Chapter II. The world economy.
Barrell, R.J. ; Gurney, Andrew ; Dulake, Stephen 等
Uncertainties over the prospects for the oil price mean that the
short-term forecast is subject to a wider margin of error than usual.
The Iraqi invasion of Kuwait could lead to a reduction of world oil
production by at least eight per cent immediately and has already
produced a significant rise in oil prices. Our central forecast assumes
that in the short turmoil prices will stay firmer, but that in the
longer run there will be no major change in oil market conditions. We
have assumed that oil prices (or more precisely the arithmetic average
of Brent and Dubai spot prices) will be around $25 per barrel in the
second half of 1990, but that they will fall thereafter. This should
leave crude oil prices in the range 20-22 per barrel by the end of
1991. Annex I to the chapter investigates the effects of an oil price
rise on the world economy, and looks in particular at the distribution
of the effects across the major economies. The conclusion of the Annex
is that a 25 per cent rise in oil prices is likely to raise inflation in
the major seven economies by only a quarter to a half a per cent in the
short run, and to lower output by up to a half per cent.
We do not expect oil prices to stay high for long because the
reduction in supply from Iraq and Kuwait only partly offsets the current
situation of oversupply in the market. Unused oil production capacity in
the world is probably only just less than iraqi and Kuwaiti production,
although some of this capacity is located in the Gulf. Even if output
fell by the full amount of the two countries' production, stock
levels are very high. The combination of strategic reserves, commerical
stocks and stocks in producer countries combine to produce stocks that
would cover almost a full year's consumption. After some initial
turbulence the existence of these stocks, which relative to output are
double the level available in either 1974 or 1979, will put downward
pressure on prices. it is also the case that the response to the 1974
and 1979 oil price shocks increased the flexibility of the capital
stock, and it is possible to shift between primary energy sources more
quickly now than was possible in 1974. Chart 1 plots the past level of
the real oil price and also our forecast up to 1999. Although prices
fall in the short term we expect them to gradually strengthen over the
next decade. There are many differences between the scale and impact of
the last two oil crises and the current one. The oil intensity of output
in the advanced world has declined by 25 per cent over the last decade,
and oil production is only around its 1979 level. Any oil price change
will hence have less effect on prices and output. We are also not
anticipating that there is any prospect of oil price rises on the scale
observed in 1974 and 1979 partly because demand has become more elastic,
but also because OPEC is both less important, with less then 45 per cent
of output, and also much less cohesive than it was in the 1970s.
It is not only the oil market that is now different. The 1974 oil
crisis was preceded by rapidly rising commodity prices and a very sharp
acceleration in world demand and inflation. Commodity prices have now
been falling sharply for two years, and world output has already begun
to slow down. The 1979 oil crisis was preceded by a period of rising
inflation accompanied by relatively stagnant output, and although the
oil price rise contributed to inflation it was not the major cause of
the recession in 1980/1. The change of administration in the US (and the
UK) was accompanied by a shift in policies. Real interest rates in the
US, which had been negative, rose very rapidly, and the US real exchange
rate also rose. Real of the early 1980s had left most of the major
economies operating well below capacity. Chart 2 plots capacity
utilisation rates in the major economies since the mid-1980s.
Utilisation at the turn of the decade was higher than for at least ten
years, and as a consequence inflationary pressures began to develop in
all the major economies. Chart 3 plots recent and prospective
inflationary developments in the major four economies.
The reasons for the surge in growth during the late 1980s are still
unclear, but a number of factors contributed. The defence of the Louvre
accord exchange rates in 1987 led to large scale increases in foreign
exchange reserves especially in Germany and Japan. Although these flows
could have been fully sterilised neither country wanted to take on the
full interest rate consequences that this would have required and as a
result monetary conditions were loosened and monetary targets were
overrun in both countries. German central bank money targets were
overrun in 1986 and 1987, and even the change to M3 targeting in 1988
could not prevent a further overrun. Although the defence of the Louvre
accord exchange rates failed it did allow the US to export some of its
inflationary pressures to the rest of the world. The effect of this
monetary loosening was compounded by the effects of financial
deregulation which has led to a temporary rise in consumer spending in a
number of economies. The process of deregulation probably started
earlier and has proceeded further in the UK and consumption has risen
strongly as a result. Deregulation has also been under way in Japan,
albeit at a slower pace. Both France and then Italy have, partly as a
consequence of the decision to remove capital controls in 1990,
undertaken some degree of deregulation. The process is likely to extend
further, especially as the success of the European Commission's
1992 programme depends heavily on increased competition in financial
services. This is likely to have a particularly strong influence on the
availability of consumer credit in West Germany, where the banking
system has until recently been dominated by rather cumbersome regional
banks owned by the Lander.
