Chapter I. The home economy.
Anderton, Bob ; Britton, Andrew ; Gregg, Paul 等
The forecasts were prepared by Bob Anderton, Andrew Britton, and
Paul Gregg, but they draw on the work of the whole team engaged in
macroeconomic analysis and model building at the Institute. Parts One
and Two of the chapter were written by Andrew Britton, Part Three by Bob
Anderton.
PART ONE. RECENT DEVELOPMENTS AND SUMMARY OF THE MAIN FORECAST
Since last November we have based our forecasts on the assumption
that the UK will soon become a full member of the European Monetary
System. There has been no change in the official position on entry to
confirm or correct that assumption, but recent hints and rumours make
clear that it is the right assumption to make. We retain it for this
forecast. The actual date of entry is now more likely to be in the first
half of next year; a fall in the rate of inflation is seen as a
precondition, and it is one which may not now be fulfilled as soon as we
had hoped. We assume that some announcement on the ERM is made about the
end of the year, permitting an interest-rate cut in the first quarter,
followed by formal accession by the second quarter, about the time of
the Budget.
The attitude of the British government to economic and monetary
union in Europe has been one of disbelief and hostility. It seems
increasingly likely however that agreement will be reached to form such
a union, with or without British membership. We assume that the process
is complete by 1997; we also assume that the UK joins, even though this
is not current policy. For the present forecast this affects mainly the
last few years of the decade, and makes very little difference to the
prospects for this year or next. (A commitment to EMU would add
credibility to membership of the ERM, and might hasten the reduction in
interest rates.)
As expected, the Budget this year changed little; it was presented
along with a sombre account of economic prospects in the FSBR. Meanwhile
local authority expenditure has been increasing faster than expected or
intended, financed by the high levels at which the new poll tax has been
introduced. We assume that control of spending will be restored, and
that next year the rise in the poll tax will be no more than in line
with inflation.
Since the Budget the tone of Treasury comments on the economy has
become even more sombre (as it often does in the approach to the annual
review of public spending). It has been suggested that there will be no
scope for tax cuts before the next general election. That would be in
line with our analysis and our assumptions for this forecast. Indeed we
assume no scope for tax cuts even after the next general election (see
below).
Our short-term forecast is not as optimistic as it was in February.
On both inflation and the balance of payments we have made significant
changes. For output the forecast is not much altered.
The more rapid rate of inflation now in prospect reflects mainly
the high level of the poll tax and some smaller increases in charges
announced about the same time. These should not be included in an
assessment of the underlying rate of inflation to which the rise in the
deflator for GDP at factor cost might be a better guide. But they will
be quoted in wage claims and may for that reason raise the underlying
rate later in the year. For the end of this year we are forecasting a
12-month rise in the RPI of 8.8 per cent assuming no cut in interest
rates. By the end of 1991 the 'headline figure' could be below
5 per cent.
The run of disappointing trade figures in the first quarter of the
year and revisions to the data on the invisible account revived fears of
a continuing large deficit on the balance of payments. (Estimates of the
stock of UK net assets overseas have also been revised down
substantially.) The high level of imports is difficult to reconcile with
the evidence that manufacturing output is falling and that stocks are
being run down. The view that the trade figures were `erratic' must
be accepted for the present, and the outlook is for a sustained
improvement for the rest of the year. Even so the current account
deficit for the year is now forecast at about 9-1 5 billion. Next year
it should be reduced to below 10 billion [pounds].
The level of output probably fell in the first quarter of this
year. it is likely that stocks are being run down and fixed investment
cut back in response to the continuation of high levels of interest
rates. Consumer spending on the other hand seems to show considerable
resilience. For the rest of the year output growth should be resumed,
but at a slow pace. The rise in GDP year-on-year is forecast at 1.2 per
cent, or 0.8 excluding North Sea Oil. This is close to the forecast
published by the Treasury in the FSBR.
