Why the capital account matters.
Pain, Nigel ; Westaway, Peter
WHY THE CAPITAL ACCOUNT MATTERS
Introduction
Most discussion of the balance of payments and its implications for
exchange-rate prospects and economic policy falls into two distinct
categories. Some authors focus on the current account alone while others
argue that in a world of liberalised capital markets information from
the volume of trade flows will simply be swamped by flows of highly
mobile international capital. In this note we argue that both these
viewpoints are too extreme; in aggregate both the current and capital
accounts will matter.
Of course this is simply another way of stating the more
sophisticated theoretical argument that the exchange rate must act as a
market clearing price, moving continuously to reconcile the total demand
and supply for sterling in the face of both expected and unexpected
changes in current and future activity in both goods and financial
markets. Despite the underlying complexity, this note argues that it is
still possible to use the capital account to obtain a measure of
exchange-rate pressure which provides more information than the current
account alone. Moreover, the useful information contained in the
composition of the capital account allows us to distinguish between
long-term structural trends in the flow of capital and more short-term
speculative movements.
We begin by outlining recent developments in the balance of
payments and then relate them to the theoretical determination of the
exchange rate in foreign exchange markets. We later deal with arguments
against the use of the capital account in such analysis while the final
section discusses some policy implications.
Recent developments in the balance of payments
In this analysis of the capital account we intend to focus upon
foreign direct investment and portfolio investment, excluding that
undertaken by the banking sector. These two categories are both the
largest and most long-term of the various identified capital
investments. The net sum of these two flows plus the current account
will be referred to as the basic balance.
This does not rule out the possibility that other elements within
the capital account are non-speculative; we will return to this issue
below. For the moment we would simply note that while national
definitions of the basic balance can vary, the concepts of long-term and
short-term capital are widely used around the world by the IMF, the Bank
of Japan and the Deutsche Bundesbank amongst others.
Recent developments in the UK balance of payments are summarised in
table 1. Over 1979-83 the current account surplus was more than offset
by net outflows of direct and portfolio investment, implying a small
deficit in our basic balance measure. In part this may have been the
result of adjustment effects induced by the abolition of exchange
controls at the end of 1979. In the subsequent five years to 1988 the
basic balance deficit increased somewhat as the current account moved in
to deficit and net outflows of direct investment rose quite
substantially. Net inflows within the banking sector increased in
magnitude although there was actually a net increase in official
reserves. [Tabular Data Omitted]
The data for 1989 (annualised using figures for the first three
quarters) show a further deterioration in our basic balance measure to
an annual deficit of 50.3[pounds] billion, some 9.8 per cent of GDP. In
part this is due to a sharp turnaround in portfolio investment with net
outflows rising to 25.2[pounds] billion. Marked changes are also
apparent elsewhere within the capital account, particularly in the
reserves and other investment. This latter development reflects an
increase in net borrowing from overseas banks. We return to some of the
factors behind these shifts and some potential caveats to our approach
below.
It is instructive to place these changes in the basic balance in an
international context. As chart 1 illustrates not only is this
particular measure of changes in the composition of the balance of
payments now much larger than anything in the recent past, it is also
far in excess of those run over the 1980s by the world's major net
importer, the United States, and the world's major net investor of
long-term capital, Japan.
Theoretical implications
Why do we even worry about capital flows, long-term or otherwise,
when we know that in total they are automatically equal and opposite to
the current account? It is often suggested that any deficit on the
current account has to be actively financed by attracting the requisite
level of so-called `hot money' inflows in order to balance the
books. The composition of the capital account has no role to play in
this story and is of no concern to policymakers. Both these implications
are seriously misleading.
Consider the purchase of an import by a UK resident. Payment
involves a transfer of funds from the bank account of the UK resident to
that of the foreigner. This transaction will be recorded as a banking
sector capital inflow. Instantaneous balance prevails. Similarly,
consider the purchase of a foreign security by a domestic institution.