The basically monetary cause of the increase in growth has been
followed by a basically monetary response from the authorities. Chart 4
plots recent changes in short-term interest rates over the last year in
the major four economies. German and Japanese short rates have risen
sharply whilst those in the US have been falling from peaks that were
achieved earlier. Chart 5 plots recent and prospective long rates. These
rose sharply in late 1989 and early 1990, especially in Germany and
Japan. Higher long rates indicate either that the market is anticipating
higher short rates over the period to maturity or that the risk premium
on long assets has risen. Anticipated short rates may have risen either
because inflation expectations have been revised up or because real
interest rates are expected to be higher. We feel that the rise in long
rates, especially in Germany, reflects all three factors. Unification
with the East is likely to put downward pressure on wages and increase
profit opportunities, raising rates of return. However, perceived risks
on the average future investment may have risen and as a result the
liquidity premium is likely to be higher. Finally, and we feel most
significantly, inflation expectations do appear to have been revised
upward throughout the major
The monetary response to rising inflation colours our whole
forecast, which is set out in table 1. US output growth appears to have
been slowing over the last year, and recent data revisions have reduced
estimates of growth in 1989 to 21/2 per cent, which is below our
estimate of capacity growth. The prospects for slower growth and hence
declining inflation have allowed the US authorities some space for
reducing interest rates, and the looser stance of monetary policy, along
with continuing Congressional delays to producing a tighter fiscal
stance, indicate that although growth may be as low as 1.5 per cent this
year it is likely to rise into 1991. Inflation in the US should reach a
peak in 1990, and we are forecasting that it will fall to 41/4 per cent
in 1991. Output growth in the US is expected to stay below capacity
until 1993, puffing downward pressure on price inflation. We expect that
inflation will have fallen to around 2.75 per cent from 1 994 onward.
The prospect for a soft, but successful deceleration in US
inflation has consequences for the rest of the world. In particular we
expect that world trade growth will slow down from an average of around
7 per cent over the last four years to around 4/4 per cent in 1990 and
5% per cent in 1991. Slower trade growth is a factor behind slower
Japanese growth in 1991. The weakness of the Yen in 1989 and 1990 is
already boosting Japanese exports, and this, in combination with strong
domestic demand and a strong contribution to GNP from net property
income from abroad, is expected to raise Japanese growth to around 5.5
to 6 per cent in 1990. Japan is still a relatively closed economy, and
the fall in the Yen is likely to have only a small impact on domestic
inflation, which we expect to settle just above 21/2 per cent a year.
Recent developments in Europe have insulated the major economies
there from the effects of the slowdown in the US. The prospect of
developments in Eastern Germany has given the West Germans a boost to
their growth, and hence has affected the prospects for the rest of
Europe. French and Italian growth are both expected to fall in 1990
after two to three years of growth in excess of capacity. The slowdown
is more marked in italy than in France. The latter country is currently
expected to return to full capacity growth with low inflation relatively
quickly.
Developments in Germany remain rather uncertain. The arrival of
over a million migrants in the last eighteen months has raised the
prospect for growth without excess inflation. We anticipate that the new
migrants will be absorbed into the workforce relatively slowly. These
workers, along with those who will now travel across the border to West
Germany and West Berlin will raise the rate of growth of productive
potential in the current Federal Republic. They will also put downward
pressure on wages. The combination will, we expect, allow West German
growth to average 3 per cent a year for much of the 1990s, compared to 2
per cent in the 1980s. Despite this acceleration in growth we are
anticipating that inflation will not exceed the level experienced in
1989. Our forecast for German growth is relatively smooth, reflecting
both the use of an estimated time series model and also a belief that
market mechanisms take time to adjust. However there are clearly severe
risks on both sides of our forecast. This may be the last time that we
are able to produce a forecast for the Federal Republic alone. There are
already plans to change the basis upon which statistics are produced.
The Bundesbank intends to move the current account statistics over to an
all-German basis immediately. This will be better than treating
intra-German trade as domestic trade, and it will reduce the world
current account discrepancy. it will make the comparison of new data
with the recent past more difficult. It is to be hoped that national
accounts data will continue to be produced for West Germany alone, as
this will make the interpretation and hence control of events
considerably easier. In the short term we do not anticipate that events
in Eastern Europe outside the GDR will have any noticeable impact on
developments in the West, although their longer-term implications may be
significant.
(c) Longer-term prospects
Our base forecast is predicated on a belief that the current oil
crisis is temporary and that the world economy resumes a process of
steady growth relatively quickly. in the 1980s discussions of
international economic problems were dominated by the issue of balance
of payments imbalance. A combination of developments in Europe and
structural changes in Japan appear to have reduced the potential scale
of such imbalances. Chart 6 plots the current account to GNP ratios for
the major 3 economies. This shows that we are expecting the scale of
capital flows to gradually decline. The pattern of world trade
imbalances that we are forecasting depends in part on our projections
for world trade shares. The forecast appreciation of the Yen along with
some structural change will produce some stabilisation of the Japanese
trade share at around 7 per cent. Meanwhile we expect that the US will
continue to regain its share of world trade which we expect to rise from
12 per cent in 1990 to around 14 per cent by the end of the decade.