Our forecast for growth in 1991 has been revised up a little to 2.7
per cent, a higher figure than would be suggested by the Treasury's
forecast for the first half year. The main reasons for the relatively
strong growth are the reduction in UK interest rates and the buoyancy of
world demand.
Our medium- and long-term forecasts reflect our view of the
consequence of full ERM membership and the transition to EMU. Initially
we assume that the effective exchange-rate index will fall by about 2
per cent a year; this is consistent either with wider margins for
Sterling within the ERM, or occasional realignments. By 1997 we assume
exchange rates in Europe are fixed; our exchange rate would then
appreciate a little as the European currencies (or currency) strengthen
against the dollar.
Consistent with that view of exchange rates, we assume a gradual
fall in short-term interest rates in the UK, to 5 per cent by the end of
the decade. Although underlying inflation also falls, this is mainly a
reduction in real interest rates, and should increase investment, adding
to the sustainable rate of growth of output. Long-term bond yields are
expected to fall consistently and the price of equities to rise.
A striking feature of our medium- and long-term forecasts is the
low rate of inflation after 1992. The prices of imports are given by
world inflation (see chapter 2) and the path of the exchange rate. Given
that path for the exchange rate (and the pressure of demand) the
reduction in interest rates actually helps to slow down inflation by
reducing the costs of holding stocks. Moreover the very low figures for
the increase in the RPI produced by cuts in mortgage interest rates may
encourage low wage settlements.
PART TWO. FINANCIAL SURPLUSES AND DEFICITS
Despite the high level of nominal interest rates the personal
sector was in large financial deficit in 1988 and 1989. This was
associated with a large deficit on the current account of the balance of
payments (a financial surplus for the overseas sector) and with a
surplus for the public sector. (We assume that this picture is broadly
correct, with the residual error mainly attributable to the measurement
of the company sector balance.) This is a combination of financial
balances without precedent, and doubts have been expressed about its
sustainability. Behind the medium-term financial strategy, published by
the government at the time of the Budget, there probably lies a
calculation that the personal sector will move back into its accustomed
surplus, allowing the current account of the balance of payments to
improve, whilst at the same time the public sector moves back into
balance within a few years. This could be described as a move back
towards equilibrium; we compare that pattern with our own forecasts.
As table B shows we expect a much reduced deficit for the personal
sector this year, followed by a small surplus in 1991. This is matched
by an improvement on the current account of the balance of payments. The
surprising feature of the table is the behaviour of the financial
balances after 1991. The personal sector moves again into sustained
deficit, the current account deficit widens and the public sector is
left to repay debt on an even larger scale.
The reopening of the personal sector deficit is a consequence of
the fall in interest rates, assumed as part of the transition to
economic and monetary union. Had interest rates been held at their
current levels the personal sector would have been in increasing
surplus. The major stimulus to personal sector spending when interest
rates fall is to investment in housing; both the price and the volume of
new building rise substantially. Added to that is a powerful effect from
the growth of consumer credit, linked to extra demand for durables.
These are further reinforced by the effect of lower interest rates on
the prices of gilts and equities, which provide capital gains for the
personal sector adding to its net financial wealth.
Even in a forecast to the end of the decade the full effects of
lower interest rates do not have time to show themselves. In the very
long term the stock of credit would be fully adjusted to the lower level
of interest rates following monetary union, and the flow of new
borrowing would be no more than that needed to keep the debt-to-income
ratio (or debt-to-wealth ratio) constant. Similarly after a very long
period the stock of personal sector net wealth would adjust to a new
equilibrium relative to income. At that equilibrium the ratio of net
wealth to income would be maintained by a combination of capital gains
(on equities and indexed gilts) and the financial surplus of the sector.
The size of the surplus would reflect the allocation of the
sector's portfolio as well as its total net wealth. Perhaps such
ideas of stock equilibrium are behind the suggestion sometimes made that
a personal sector financial deficit is necessarily self-correcting.