The purchase of the share is counted as a portfolio investment capital
outflow. Correspondingly, the proceeds of the share sale will accrue to
the bank account of an overseas resident. Again there is automatic
balance. Neither of these transactions require consideration of hot
money or long-term flows. Instead they comprise an underlying
transaction (the import or the share purchase) and an accommodating
banking sector flow. It is the sum of the underlying transactions which
is usually identified as the basic balance.
The key point is that the ultimate implications for sterling of
both the import and the share purchase are identical. In both cases
there is a net transfer of funds from the bank accounts of domestic
residents to those of overseas residents. If the desired proportion of
foreign currency in the bank accounts of overseas residents is greater
than that of domestic residents then, ex ante, there will be more net
sterling deposits than investors want to hold. Attempts to switch into
foreign currency will lead to banks entering the interbank market in
order to attract the foreign currency funds required to satisfy the
demands of foreign depositors. Interbank deposits are required as the
banks will actively attempt to match the currency composition of their
assets and liabilities.
The exchange rate must fall or the interest rate must rise to match
demand and supply, with the size of the change depending upon the
sensitivity of asset demands to the relative return on sterling compared
with foreign currency, as measured by the difference in interest rates
plus the expected fall in the exchange rate. In contrast to the usual
explanation, the expected relative return must rise to persuade
investors to hold on to sterling, rather than to attract the `hot
money' inflow in the first place. The exchange rate is not moving
in order to finance a given deficit but to determine how it is financed.
A number of extensions can be made to the basic story. Firstly, it
is possible that domestic residents will choose to make payment by
running down any deposits they may hold with overseas banks. The size of
any adjustment in the return to sterling in this case will depend upon
the currency preferences of depositors with both domestic and overseas
banks. Secondly the extent to which the price of sterling adjusts may be
limited by changes in government holdings of foreign exchange reserves.
However, since reserves are finite, the counterpart to any sustained
imbalance must ultimately consist of net flows within the banking
sector. We would expect that such inflows, particularly of the order of
9 per cent of GDP, would cause the premium offered on sterling to rise
in order to reconcile demand and supply.
Of course this does not imply that the present structure of the
balance of payments necessarily implies an imminent collapse in the
exchange rate. Indeed if a string of deficits in the basic balance has
been anticipated, the information should already be incorporated in the
current value of the exchange rate.
Once asset demands are in equilibrium we might expect net
speculative flows to tend to zero. This does not however imply that our
chosen measure of the basic balance should return to zero, that is, net
banking sector flows are zero; it is quite possible that investors wish
to hold a certain proportion of their growing portfolios in the form of
deposits with overseas banks, although the demand for sterling may be
less than the demand for dollars or marks.
The main point is simply that marked changes in the composition of
the balance of payments are likely to prove unsustainable. Both the
current account and the capital account can provide an indication of
present and future pressures on sterling, ultimately resulting in price
changes that will help to reduce imbalances and restore stock
equilibrium by improving competitiveness and changing portfolio
preferences.
Criticisms of the capital account approach
Three main arguments have been advanced to suggest why the basic
balance and other measures of imbalance derived from the capital account
may not be an appropriate policy concern; the uncertainty generated by
the existence of the sizeable sectoral balancing item, the increased
liquidity of international investments and the importance of speculative
elements in determining the reported capital flows.
The balancing item is the statistical discrepancy between the
recorded current account and capital flows. While it is undoubtedly
large (as can be seen from table 1), it does not negate the essential
message from the capital account. This point is illustrated in chart 2
where the original basic balance measure is plotted alongside a revised
measure obtained by adding the balancing item to the recorded basic
balance. The balancing item may be able to `explain' away part of
the current account deficit or part of net longer term capital outflows
but it cannot account for both.
As for the liquidity argument, whilst individual investments are
highly liquid, the share of the portfolio held within a particular
region may be less so if international portfolio diversification is seen
as a means of reducing overall risk. Sceptics may point to the events in
the last quarter of 1987 when, following the stock market crash, some 7
billion [pounds] worth of overseas portfolio investments were
repatriated, in part to provide a source of funds to take up several
large rights issues at that time. This does not however negate the risk
argument. In a world characterised by equilibrium in asset stocks, flows
may at times be perverse as investors seek to restore the desired
composition of their portfolios.
