Chapter I. The home economy.
Anderton, Bob ; Britton, Andrew ; Soteri, Soterios 等
The forecasts were prepared by Bob Anderton, Andrew Britton, and
Soterios Soteri, but they draw on the work of the whole team engaged in
macroeconomic analysis and modelbuilding at the Institute. Parts One and
Two of the chapter were written by Andrew Britton, Part Three by Bob
Anderton. We start our forecast this time with an exchange rate 91/2per
cent higher in the third quarter of this year than we anticipated in
May. The main reason for the appreciation of sterling was probably a
reassessment by the market of the likely course of UK monetary policy
over the next year or two. The likelihood of an early and significant
fall in interest rates has receded, as forecasts of the underlying rate
of inflation have been revised up. At the same time the commitment to
join the exchange-rate mechanism has become firmer, and the Chancellor
has been interpreted as wishing to 'talk the rate up'.
The higher starting rate of sterling itself has important
implications for our short-term forecast. Moreover we share the changed
view of the future course of monetary policy which we attribute to
'the market'. We now assume that base rates stay at 15 per
cent until the second quarter of next year, failing to just 14 per cent
by the fourth quarter.
If uncovered interest parity holds, then the existence of an
interest differential in favour of sterling implies the expectation of
sterling depreciation in the future. Applying that theory, and the
principle of consistent expectations, to our forecasts, we now expect a
faster rate of exchange-rate depreciation next year than we have
previously. This would be consistent with membership of the
exchange-rate mechanism, but with bands wide enough to permit some
depreciation next year without a realignment. Looking further ahead our
forecasts imply, as before, that downward realignments of sterling are
allowed until 1997, when the UK is assumed to join an economic and
monetary union.
Table A shows to what extent the change in our short-term forecasts
can be explained simply in terms of different assumptions about the
exchange rate and interest rates. The first section shows some features
of our May forecasts. The second section shows those forecasts reworked
with the exchange-rate and interest-rate assumptions we have now
adopted. This can then be compared with the figures in the third
section, which are taken from our new forecasts.
The higher level of the exchange rate and of interest rates next
year is enough on its own to explain the lower growth rate of output we
are now expecting for next year. The variant shows the current account
deficit slightly improved, initially by the J-curve effect of exchange
appreciation, subsequently by the lower level of activity. It also shows
the rate of inflation next year markedly reduced, although this last
effect must be seriously exaggerated in present circumstances.
Our new forecast also takes account of other recent developments
and other information which has become available since May. The level of
demand and activity in the first half of this year was higher than we
expected. Consumer spending was still growing significantly, although
the fall in retail sales in June may indicate that the trend has now
flattened off. The buoyancy of import volume, impetus from the latest
oil price rise. (Were it not for the rise in the exchange rate our
forecast of earnings increase would have been raised considerably this
time.)
The outturn for the current balance so far this year shows a
deficit at an annual rate of 21 8 billion. We expect a small improvement
in the latter half of the year, thanks to better terms of trade (higher
world oil prices and a higher exchange rate). Next year the trade
balance is expected to deteriorate a little as the volume effects of the
exchange-rate appreciation make themselves felt.
The outlook for the medium term is based on our assessment of the
effects of full EMS membership, followed by membership of an EMU in the
late 1990s. inflation slows down to 'Franco-German' rates,
with interest rates also coming gradually into line. The rate of growth
picks up to a sustainable 2 1/2 per cent, with unemployment little
changed at about 1 1/2 million. The current account of the balance of
payments continues in substantial deficit for some years, gradually
reducing towards the end of the decade, but that position should be
financial in the policy context we assume. The surplus on the public
sector increases again in the mid-1990s as lower interest rates ease the
cost of debt service, but eventually the accounts move back to balance
(or indeed a slight deficit if privatisation comes to an end). To
understand the present problems of the UK economy it is necessary to
look back at least three years and account for the very rapid growth of
demand which took place from 1987 to 1989. The acceleration of inflation
and the deterioration of the balance of payments have both been
attributed to the boom which got under way at that time. in this section
we conduct a brief historical investigation asking four questions. Could
the boom have been prevented by the use of conventional instruments of
fiscal and monetary policy? if so, why was it not prevented? Why was the
need for action not anticipated? And could a similar sequence of events
occur again?