Whilst the principle seems to be correct, the time-scale over which it
can be applied may be very long indeed.
In our consumption function the effect of accumulated wealth on
current spending, although statistically significant, is relatively
small. Simulations on the model indicate that convergence on the
equilibrium wealth-to-income ratio can take decades rather than years.
On the other hand we recognise that our model may not capture all
aspects of consumer behaviour. Further work is needed to investigate the
effects of expectations on spending. We have in fact changed the profile
of consumer spending in this forecast to a certain extent to allow for
the possibility that the reductions in interest rates associated with
EMU are correctly anticipated.
It is perhaps misleading to pay too much attention to the net
acquisition of financial assets as a measure of `balance' or
equilibrium. its definition is a matter of accounting convenience alone,
especially so far as the treatment of capital gains is concerned. The
more fundamental issues concern the stocks of assets and their
relationships with current or expected income flows. In the present
context however the path of these financial balances does seem to point
to a real change of behaviour in the 1990s compared with previous
periods. Behind the concern with the financial balance of the personal
sector is the accounting relationship between sectors involving the
current account of the balance of payments and public sector borrowing.
These balances are also defined in a way that is open to question, but
they remain of concern to policymakers nevertheless.
Variant forecasts
One way of examining the consequences of the renewed deficit for
the personal sector in the forecast period is to look at a variant in
which savings remain relatively high. In the variant a negative residual
is added to the consumption function in the model. As a result consumer
spending is lower throughout, the amount of the reduction building up
initially but levelling off at 2 per cent after about three years. As
table B shows the personal sector now stays close to balance.
In this variant the exchange rate and the rate of interest were
both held fixed. The level of output is lower, initially because of
weaker demand, but ultimately because the capacity of the economy is
reduced by a lower level of fixed investment. In the first few years of
the variant forecast, economic activity and the price level are both
depressed.
The consequences for the other sectors of the economy are also
shown. Taking the year 1993 as an example, the improvement of 8 billion
[pounds] in the financial balance of the personal sector, compared with
the main case, is matched by reductions of 4 billion [pounds] each in
the surpluses of the public and the overseas sectors. The deficit of the
company sector is unchanged. The current account of the balance of
payments is still in deficit, but heading more rapidly towards balance
than it does in the main case. Perhaps the assumption we make about
fiscal policy in the main case is tighter than is strictly necessary for
the variant with more savings. To make the outcome on the current
account comparable a second variant was computed in which tax cuts were
made (in addition to the residual adjustment to the consumption
function) so as to restore the balance of payments deficits to broadly
the path of the base run. The results are shown in the third section of
table B.
If we focus again on 1993, only two columns are different between
the main case and the second variant. The changes to the personal sector
and the public sector match one another. The personal sector is in small
surplus, and the public sector is also in surplus-but to a much reduced
extent as compared with the base run.
We have not considered a variant in which extra saving results in a
lower rate of interest. This might be appropriate under the present
exchange-rate regime, if the prospect for a better outcome on the
balance of payments caused the exchange rate to appreciate and the rate
of inflation to be lower as a consequence. It is not clear, however, how
the current exchange rate would react to the prospect of a better
outcome for the current account which would be evident only after the UK
had joined a monetary union.
In the absence of an exchange-rate rise, the effect of higher
savings on inflation is small. That being so, it is not clear how
interest rates would now react since the rate of inflation seems to be
the main criterion used by the monetary authorities in deciding when
interest rates can come down. Once the UK is a full member of the
exchange-rate mechanism interest rates are unlikely to respond much to
any signals other than those that come from the foreign exchange market.
If we treat interest rates as fixed there is no economic mechanism by
which a higher level of savings is translated into a higher level of
fixed investment. The increment to net wealth, when it occurs, is all in
the form of net overseas assets.
From the point of view of the government in power in the mid-1990s
the low rate of personal savings we forecast presents a policy problem.