The liquidity argument can also be applied to direct investment. By
direct investment we mean an investment which is made to acquire a
lasting interest in an enterprise operating in an economy other than
that of the investor and which gives the investor an effective voice in
the management of the enterprise. Such investment includes mergers and
acquisitions as well as capital investment in greenfield sites. To the
extent that recorded investment flows are increasingly dominated by new
cross-border mergers and acquisitions it is possible to argue that
direct investments are becoming increasingly liquid as firms may more
readily be sold to other investors. The commitment to overseas
production may be less in those companies who have simply acquired
existing assets.
We view this argument somewhat sceptically. Both joint ventures and
the purchase of the ownership rights to existing overseas assets may be
preferred to investment in greenfield sites in order to overcome the
transactions costs arising from the need to find suitable sites, obtain
planning permission, hire labour and establish a new product. Joint
ventures in particular provide existing managerial expertise and a
potential source of additional equity for capital constrained firms.
The third criticism, related to the liquidity argument, is that the
so called `long term' flows merely reflect expectations about the
short term relative returns from investing in alternate locations. This
oversimplifies the aggregate investment decision which in the case of
portfolio investment will depend on both structural (domestic and world
wealth, exchange controls and investment costs) and speculative
(expected relative return) factors. Further details can be found in
Westaway and Pain (1989).
It is possible to obtain an estimate of the structural influences
in the recorded levels of direct and portfolio investment by using the
estimated expectational effects embodied in the econometric equations in
the NIESR Domestic Econometric Model. For portfolio investment we
subtracted the expectational effects and revaluations from the actual
end quarter stock. Our estimate of the structural flow is the difference
between the revised stock and the actual stock at the end of the
previous quarter.
Speculative factors may also influence direct investment.
Ultimately expectations must dominate given that flows reflect the
expected profitability from investing in alternate locations. However
such expectations are long-term in nature and unlikely to be influenced
by quarterly fluctuations in, say, relative labour costs. Moreover
adjustment costs for fixed investment are such that it may take many
years for differentials in national rates-of-return to be eroded. This
is not to say that short-term expectations are unimportant although
price movements are more likely to affect the timing of any investment
rather than its long-term level. For the purposes of this analysis we
have assumed that the dynamic exchange-rate terms in our equations for
inward and outward direct investment (see Pain(1989), NIESR(1989))
adequately capture the importance of short-term expectations. They were
therefore subtracted from the recorded flows to obtain our estimate of
structural investment flows.
The structural flow estimates permit calculation of the underlying
level of our basic balance measure. This is shown in chart 3, alongside
the original measure from chart 1. Although the uncertainty surrounding
the calculation of the underlying measure should not be underestimated,
it seems clear that the recent changes in the capital account are due to
identifiable structural trends rather than short term speculative
factors. However, the chart also shows that speculative effects can be
important and have grown in magnitude over the sample period, peaking in
the middle of 1987 prior to the downturn in the stock market. For 1988
and the first three quarters of 1989 we estimate that such effects
account for some 25 per cent of recorded net portfolio outflows.
There are a number of identifiable factors lying behind the upsurge
in longer-term capital flows in the 1980s. Firstly, the abolition of
exchange controls at the end of 1979 had significant effects on the
level of both direct and portfolio investment outflows. Financial
deregulation has been accompanied by increasing international
diversification of investment portfolios. The adjustment process was by
no means instantaneous due to the time required to acquire information
on suitable investments and expand overseas dealing operations.
Deregulation was also instrumental in improving the attractiveness of
the UK as an investment location in the mid 1980s with the abolition of
fixed brokers commissions at the time of the `Big Bang' reforms.
Secondly, there has been a rapid increase in the size of total
portfolios over the 1980s. For example, the total assets held by
domestic insurance and pension funds grew at an annual compound rate of
18.2 per cent between the end of 1979 and 1988. Institutions are
continuing to acquire some 20-25 billion [pounds] of contractually
related savings from the personal sector. At the present time this is
combined with an absence of suitable domestic investments with the
public sector maintaining its buyback of gifts, firms issuing little new
equity and takeovers limiting the size of the equity base.