A retrospective policy variant
We have used the institute's macroeconomic model to estimate
what would have been the outcome for the economy if a different set of
policies had been adopted from the beginning of 1987. The changes are
made to the normal instruments of monetary and fiscal policy, that is to
the level of interest rates, to the rate of income tax and the amount of
public spending on goods and services. We have not assumed the
introduction or re-introduction of any direct form of credit control or
regulation.
In the retrospective policy variant we assume that the level of
interest rates was held constant at 12.4 per cent continuously from 1987
to the end of 1991. The average level of interest rates in this period
is therefore very similar to what has actually occurred (or is forecast
to occur in the next 18 months). This 'counterfactual' case
contrasts with an actual fall in interest rates in 1987, a steep actual
rise in the latter half of 1988, continuing to the present, and with a
small forecast fall during next year.
We assume in the variant that fiscal policy was progressively
tightened in 1987, 1988, 1989, and 1990 by raising income tax instead of
cutting it and by actual falls in the volume of public expenditure. The
income tax increases (compared to the base run) are equivalent to rises
of about 7p in the basic rate (with a direct revenue effect of El 2
billion a year) by 1989. The reduction in public spending is equivalent
to about 8 per cent of public authorities' consumption by 1990. (It
is assumed that these fiscal policy changes are reversed between 1992
and 1994). Had policy changes of this magnitude been introduced in the
late 1980s they would doubtless have been regarded as very severe
indeed. There can be few, if any, precedents for such a sharp deflation.
Before presenting the results of this variant, three points should
be made about the methodology. The first is a general point about the
treatment of expectations. In using the model to create a
'counterfactual history' we have to assume that the same
expectational errors were made (by firms, unions etc) in the variant as
in reality. Since these expectational errors cannot be identified we do
not know how plausible an assumption this is.
The second point concerns the exchange rate, which has been assumed
unchanged in the variant. This should be correct as an approximation.
Neither a temporary tightening of fiscal policy, nor a change in the
profile of interest rates with the average level unchanged, would
necessarily result in a very different outcome for the exchange rate.
The problem of using the model to recalculate more exactly the
exchange-rate path is that the results depend crucially on the extent to
which the policy changes were anticipated.
The third point concerns the behaviour of consumers. They too may
make forecasts of future policy changes, and such forecasts may
influence their spending. The announcement of tax cuts in the Budgets of
1987 and 1988 may have contributed to the consumer boom by raising
expectations of tax cuts to come in the future. Similarly the much
tougher fiscal stance shown in the variant might also have been
extrapolated in expectations of further tightening to come. (Conversely some might argue that the more tax cuts there are now, the less tax cuts
there are still to come.) Our consumption function is not forwardlooking
in this way, so we cannot take any effects of this kind into account.
The results of the simulation are shown in table C. The level of
output is reduced by about 1 per cent in 1987 and by a further 1.3 per
cent in 1988. This reduction is smaller than the forecasting errors made
at the time, despite the large scale of the deflationary measures
assumed in the variant. Even in the variant unemployment falls in the
late 1980s, but it levels off at about 2 million, significantly higher
than the level actually reached this year.
The effect on the balance of payment is substantial. There is still
a deficit on the current account after 1987, but it is much smaller than
that actually observed, and by 1991 the account is almost in balance. It
is likely that one consequence of this better balance of payments
outcome would have been a higher level of the exchange rate, but that
effect is not included in the variant shown.
The effect on the underlying rate of inflation is best judged by
the figures for the deflator of GDP at factor cost. The effect of the
assumed deflationary measures is felt mainly in 1988 and 1989. Later on
the effect on the price level wears away, so that the rate of inflation
is actually higher in the variant. The effects on the underlying retail
price index are similar, but there are additional changes resulting from
smoothing out the path of interest rates in the variant.
It is, perhaps, disappointing to find that the large scale demand
deflation assumed from 1987 to 1989 does not do more to reduce inflation
subsequently. In this context the fixed exchange-rate assumption is
important, since one of the main reasons for the acceleration of
inflation in 1990 is the fall in the exchange rate in 1989. It is
possible that a more deflationary fiscal policy would have been
associated with a higher exchange rate, even though interest rates were
held constant.
Explaining past policies
The counterfactual simulation shows that it would have been
possible to reduce the scale of the boom, and to prevent the balance of
payments moving into such large deficit by taking deflationary measures
in the Budgets of 1987 and 1988. In fact both these Budgets were
expansionary, and in addition interest rates were reduced during 1987
and the first half of 1988. At the time the institute supported
interest-rate reductions, but argued against tax cuts (National
Institute Economic Review February 1988, p5). No one was advising the
Government to embark on a deflation on the scale illustrated in the
variant.