Fiscal tightening on the scale indicated, whether it took the form of
tax increases or public spending cuts, would be unpopular and might be
damaging to the economy. it would therefore be attractive to find a way
of increasing personal sector savings. Some tax concessions were
announced in the Budget intended to help savers, but their effect on the
personal sector as a whole is unlikely to be large. The government has
argued that direct controls on personal sector borrowing would not be
effective. We conclude that low personal sector savings, and a tight
fiscal policy, are the best assumptions to take for the present as the
main case of our forecasts.
PART THREE. THE MAIN FORECAST IN DETAIL
Forecasts of expenditure and output (table 1) The revised figures
for GDP show an excess of the output measure over the expenditure
measure for last year. One reason for this could be that output may
actually be overestimated, particularly manufacturing output; our
reasons for believing this may be the case are given in Box 1 on page
19.
Compared to our last Review we are forecasting a marginally smaller
growth in GDP this year at 1.2 per cent. Substantial de-stocking
accounts for much of the slower growth in 1990. We are also less
optimistic about the recovery in oil output. The net contribution to
output from the balance of payments is less in this forecast which
partly reflects the poor trade figures of the first quarter of this
year. In contrast, we have higher public sector output growth for 1990
due to the higher levels of public expenditure by local authorities that
have already occurred. Our forecast of consumers' expenditure
growth is virtually unchanged at just over 1.5 per cent.
Next year we are expecting a strong recovery in output with exports
continuing their good performance and consumers' expenditure also
showing renewed growth, especially late in 1991 as our assumed
interest-rate falls begin to take effect. Oil output should also be
stronger by this time and fixed investment growth could be around 2 per
cent. This will bring total GDP growth back towards its potential trend
rate of approximately 2% per cent.
Wage and price inflation (tables 2, 9 and 10) Our assumption of UK
ERM entry (in the second quarter of next year) implies that UK interest
rates will eventually converge towards European average levels. We
assume that before ERM entry Sterling depreciates-in line with the open
arbitrage condition which is equivalent to the interest-rate
differential between the UK and overseas less our assumed risk premium
for the UK (see table 10). After ERM entry UK interest rates gradually
move towards European levels, which is consistent with some continuation
of the depreciation of Sterling against the D-Mark, as well as a
remaining, now smaller, UK risk premium vis a vis Germany. This also
implies a depreciation of the UK effective exchange rate. UK membership
of ERM would therefore deliver a similar future exchange-rate path to
that of Italy. Once European monetary union takes place (circa 1997) the
UK exchange rate is irrevocably fixed against the other European
participating states. However, this will probably mean a small
appreciation of Sterling against the US Dollar due to the strength of
the D-Mark.
As the UK effective exchange rate has already depreciated substantially over the past year this means that there will be mounting
pressure for considerable import price rises this year. However, the
short-term effects of exchange-rate movements in our manufacturing
import price equation are not as large as the effects arising from world
price increases in foreign currencies. This implies that importers may
initially cut profit margins (in order to maintain their market share)
before implementing the full price rise if the exchange-rate fall
persists. In addition, weak world basic materials prices may further
help limit import price growth to around 4.5 per cent this year. Our
forecast of future exchange-rate falls next year will probably keep
import price inflation at approximately the same rate in 1991.
Producers will find these import costs rising at the same time that
unit labour costs are accelerating due to the combined effect of
increased earnings and falling productivity growth. Profit margins must
therefore fall if underlying price inflation is to stop rising-this may
be happening to a certain extent but the recent upward trend in producer
output prices indicates some producers are reluctant to lower profit
margins.