Foreign direct investment has been aided by the growth of world
markets and the rise in real corporate profits which has provided much
of the requisite investment finance. Expanding overseas has also become
an essential part of minimising currency risks as it enables companies
to obtain a closer match of their cost and income currency mixes.
Policy implications
A number of important implications for policy arise out of our
analysis of the capital account. Most obviously it suggests that a
blinkered focus on the current account alone may be misguided. Marked
changes in the structure of portfolio preferences are of equal
importance in understanding exchange-rate fundamentals. Correspondingly
policy at both micro and macro levels might be widened to incorporate
measures designed to encourage longer-term inward investment. Such
policies would be desirable both for their beneficial supply-side
consequences and also for their macroeconomic implications arising from
their role in the determination of the exchange rate.
A large number of microeconomic policy measures fall into this
category; investment incentives, tax structure and competition policies
may all be important determinants of the scale and chosen locality of
international investment. Recent work by the OECD (OECD 1989) suggests
that international investment incentives can have a significant impact
on the intra-regional regional location of investment within a wider
market such as the EEC. The structure of business taxation also plays an
important role in stimulating investment and it will be interesting to
see whether the run-up to 1992 produces a round of successive tax
reductions within Europe as national governments compete to attract
multinational companies. Competition policy is another obvious source of
uncertainty to the potential investor, particularly if applied
inconsistently or if so-called strategic industries are protected. One
of the main reasons for the negative inflow of foreign portfolio
investment in the first quarter of 1989 was the force sale of part of
stake held in BP by the Kuwait Investment Office.
Apart from explicit supply-side measures, the government can also
affect the capital account through its own actions as an important
player in financial markets; in particular through its role as a
provider of long-term securities. In the recent past the policy of fully
funding the PSDR has curtailed the supply of fixed interest sterling
securities. Contrary to the government's hopes the gap has only
partly been filled by private sector issues. With pension funds becoming
increasingly mature the demand for fixed interest or index linked gifts
to match known financing requirements has grown. A return to a policy of
over-funding may ameliorate the consequences of these developments which
have resulted in an increased outflow of portfolio investment into
overseas government securities and corporate debentures.
So far we have mentioned policies which will have downstream
macroeconomic implications. However it is equally important to emphasize
that standard macroeconomic policy measures can have consequences for
the capital account and hence influence the overall policy stance. For
example it is possible to argue that any policy-induced improvement in
the current account will help to stem the tide of outward portfolio
investment, at least to the extent that it is driven by expectations of
capital gains from a future depreciation in the exchange rate (see
Davies 1989). However it is also possible that deflationary measures may
worsen the structural capital imbalance by lowering expected
profitability and making the UK a less attractive place to invest.
While the government could rightly claim to have undertaken a
number of measures to attract overseas investment such as the reductions
in corporation tax and the changes to stamp duty at the time of the `Big
Bang', there is little sign that the capital account figures highly
in the overall macroeconomic policy framework. This note suggests that a
focus on both the current and capital accounts is required in order to
fully assess any financing problems arising from the balance of
payments. So long as imbalances of the present magnitude remain, it is
difficult to see how domestic interest rates can be significantly
reduced without the risk of a substantial fall in the exchange rate.
REFERENCES
Davies G (1989) `Key Aspects of the Balance of Payments
Problem', Appendix 9,`The 1989 Autumn Statement', First report
from the Treasury and Civil Service Select Committee, Session 1989-90
NIESR (1989), `National Institute Model 11', December 1989-90 OECD
(1989) `Investment incentives and disincentives: effects on
international direct investment" (OECD Paris) Pain, N (1989),
`International direct investment flows and the UK economy',
National Institute Discussion Paper No. 158 Westaway P and N Pain (1989)
`Towards a structural model of the UK exchange rate' National
Institute Discussion Paper No. 165