It is not clear to what extent macroeconomic policy was being
conducted at this time with a view to managing domestic demand. Earlier
in the 1980s such an aim was sometimes quite explicitly denied. It was
asserted that policy was governed by objectives for monetary growth or
considerations of fiscal stability in the medium term. By the end of the
1980S however the growth of 'money GDP', that is total output
at current prices, had become the focus of attention. (When the targets
for 'money GDP' were overshot this was excused on the grounds
that the growth was real' rather than nominal'.) What was
actually done by policy makers between 1987 and 1988 can be best
explained however in terms of their preoccupation with the exchange rate
and with the PSBR. Throughout 1987 and 1988 the sterling exchange-rate
index was generally strong. Between the fourth quarters of 1986 and 1987
it rose by 8.9 per cent, and by a further 4.3 per cent by the fourth
quarter of 1988. Moreover world interest rates were changing relatively
little, and generally lower from those in the UK following the stock
market crash of October 1987. External financial variables had been the
most common trigger for rises in the level of UK interest rates
throughout the 1970s and 1980s. There was on this occasion no need to
tighten monetary policy in order to protect sterling. On the contrary
the official reserves were rising strongly. This was the period when
sterling was trying to 'shadow' the D-Mark, as if the UK were
a full member of the EMS. it might be expected nevertheless that
domestic policy, either fiscal or monetary, would have been tightened if
the domestic rate of inflation had been seen to be high or accelerating.
During 1987 however the average increase in the retail prices index was
only 4.2 per cent, and it was little higher at 4.9 per cent in 1988.
(Real interest rates were actually, very high in any historial
calculation.) The forecast rate of inflation was 4 per cent in the
Financial Statements of both the 1987 and 1988 budgets. The
Institute's forecasts were only a little more pessimistic; indeed
we remarked in the Review on how slight had been the impact of rising
demand on the price level (National Institute Economic Review, February
1988 page 7), explaining that unemployment was still high, productivity
was rising fast, and import prices were falling. The delay before the
inflationary threat became manifest was one reason for the delay in the
policy response.
An earlier symptom of excess demand was the deterioration in the
trade figures. The Institute was amongst the first to draw attention to
this, forecasting a serious balance of payments problem as early as the
summer of 1986 (National Institute Economic Review, August 1986, page
5). In the event the trade figures improved briefly in the early months
of 1987, before deteriorating very sharply by the end of that year. The
line taken by the government was that the balance of payments presented
no problem: it was the counterpart to a private sector financial
deficit, and would therefore be self-correcting.
Believers in the 'political business cycle' will argue
that action was not taken to reduce demand in 1987 because of the
approach of a general election. Some may even suppose that the boom was
deliberately engineered to suit the political timetable. The evidence on
this occasion does not fit that theory well. The 1988 Budget was
expansionary even though the election was over. The main rise in
interest rates did not come until the latter half of 1988. A cynic would
have predicted expansion in early 1987, with the brake sharply applied
by the end of the same year. A more important influence on policy was
the size of the PSBR, itself. We may argue that the scale of tax
measures at the time of the Budget should be judged in relation to the
state of the economy as a whole. In practice the state of the public
sector accounts tends to attract more attention. The PSBR expected at
the time of the 1987 Budget was 'only' 1 per cent of GDP; but
at the time of the 1988 Budget the accounts were in surplus. The
government, and many commentators said, and still say, that fiscal
policy was very tight. By implication that meant that it could not be
tightened further. A variety of explanations can be offered for the
policies adopted in 1987, independent of the economic forecasts being
made at the time. However, no explanation of the late 1980s would be
complete without a post-mortem on the unusually large errors made at
that time in forecasting the growth of demand and output.
Forecasting errors
Table D shows the forecasts of GDP growth published between
February and June 1988 by the Treasury and 18 independent forecasters.
For the year 1988 the convergence of views is remarkable. The range
extends only from 2.8 per cent to 3.6 per cent; no-one at all took a
significantly different view from the official Treasury forecasters. In
the event everyone in the table was wrong. The herd instinct did not
serve us well. (For the second year shown, the range was wider at 0.8
per cent to 3.3 per cent, and the average forecast, 2.0 per cent, was
very close to the mark).