As profit margins become tighter, employers may be more reluctant
to grant large earnings increases. However, earnings will be affected by
the following factors: first, in previous years average earnings were
somewhat restrained by income tax cuts but this will not happen this
year and looks increasingly unlikely next year (although the reduction
in national insurance contributions effective from last October will
have some effect this year). Tax cuts would also increase the
sustainable level of utilisation (i.e. decrease the NAIRU) thus
decreasing the underlying rate of inflation for any given level of
actual utilisation. Second, previous housing price booms have been
followed by rapidly rising earnings. Third, earnings may now be more
strongly linked to interest-rate increases as the personal sector
interest-linked debt has substantially increased in recent years.
Fourth, wage settlements have been high relative to increases in average
earnings over the past year or so and the discrepancy has often been
explained in terms of a reduction in wage drift' as the economy
slows down (i.e. overtime hours and payments decelerate). However,
latest data indicate that over-time and total hours worked in
manufacturing have stopped decreasing in the early part of this year.
The implication is that more of the recent high wage settlements will be
transmitted into future average earnings growth figures compared to the
situation where hours continue to fall. Most of the above points suggest
upward pressure on earnings growth and this partly explains why we are
forecasting no significant fall in earnings growth both this year and
next. In the longer run there should be some downward pressure on wage
inflation from the extra discipline exerted by UK ERM membership.
However in the short term our forecast of underlying inflation, as
represented by the deflator for GDP at factor cost, is therefore higher
compared to our last forecast.
The RPI grew by just under 9 1/2 per cent during the year to this
April. This partly reflected the excess cost of the poll tax relative to
domestic rates and also the uprating of excise duties in the last
budget. Further utility price rises should bring retail price inflation
very close to 10 per cent in the coming months, which has important
implications for average earnings. We believe the RPI will be increasing
by around 9 per cent per annum in the fourth quarter of this year but
our assumed interest-rate falls of next year will bring it down to
approximately 5 per cent in the fourth quarter of 1991.
The consumer price index will be subject to a discontinuity from
the second quarter of this year because of the treatment of the poll tax
in the National Accounts. Domestic rates were previously classified as a
tax on housing services and part of nominal consumers' expenditure
whereas the poll tax is treated as a deduction from income. As the
volume of housing services consumed will be the same this implies that
the volume of consumers' expenditure does not change. Consequently,
the implied consumers' expenditure deflator will fall but this
obviously does not represent any change in underlying inflation. The
tables in the Review now reflect these changes.
Personal income and expenditure (table 2)
Although the data are volatile it does seem that a slowdown in the
growth of both consumer credit and retail sales is well under way. This
obviously largely reflects high interest rate levels as personal sector
debt payments to income ratios have virtually doubled since early 1988.
But consumer uncertainty concerning future real disposable income, house
prices and lower expectations of future tax cuts may also begin to
discourage consumers' expenditure. Our short-term forecast for
consumers' expenditure is similar to the February issue of this
Review. We expect consumption growth to fall to around 1 1/2 per cent
this year with a recovery to around 2 per cent next year. Given our
forecast for the growth of personal disposable income this implies a
slight rise in the savings ratio. We have not made any allowances for a
pre-election reduction in income tax as fiscal restraint is required to
offset the effects on demand of falling interest rates given our
assumption of ERM entry. Much depends on the growth of earnings and
inflation (and hence real incomes) and the expectations of consumers.
Our consumption equation is not forward looking, but given the life
cycle theory that consumers will maximise utility by smoothing their
consumption path over their lifetime their expectations of future income
and interest rates will affect current consumption. Consequently, our
residual adjustments on consumers' expenditure are partly designed
to capture this more smoothed behaviour of consumption.
