, the government faces serious
credibility problems. Inflation has come down, but only to 6.2 per cent
in September, well above the ERM average. The 1992 budget contained an
ad hoc package of measures designed to cut the overall deficit by Lit 13
billion to Lit 128 billion. However, much of this improvement comes from
tax receipt increases produced by special measures such as tax amnesties
for tax avoiders. However, after the 1992 elections we expect the
process of true consolidation to be resumed, with lower spending growth
and higher income taxes. This will help improve the prospects for the
balance of payments. As chart 9 shows we expect slower growth to
eventually produce inflation convergence on German rates, but we do not
believe that this will be achieved without one more realignment before
1995, the date after which the Maastricht treaty suggests no further
realignments should take place.
Canada
Growth in the middle of the 1980s in Canada was very strong,
stimulated by low interest rates and a loose fiscal stance. Inflationary
worries began to emerge in 1988, and interest rates were raised and
eventually fiscal policy was tightened. Inflation only rose to 5.0 per
cent in 1989, but the authorities were very concerned about it
accelerating further. Monetary policy was held tight until the second
quarter of 1990, when interest rates peaked at 13.6 per cent. They have
been declining since as signs of the recession have become clear. Output
fell throughout 1990, and was only 1/2 a per cent above that in 1989,
and 1991 will beyond doubt see a recession on a year-on-year basis.
The recession does, however, appear to be over. The economy grew at
an annual rate of almost 5 per cent in the second quarter of 1991 after
a full year of quarterly declines. Domestic demand rose even more
strongly. The decline in interest rates over the last year has boosted
both residential investment and consumption. Total consumer spending was
2 per cent higher than in the previous quarter, and durable goods spending rose by 7 per cent (28 per cent at an annual rate). The
Conference Board of Canada's Index of Consumers Attitudes rose
strongly in the second quarter. Real incomes have risen and savings have
fallen. Residential investment has risen strongly, and after five
quarters of decline it is now 5 per cent above the level of the previous
quarter.
The recovery has been largely driven by the personal sector.
Business investment hardly rose in the second quarter, in part because
capacity utilisation rates are low, but it appears largely because the
corporate financial position is very weak. Profits are 50 per cent below
their peak in the first quarter of 1989. Business inventories fell
markedly in the second quarter, and the growth rate of GDP would almost
have doubled if they had not done so. We expect some of this destocking
to unwind, and this is a factor behind our upward revision to our
forecast. Table 16 sets out our forecast for the Canadian economy.
The short term prospects look considerably brighter than they did 3
months ago. Core inflation, after netting out the effect of the Goods
and Services Tax increase in January, has probably dropped to 3 1/2 per
cent. Wage settlements have begun to moderate. Private sector
settlements were averaging 3.6 per cent in July, down from 5 1/2 per
cent in the first quarter and public settlements, at 2 per cent, are
even lower. Unemployment appears to have stabilised over the summer at
around 10.6 per cent. As in other countries unemployment lags behind
demand.
We are expecting both consumption and residential investment to
keep rising, but business investment is expected to be flat for the next
year. Both will fall on a year-on-year basis in 1991 before rising by
2.3 and 5.7 per cent a year in 1992. Domestic demand is expected to grow
by 2 1/2 per cent next year after falling this year. GDP growth will
exceed the rate of domestic demand growth for some time. Export volumes
shrank sharply over the last year, and Canada lost market share after
competitiveness declined by more than 4 per cent in 1990. However
exports of goods have began to pick up in the second quarter, and we are
expecting net exports of goods and services to add half a per cent to
GDP growth in 1992.
The 1980s saw a long succession of balance of payments deficits of
2 to 3 per cent of GDP. This reflected both the strength of demand and
the over-valuation of the Canadian dollar. We expect demand growth, to
be slower in the 1990s than in the 1980s, and fiscal policy will be
tighter. Hence the current balance is likely to gradually improve over
the next decade. REFERENCES
Ray Barrell, Andrew Gurney, and Jan Willem in't Veld, (1991),
'The real exchange rate, fiscal policy and the role of wealth: an
analysis of equilibrium in a monetary union', National Institute
Discussion Paper no. 3.
Barrell, R. and in't Veld, JW, (1991), 'FEERS and the
path to EMU', National Institute Economic Review, no. 136, August.
Breush, F., Busch, G. and Walterskirchen, E., (1991), Short-term
prospects for the European Economies', paper given in Brussels in
October 1991, published in Conjunctura Italiana, November 1991.