Table E shows the official forecasts of both March 1987 and March
1988 in more detail. The errors in the components of demand were even
larger than the errors on GDP. The errors in GDP are about twice the
average error from previous forecasts; the errors on consumption and
investment in 1988 are three times the previous average. As the table
shows some of the discrepancies can be explained by inaccuracies in the
data available to the forecasters for the recent past. Thus in March
1987 the forecasters were told that consumers' expenditure had
increased by 41/2 per cent in 1986; we are now told that the rise had
been 51/2 per cent. This does not explain however why the forecasters
expected the growth rate of spending to slow down in 1987; in fact it
accelerated. A similar mistake was made by the forecasters in March
1988: again they were misled about the re growth of spending; again they
compounded the error by expecting a deceleration instead of even faster
growth in the next year. Recent statements have suggested that the
policy errors of the late 1980s were partly the result of poor
statistics(1). No doubt it would have been helpful if the coverage,
especially of the expenditure data, had been better. It would be wrong
however to see this as the main reason for the errors in forecasting
output growth.
Table F shows successive estimates of output growth based on the
three measures of GDP. The revisions to the output measure have been
negligibly small. This is the estimate preferred by the Institute as an
indication of annual growth rates, and used by us in forecasting
throughout the 1980s. We cannot attribute the errors we made in our
forecasts in the late 1980s to first estimates of the expenditure or
income measures, since we largely discounted them at the time. Yet we
made much the same errors as did the official forecasters. Like them we
saw the economy slowing down, when in fact it was about to speed up even
more.
Some of the factors which raised spending in the late 1980s cannot
be accounted for even after the event. These show up as
'residuals' in our present equations for consumer spending,
credit expansion and private investment. Taken together these
'residuals' raise the level of consumer spending by 2.4 per
cent in 1988, of investment by 3.4 per cent and of GDP by 1.2 per cent.
Further work is needed before we can explain in full the circumstances
which led to the boom of 1987 and 1988. in the last-three years we have
made progress by modelling better the influence of credit availability
and financial wealth on consumer spending. The next stage may be to deal
explicitly with consumer expectations. Could it happen again ? Having
reviewed the operation of monetary policy at the beginning of this year,
the authorities concluded that a reform of the method of control was not
appropriate. Direct control of credit was again ruled out as an option.
it also seems that little change is to be expected in the way that
fiscal policy is conducted. The question arises whether another
inflationary boom in the future could be avoided or corrected any more
successfully than that of the late 1980s.
The possibility of such conditions emerging in the forecast period
must be taken seriously. In the medium term, we expect interest rates to
fall sharply, raising asset values and reducing the cost of credit. We
hope that our model now takes account of the full effects this would
have on spending by persons and by companies, but the period since
credit was deregulated is too short for us to be confident that this is
the case. Asset values could again be inflated in the future to an
unknown extent, for example, by optimism aroused by the closer
integration of Europe. The approach of another general election will
also affect sentiment in a way that we cannot now foresee. The
possibility of a boom beginning in say 1992 certainly cannot be ruled
out.
It is to be hoped that next time, with improved statistics, better
econometric models, and heightened vigilance, the forecasters,
(ourselves included) will spot the boom in its early stages. It will
however be more difficult next time for the authorities to respond
quickly to such a warning if it is given to them. Once the UK is a full
member of the EMS, interest rates will have to be guided by the
prospects for the exchange rate. it will be fiscal policy (by default)
which will have to cope with disturbances to domestic demand. As things
stand, with Budgets just once a year, that response cannot easily be a
timely one.
PART THREE. THE FORECAST IN DETAIL
Forecasts of expenditure and output (table 1) We begin this
forecast with a higher exchange rate than we were expecting in the May
Review and higher than expected outturns for some expenditure categories
(such as consumers' expenditure and stockbuilding). The major
effect of these two factors is to raise our forecast of demand and
output for this year, with a correspondingly lower forecast for the
growth of output next year. Most of this year's forecast of 2 per
cent output growth occurs in the first half of the year and the path is
fairly flat thereafter. Our new assumption of 15 per cent base rates
persisting until mid-1991 adds to the depressing effect of a weaker
export performance next year (due to the loss in competitiveness) and
limits growth in output to around 2 per cent for 1991.