Fixed investment and stock building (tables 3 and 4) Virtually all
of the variables which encouraged strong investment growth in the late
1980s seem to be heading for a downturn this year; capacity utilisation
will fall as demand declines and reduce the need for new investment;
profitability will also fall in line with demand thus reducing both the
amount of internal funds available for investment and the return on that
investment; the growing financial deficit of the company sector will
probably result in less investment as companies attempt to move back
towards financial balance. The high cost of finance is obviously another
major factor constraining investment and the recent rise in long-term
interest rates-probably reflecting more pessimistic expectations
concerning inflation-will also discourage investment by companies who
take a `long view' including those who raise their own funds by
issuing corporate bonds. The respondents to the April CBI industrial
Trends Survey tend to agree with all the above points and indicate that
investment intentions have recently weakened particularly for smaller
firms and those firms in the consumer goods industries. Given these
factors and the depressed state of housing investment we expect around a
2 per cent fall in total investment this year. We are forecasting a mild
recovery of 2 per cent total investment growth for next year, but
manufacturing investment may well remain flat as capacity still seems
adequate after the rapid manufacturing investment of recent years. Our
forecast of a recovery in total investment next year is largely due to
our assumed rapid interest-rate falls resulting from UK ERM entry in the
first half of next year.
Latest figures have revised stock building downwards for last year
and it now appears that de-stocking began in the last quarter of 1989.
We believe that further de-stocking in all sectors will be an important
element of the slowdown in the economy this year. Milder de-stocking may
well persist into next year as the company sector attempts to continue
its move towards a more satisfactory liquidity position and the trend of
declining stock/output ratios is maintained. We expect most of the
negative stock building to occur in distribution as this sector seems
particularly sensitive to liquidity constraints and also experienced a
probably unintended increase in its stock/output ratio last year.
Balance of payments (tables 5 and 6)
This year's first quarter current balance deficit of 5 1/2
billion [pounds] now means that the monthly deficit for the rest of the
year must average around 1 billion [pounds] if the Treasury forecast of
a 15 billion [pounds] current balance deficit for 1990 is to be proved
correct. However, these first quarter figures should be treated with
caution. Abnormally high imports of erratic items (officially defined as
ships, precious stones, North sea installations and aircraft) added
around C600 million to the quarterly deficit and the oil trade surplus
is also temporarily low due to short-term production problems in the oil
sector. Looking back over a longer period it seems that the trend growth
rates of imports and exports are moving in the right direction. Our
forecast for 1990 of substantial destocking and declines in both
investment and capacity utilisation will keep imports subdued. At the
same time strong world trade growth will keep exports buoyant and the
oil trade balance should recover somewhat. We are now expecting a
slightly larger fall in the UK effective exchange rate this year
compared to our February Review. (This follows from our assumption that
UK interest-rate differentials are now higher through 1990 as UK ERM
entry is now assumed to occur next year.) Therefore, this year's
trade figures will be a combined result of J-curve effects from our
expected Sterling depreciation this year and a better volume performance
due to improved competitiveness from the previous year's
depreciation. Taking these points into consideration we expect the
current balance deficit for this year to be around 15.5 billion
[pounds].
This forecast improvement on last year's deficit is all
accounted for by a much better performance in visible trade as our
forecast surplus of 2 billion [pounds] for invisible trade for
1990-consisting of a 4.5 billion [pounds] surplus on services, a 1.4
billion [pounds] surplus on IPD and a 3.9 billion [pounds] deficit on
transfers-is lower than the unusually low surplus for last year. The
very low IPD surplus for 1990 largely reflects the high interest-rate
returns on the deposits held by overseas residents in UK banks.
Secondly, our forecast of net revenue from IPD for this year and next is
lower than last time because upward statistical adjustments to inward
portfolio investment, combined with new information acquired from
securities dealers, has resulted in a substantial fall in the UK's
net asset position compared to previously published figures.
Next year should see the current balance deficit continue its
decline to around 10 billion [pounds]. This partly follows from an
improvement in IPD net revenue as UK interest rate differentials fall
and as exports of financial services begin to benefit more from the
opening of financial markets in Europe as we approach 1992. Visible
trade is also forecast to improve again in 1991 as the effects of the
depreciation this year improve the price competitiveness of UK tradeable
goods.
Our forecast for the components of the capital account (the
counterpart of the current account) is shown in table 6. The table
focuses attention on the sustainability of the present balance of
payments situation by showing the `basic balance' which is defined
as the current account plus net structural flows. The basic balance
represents the amount of short-term accommodating flows (after allowing
for official government intervention in the foreign exchange market and
a large balancing item) required to balance the capital account. A very
large basic balance deficit arose last year because the problem of a
large current account deficit was exacerbated by large net outflows of
portfolio investment. These outflows were encouraged by several factors:
returns on overseas equities relative to the UK were higher (this
includes the effect of an expected depreciation of Sterling resulting in
substantial outflows in search of potential capital gains from
revaluations); large cash flows into UK life assurance and pension funds
resulted in portfolio investment abroad, as the dwindling availability
of UK government gilts and the limited number of new equity issues
restricted the range of suitable investments in the UK. However, the
size of the implied banking sector inflow was much reduced by official
intervention.
This year should see a reduction in the size of the basic balance
deficit largely because our forecast of a decline in corporate
profitability and the probable movement of the company sector back
towards financial balance should constrain the amount of finance
available for UK investment overseas (especially direct investment).
Slower UK equity price growth relative to the world average should
encourage the continuation of net portfolio outflows, but the effect on
the basic balance deficit is partially offset by our forecast of a
substantial improvement in the current balance. However, without the
help of the large official intervention of last year the required
accommodating net banking sector inflow should remain quite substantial
this year. Given that we are forecasting 15 per cent base rates for the
rest of this year the high returns on foreigners' bank deposits in
the UK will depress our net earnings on IPD. Next year we will probably
also see a large basic balance deficit; the improvement of the current
balance deficit to under 10 billion [pounds] and reduced net portfolio
outflows (as the abolition of stamp duty improves the competitiveness of
the UK stock exchange and the scope for currency revaluation related
capital gains is reduced as the UK enters the ERM) will decrease the
basic balance deficit but the renewal of direct investment outflows as
company profitability recovers will have the opposite effect.
Nevertheless, IPD revenue should recover somewhat next year as the
returns on a similar sized banking sector inflow as in 1990 are much
reduced by the assumed rapid interest-rate falls in the UK.
Output and the labour market (tables 7 and 8) According to the
latest data manufacturing output is now failing but some other economic
indicators suggest that the downturn in this sector may actually be
stronger (see Box 1 on capacity utilisation). The output of the energy
sector is still adversely affected by production problems in the oil
sector and is far weaker than we expected. Within manufacturing, output
of the non-durables industries (such as textiles, clothing, footwear and
leather etc) is not looking as weak as the durable goods industries,
which is consistent with the view that high interest rates are slowing
credit-led demand. We expect non-oil GDP growth to slow down to around
3/4 of a per cent this year with output falls in both the manufacturing
and construction industries partially offset by increased public sector
output arising from higher local government spending. Total GDP growth
should be a little higher as oil production begins to recover in the
second half of this year. Next year will probably see a renewal of GDP
growth to approximately 2% per cent helped by both lower interest rates
and a better net contribution to GDP from the balance of payments partly
arising from the improvements in competitiveness implied by previous
Sterling depreciation.
Recent employment trends are discussed in Box 2 but a few extra
points are worth noting here. Although total unemployment has been
registering slight falls, some southern regions have experienced actual
rises in unemployment which could reflect a stronger decline in demand
in these areas due to the higher mortgage debt/income ratios prevalent
in the south. Even though total employment is still rising, sectors such
as manufacturing are experiencing employment falls. The fall in
employment will consist mainly of job losses for full-time males who
will be eligible for benefit and hence satisfy the unemployment count
criteria. We would therefore expect measured unemployment to rise in the
second half of this year possibly rising to around 1.8 million at the
end of next year. This will be largely due to manufacturing employment
falls and slower employment growth in most other sectors, particularly
distribution, although public sector employment will be less affected
due to higher spending.