Previously we expected a fairly abrupt slowdown in consumers'
expenditure this year, but given the recent path of real incomes we now
believe that a gentler deceleration in consumption will continue into
next year. Our forecast profile for investment has also changed in
response to the recent higher than expected level of demand and our new
path for interest rates; although the sum of predicted investment growth
over this year and next is the same as our May forecast, it seems more
probable that there will only be a slight fall in investment growth, of
around 1 per cent this year, with an equally subdued recovery next year.
The large de-stocking we were expecting has not materialised
(de-stocking seems to be decreasing instead of increasing) and we are
now assuming only mild de-stocking this year.
The net contribution to output from the balance of payments is now
lower in this forecast for both 1990 and 1991. The higher general demand
this year has increased imports (we, like most other commentators, had
expected the high import intensity categories such as investment and
stockbuilding to experience a larger downturn) and the deterioration in
competitiveness, resulting from both a higher exchange rate and a higher
than expected inflation rate, will have a particularly damaging effect
upon exports next year. Personal income and expenditure (table 2)
Although there are various strong indications that the growth of
consumers' expenditure is decelerating from the rapid growth rates
of recent years (for instance the large fall in retail sales in June
which was only marginally offset by a mainly seasonal increase in July),
the general impression is that consumption is still showing some
resilience. Recent Gallup surveys of consumer confidence have shown a
recovery in all components of the consumer confidence index, although
the level of the index is still hovering around that recorded at the
trough of the 80/1 recession. The recent data on consumer credit and
bank lending give a stronger impression of a consumption slowdown but it
has been suggested that the lower rate of borrowing may be connected
with non-payment of the poll tax. The figures for the first quarter of
this year for total consumption are actually quite high although
expenditure on durables has obviously weakened substantially (UK new car
registrations are substantially down on last year).
Given the high level of interest rates combined with the low level
of consumer confidence resulting from falling house prices and rising
unemployment we are expecting subdued real consumption for the rest of
this year. Real disposable income will be boosted by the high rate of
wage inflation and some fiscal measures such as the continued reform of
national insurance contributions and independent taxation. Conversely,
but to a lesser extent, fiscal drag and lower growth in dividends and
overseas property income will have a negative impact upon income this
year. Given the high consumption outturn and the growth of disposable
income we expect the growth in consumers' expenditure to be around
3 per cent this year. The continuation of high interest rates through
1991, and the depressing effect of increased unemployment and
decelerating wage inflation upon disposable income, will probably
moderate consumers' expenditure further next year.
Fixed investment and stockbuilding (tables 3 and 4) The latest CSO survey of investment intentions for manufacturing industries indicated
that real manufacturing investment would increase by around 1 per cent
this year followed by a further larger increase next year. The survey
also revealed that investment in some of the UK's more successful
export industries-such as chemicals and electrical engineering-was
expected to experience even larger increases. At the time of the survey
the UK effective exchange rate was approximately 7 per cent lower than
its current level and this may explain why the July CBI industrial
trends survey gives a far more pessimistic view of the investment
intentions of manufacturing industry. The July CBI survey shows that
growth in export orders has now come to a standstill whereas in previous
surveys it seemed that growth in export orders sustained demand for
output even though home demand was weak. The survey also reveals that
capacity expansion as a reason for investment has decreased recently
which may be related to the bleaker export prospects. There are also
signs that downward pressure on profitability is affecting investment,
as 25 per cent of the firms surveyed by the CBI indicated that a
shortage of internal finance will inhibit their investment plans in the
year ahead. A larger proportion of firms are also citing the cost of
finance as a constraint on investment which may be a result of firms
resorting to more expensive external finance as internal funds dry up.
Our forecast seems consistent with most of the main findings of the
CBI survey. We are forecasting a fall in investment of 1 per cent this
year (with falls occurring mainly in manufacturing and construction). In
addition, the higher level of the exchange rate in our forecast
restrains export growth resulting in a further fall in manufacturing
investment next year. The combination of a higher exchange rate, high
interest rates and slow growth next year will probably restrict total
investment growth to around 1 per cent in 1991.
Recent stockbuilding figures show that substantially less
de-stocking took place in the first quarter of this year than the
previous quarter. In addition, the July CBI survey shows that stocks
have been run down less than predicted by the April survey. Although a
further period of de-stocking is anticipated by the CBI survey
respondents, the larger firms (over 5,000 employees) now expect a stable
trend in stockbuilding. It may be the case that these larger firms are
much more adept at maintaining stocks at more efficient lower levels by
using computerised stocks systems (this seems consistent with the rapid
decline in the stock/output ratio in recent years). Therefore, perhaps
less de-stocking is now appropriate when demand slows down as stocks are
already kept at minimum levels. Although there is downward pressure on
profit margins the relatively high level of profitability compared to
previous downturns may also partly explain why de-stocking is fairly
restrained so far. Given these factors and our upwardly-revised forecast
for output growth this year we now expect only mild de-stocking during
1990 with some subdued positive stockbuilding through 1991.
Balance of payments (tables 5 and 6)
Since our May Review the current balance deficit for 1989 has been
revised down from E!21 billion to 219 billion. The balance of payments
data for 1989 also reveal a large balancing item of 215 billion which is
virtually the size of the deficit itself. This implies that either
capital flows are under recorded or that the current account deficit was
actually much lower in 1989. Furthermore, the current balance for last
year would actually be in surplus if the substantial unrealised capital
gains on UK net overseas assets were recorded in the current account.
Given these data and conceptual problems associated with the
balance of payments statistics it is not surprising that some economists
argue that the UK current balance deficit is not a problem. However, the
recorded current account deficit for the first six months of this year
is already C9 billion and it will take more than data revisions to make
this disappear. This large deficit has persisted in the early part of
this year partly because domestic demand has not decelerated as much as
expected. In particular, the highly import intensive categories such as
investment and stockbuilding are slowing down at a fairly gentle pace.
Import volumes have therefore persisted at a high level in the first
half of the year. Export volumes, especially manufactured goods, have
been growing strongly but the latest figures suggest a recent
deceleration which supports the findings of the CBI survey that export
orders and optimism are losing their buoyancy. The UK oil trade balance
has been disappointing as oil production has experienced an extremely
muted recovery (there may be further production disruptions caused by
industrial unrest but a higher oil price may encourage a quicker
recovery of UK oil production). Given this rather bleak state of the UK
current balance the recent large increase in the UK exchange rate seems
inappropriate, as it will hinder an improvement in the trade deficit
next year. Partly because of these factors we have revised upwards our
forecast for the current account deficit to around 21 8 billion for this
year and we do not expect much of an improvement in 1991.
Although some of our more pessimistic trade forecast originates
from visible trade a large part of the poorer performance occurs in
invisible trade. Recent data for 1989 show that the overseas earnings of
'the City' have fallen for the third year in a row. The
banking sector was in international deficit for the first time since
1979. This is partly caused by the very high rates of interest paid by
UK residents borrowing foreign currency (presumably partly to pay for
the trade deficit itself) which has resulted in a large increase in net
interest payments paid overseas. With high interest rates expected in
the UK for some time there is little scope for an improvement here. The
recent surge upwards in sterling results in downward revaluations of our
assets abroad. Consequently, the already low level of net income
received from interest, profits and dividends will become even lower in
sterling terms. Although government transfers abroad should decrease
slightly on last year we are forecasting very low invisibles surpluses
for this year and next. Net exports of services do not grow much next
year as the higher exchange rate worsens UK competitiveness.
The latest data for the capital account indicate that direct
investment into the UK has remained at a high level in the first quarter
of this year with the two banks Morgan Grenfell and the Yorkshire Bank being purchased by Deutsche Bank and the National Australia Bank
respectively. UK portfolio investment overseas also exerted a positive
influence upon the basic balance (structural flows plus the current
balance) as actual portfolio disinvestment occurred in the first
quarter. It is partly for this reason that our forecasts for portfolio
investment outflows for this year and next have been revised downwards.
However, other factors discouraging portfolio investment abroad are the
high exchange rate, which reduces the sterling returns on assets held
overseas, and our assumption of a longer period of high interest rates
in contrast to our previous forecast of rapid cuts in interest rates.
However, the expected basic balance deficits for this year and 1991 are
still similar to our previous forecast, as the smaller net portfolio
outflows have been somewhat offset by larger current balance deficits.
Output and the labour market (tables 7 and 8) Unemployment has
increased over the last quarter. There have also been recent falls in
job vacancies and it seems that the slowdown in domestic demand is now
affecting employment growth. These aggregate figures tend to obscure
some interesting facts; unemployment is mainly rising in the south east,
it is actually continuing to fall in many other regions; female
unemployment is still falling, which means that male unemployment is
increasing faster than total unemployment; employment growth is still
occurring on a substantial scale (115,000 new jobs were created in the
first quarter of this year). Latest data show that the number of
overtime hours worked is declining, which provides further evidence of a
loosening in labour market conditions. in our forecast we expect
unemployment to increase at a faster rate in the second half of this
year and it will probably peak some time next year.