Public sector finance (table 11)
The PSDR was around 8 billion [pounds] for the last financial year.
This is approximately 4.5 billion [pounds] below the Autumn Statement
forecast and reflects both higher expenditure and lower receipts. The
changeover to the poll tax seems to have added around an extra 3 billion
[pounds] to local authority expenditure. Additional capital expenditure
has also occurred before new regulations come into force. An increasing
take up of personal pension plans has also reduced revenue and the high
level of interest rates has also increased the cost of servicing public
debt. For this financial year our forecast of rising unemployment in the
second half of 1990 will increase spending on grants and accelerating
public sector pay deals will boost an already high level of expenditure
on government services. Our forecast of a decline in corporate profits
will further reduce corporation tax this year but government revenue
will be helped by a recovery in the oil sector. Looking further ahead we
are assuming that, like this financial year, caution will dictate that
tax cuts are not appropriate next year especially if interest rates do
fall rapidly as our assumed UK ERM entry suggests. Of course, these
estimates are very uncertain as political pressure in a pre-election
year may bring forth tax cuts in the next financial year and methods to
reduce poll tax payments may also be introduced. We have assumed that
poll tax payments in the future rise in line with inflation.
THE MEDIUM-TERM FORECAST
One difference between our current medium-term forecast and the
February Review is that the current balance deficit does not disappear
by the end of the forecast. This is largely due to the fact that
European monetary union reduces interest rates further thereby boosting
imports through increased demand. Although we allow for some fiscal
tightening the extent of fiscal restraint required for a zero current
balance would be implausibly restrictive and the most optimistic outcome
is that the current balance deficit begins to trend downwards. Although
highly uncertain, our capital account equations indicate that UK net
structural flows will make the situation worse and a substantial basic
balance deficit will also persist throughout the medium and long term.
The major net structural outflows in our long-term capital account
forecast seem to be developing within direct investment. This is largely
due to our forecast of stronger output growth abroad compared to the UK
and also continually rising real unit labour costs at home but falling
real unit labour costs overseas.
However, the actual outcome for the balance of payments could be
better than forecast as we have not allowed for any specific benefits to
inward UK direct investment resulting from the reduction of Sterling
exchange-rate uncertainty once UK ERM membership takes place.
Furthermore, there is some evidence to suggest that inward direct
investment helps the UK current balance. First, our exports of
manufactures equation includes a stochastic trend which shows an
improvement in underlying UK export performance which could be partly
due to the benefits of direct investment as overseas investors use the
UK as a base for exporting into Europe. Secondly, if we include the real
stock of inward investment in our imports of manufactures equation we
find that direct investment is negatively signed suggesting that
overseas investment in the UK results in the substitution of UK domestic
production for imports of manufactures.
The financial balances of the domestic sectors as well as the
overseas sector may also remain in imbalance in the medium term. The
personal sector will be encouraged to move back towards deficit as
interest rates fall rapidly encouraging less savings and more
consumption based on cheaper credit and revaluations of wealth. This
implies a continuing surplus for the public sector as tax revenues
remain high because of buoyant activity and defence spending is reduced
in the long run. However, the behaviour of the personal sector's
savings ratio is uncertain and our variant in part two shows an
alternative scenario where the personal sector saves more.
Given our forecast of rapidly failing interest rates, investment is
likely to show a reasonable performance in the medium term which seems
to restrain capacity utilisation thus reducing pressure of demand
effects and hence inflation. Consumer price inflation slows down in the
medium term partly because the sustainable level of utilisation rises
relative to actual utilisation as the cost of stock-holding falls in
line with interest rates. GDP is forecast to grow at a rate close to its
potential trend of between 2 3/4 to 3 per cent throughout the
medium-term period. This produces good productivity growth rates
especially in manufacturing where employment growth is particularly
subdued. However, the strong output growth will tend to move import
growth above that of exports and worsen the balance of payments.