According to the CSO, manufacturing output is still on an upward
trend well into the second quarter of this year. This is surprising
given the demand slowdown but it does seem that the stronger
manufacturing output growth is concentrated in the UK's more
recently successful export industries such as the chemicals industry.
Non-manufacturing output is experiencing a sharper slowdown especially
in the energy sector which has been subdued by oil production problems
and the warm weather. The combination of manufacturing employment falls
and output growth has helped prevent manufacturing productivity
declining too much and latest data show that output per head is growing
at over 2 per cent at an annual rate (but for the whole economy output
per head is actually falling). A danger here is that manufacturing wage
settlements will incorporate this productivity growth and other sectors
will follow suit while achieving inferior productivity growth rates.
Our forecast sees manufacturing output growth falling from the
third quarter of 1990 as the recent growth in manufacturing output does
not seem sustainable or consistent with other data series (such as the
large falls in manufacturing capacity utilisation cited by CBI survey
respondents). The higher level of sterling is a major reason for the
expected decline in manufacturing output and as this depresses
manufacturing exports next year we also expect manufacturing output to
be subdued through 1991. Construction and distribution are two other
sectors for which we expect only modest growth over this year and next.
Growth in real GDP excluding oil for 1990 and 1991 is only slightly
different to total GDP as we are now forecasting a slower recovery in
oil output in the near future.
Wage and price inflation (tables 2,9 and 10)
After the impact of recent events upon the price of oil, the UK is
now facing the prospect of the RPI peaking at an annual rate that could
be closer to 11 per cent than 10 per cent. Less than six months ago the
Chancellor was forecasting that the RPI would be decelerating to around
71/4per cent by the fourth quarter of this year. We are now forecasting
retail price inflation to be around 3 percentage points higher than that
in the fourth quarter. Ourforecast of retail price inflation of just
under 8 per cent by the fourth quarter of next year is higher than
previously partly because underlying inflation is higher and also
because interest rates are not falling as rapidly.
Since the end of last year, sterling has risen and UK manufactures
have been faced with falling input prices (fuels and materials prices).
Yet manufacturing output prices have shown continual monthly rises
throughout this year. Rising unit labour costs, perhaps combined with a
reluctance to allow profit margins to decline must therefore account for
this discrepancy between input and output prices. Profit margins should
fall as demand slows down but output prices may also be reflecting
higher inflationary expectations which will be shared by wage
negotiators. Average earnings are currently rising at per cent (although
manufacturing earnings are only increasing by 91/4per cent). The latest
data also indicate a slight reduction in overtime hours in manufacturing
which, if it continues, will reduce wage drift (the difference between
wage settlements and average earnings). We are forecasting a 91/2per
cent increase in average earnings for this year with a slight
deceleration next year. This slowdown in wage inflation in 1991 should
result from lower productivity related payments and an increase in the
excess supply of labour which will manifest itself as an increase in
unemployment next year. However, our average earnings forecast could
prove too conservative if inflationary expectations are spiraling
upwards. Furthermore, some large companies will be implementing second
stages of pay deals based upon a certain percentage above inflation (for
instance, some Ford workers' pay rises will be the inflation rate
plus 2 1/2per cent).
The consumer price index will be subject to a discontinuity from
the second quarter of this year because of the treatment of the poll tax
in the National Accounts. Domestic rates were previously classified as a
tax on housing services and part of nominal consumers' expenditure
whereas the poll tax is treated as a deduction from income. As the
volume of housing services consumed will be the same, the volume of
consumer expenditure does not change. Consequently, the implied
consumers' expenditure deflator will fall, but this obviously does
not represent any change in underlying inflation. The main tables in the
Review now reflect these changes.
Public sector finance (table 11)
Optimism concerning the size of future public sector debt
repayments has substantially diminished since the 1989 Budget. At that
time, Nigel Lawson predicted a PSDR of 14 billion pounds for the 89/90
fiscal year whereas the actual debt repayment was only 98 billion. Three
main factors account for this over prediction of the public sector
surplus:
(1) Revenue from national insurance contributions was depressed by
the unexpectedly high take up of private pension plans.
(2) Spending by local authorities was boosted by the changeover to
the poll tax and additional capital expenditure was brought forward to
avoid new regulations introduced in the next financial year.
(3) Slower output growth adversely affected retail sales and
company profitability which reduced revenue from expenditure taxes and
corporation tax.
Therefore, forecasts for this financial year's PSDR begin from
a lower level and the latest Treasury forecast now expects a debt
repayment of around C7 billion for 90/1. However, this projection now
seems optimistic as recent data show a 6 1/2 billion pounds public
sector deficit for the first quarter of this fiscal year. Delayed poll
tax payments are partly responsible for this-forcing local authorities
to borrow at very high interest rates-and the financial situation should
improve as the year progresses and more arrears are paid. But higher
public spending is also a substantial cause of the deficit and it
remains to be seen whether the imposition of cash limits will restrain
spending to a greater extent in the latter part of this financial year.
There are several other factors which will have a negative impact upon
the PSDR this year; independent taxation of husband and wife and the
continued reform of national insurance contributions will further
depress revenue; rapid inflation feeding into public sector pay deals
will increase expenditure; a further slowdown in output will also have a
positive impact upon net expenditure as tax revenues increase less
rapidly and current grants increase as unemployment begins to rise.
Given these factors and allowing for privatisation receipts from
Powergen etc we expect a public sector debt repayment of around 24.5
billion for this financial year.
Public spending for the 91/2 financial year will be especially
difficult to control as it is a pre-election year. Ministers have
already made bids for 21 7 billion more than the current target figures
for next year. However, given our predicted recovery in output (and
hence revenues) in the latter part of 1991 and the governments assumed
privatisation proceeds of C5 billion, we expect a higher PSDR for next
year of approximately E8 billion.
Medium-Term Forecast
Once again, but to a greater extent this time, the balance of
payments tends to dominate the medium-term forecast. We envisage fairly
large and persistent current balance deficits for the next few years
with a substantial improvement only occurring in the mid-1 990s. With
fairly slow progress towards convergence to lower interest rates and
beginning from a high level for the exchange rate the deficit tends to
perpetuate itself. Large UK deficits require capital inflows which, in
turn, require higher relative returns (i.e. high UK interest rates)
which decrease UK net property income from overseas. This makes the
current account deficit worse, thus requiring greater capital inflows
etc. The high level of the exchange rate not only exacerbates the
visible trade deficit, but it also reduces IPD income paid in foreign
currency from overseas. Throughout the medium term we have export
volumes of goods and services growing more rapidly than imports. But
starting as we do from a high level of imports relative to exports, the
differential between export and import growth rates would have to be
much larger to deliver a trade surplus.
Given this outlook for the balance of payments we expect real GDP
growth in the medium term to be constrained to about 2 1/2 per cent a
year. Consumer spending over this same period should grow at a more
sedate pace (slightly below the growth rate of GDP) as the initial surge
effects of financial liberalisation comes to an end. However, tight
fiscal policy will be necessary to produce sufficient total savings to
keep the current balance deficit under control. The lack of tax cuts and
limited growth in public spending will restrain demand and also
encourage a more sustainable path for consumers' expenditure. Given
that a tight fiscal policy is necessary, since the scope for monetary
policy is limited within the ERM, and the probability that there will be
considerable public expenditure costs in areas such as defence, we
expect public sector debt repayments of around 1 1/2 per cent of GDP for
some time to come.
Our forecast produces an inflation rate that gradually converges
towards other European rates. However, this is a slow process and the UK
inflation rate is always above that of our European partners, right up
until the time of European monetary union around 1997. This inflation
differential is associated with the depreciation of sterling, which
continues even though the UK is assumed to participate in the
exchange-rate mechanism. The general path of decelerating UK inflation
throughout the medium term indicates that, at around 2 1/2 per cent GDP
growth, the UK is operating below its sustainable level of activity (in
other words, unemployment is greater than the NAIRU). Average earnings
growth is also forecast to move downwards towards European rates, which
is consistent with wage discipline being exerted from membership of the
ERM.
NOTES
(1) Monetary policy in the second half of the 1980s' lecture
by the Governor of the Bank of England at the University of Durham,
reprinted in the Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, May 1990. See also
'Official Statistics in the late 1980s' by J. Hibbard,
Treasury Bulletin, Summer 1990.