We are anticipating that US pressure in the GATT round talks to
reduce food production and export subsidies will be successful, and that
this will contribute to the process of balance of payments adjustment in
the world economy. Chart 7 gives past paths for real commodity prices
along with our forecast and table 2 contains our forecast for all
commodity prices. We expect that real metals' prices will continue
to fall as the rate of technical change in mining and extraction is
expected to continue to exceed the rate of growth in demand. However we
are projecting rising free market real world food prices. This does not
necessarily mean that prices to consumers in the advanced world will be
any higher than they are currently. Agricultural subsidies are estimated
to cost the advanced world $250 billion a year. There are at least three
different farm support systems, all of which put downward pressure on
free market prices. The US subsidises and supports production of many
commodities. Prices are generally left to find their own level, although
up to the mid-1 980s the US authorities had considerable stockpiles
which were partly sold off during a vigorous export drive which put
downward pressure on prices in 1985 and 1986. The Japanese basically
prevent imports of rice, and domestic rice prices are more than ten
times higher than world prices. The gradual reduction of these barriers
will help support grain prices in general. The European Community has a
system of import levies and export subsidies that keep European prices
high and depress free market prices. This system is more visibly
distortionary than that in the US, but it has no more damaging effects
on the world economy. We are assuming that by the end of the 1990s real
world food prices will have returned to the levels experienced in the
first half of the 1980s. These developments will improve the US current
balance and worsen those of both Japan and Germany. Exchange rates and
interest rates Over the last three months the Dollar has weakened
against all the major currencies, partly in response to declining US
short rates, especially relative to those in Japan and Germany. Over the
year to the end of July 1990 the Yen had depreciated by 14 per cent and
the D-Mark had risen by 9 per cent in effective terms.
The weakness of the Yen has been a little hard to understand given
the size of the Japanese current account surplus, and as we anticipated
in our last Review, the Yen has recovered (by 3 per cent in effective
terms) over the last three months. Over the last decade the Japanese
current account surplus has averaged over 2 per cent of GNP, and in the
4 years prior to 1989 it averaged more than 3.5 per cent. Part of this
large scale capital outflow reflects the gradual abolition of exchange
controls and restrictions on portfolio composition. (These restrictions,
and their implications for the rest of the world, are discussed in Pain
(1990), which emphasises their importance to the UK). Flows resulting
from portfolio reallocation can be seen as temporary, but we have argued
elsewhere that there are demographic and other reasons for a sustained
capital outflow from Japan (see Barrell and Wren-Lewis 1989). We expect
those outflows to continue for some time, and hence a relatively large
current account surplus has to be achieved. Annex 11 to this chapter
shows that there has been some structural change in the Japanese trade
accounts, and that at constant competitiveness the current account would
now be some $36 billion higher if income and price elasticities had
stayed the same as they were in 1985. We believe that the markets and
the authorities had not fully taken account of these structural changes
when they allowed the Yen to appreciate strongly into 1989. The rather
rapid deterioration of the current account in 1989 can be seen as
news', and it caused the market to re-adjust its evaluation of the
Yen.
There has been much discussion of the FEER (fundamental equilibrium
exchange rate) for the Yen and its relation to PPP (purchasing power
parity). There is normally a large discrepancy between these two
estimates of the equilibrium exchange rate, especially if the PPP rate
is in excess of 200 Yen per Dollar, which would imply a much larger
surplus on the current account. We prefer the FEER, which is based on
both our estimates of the trade elasticities and on our judgement of the
scale of structural capital flows. it is not possible to uniquely define
an equilibrium bilateral rate against the Dollar when we discuss the
FEER because it is the level of competitiveness against all currencies
together that determines the size of the current account. However, at
current exchange rates for currencies such as the D-Mark and the Franc
we would judge that the FEER for the Yen is around 140-5 Yen per Dollar.
The evolution of the Dollar Yen FEER over time depends not only on the
complete pattern of bilateral rates but also upon the prospective paths
for prices in all the countries involved. As the Yen is at around its
FEER and as Japanese inflation is expected to stay below that in the US
and elsewhere we would expect the Yen to continue to appreciate in
nominal terms in order to stay around its real FEER level. We also
expect the scale of structural capital flows to decline over the next
decade, and this will put further upward pressure on both the real FEER
and, we presume, the nominal effective exchange rate. Table 3 gives our
projections for all exchange rates and chart 8 the past and expected
paths for effective exchange notes.
It is much more difficult to assess the prospects for the D-Mark in
terms of its FEER. Until last Autumn we had been expecting large scale
capital outflows from Germany to continue for some time. These reflected
not only the savings behaviour of the population but also the relatively
low rate of return to real investment in Germany compared to those
available elsewhere. Developments since November have changed our
judgement. Firstly the influx of migrants is likely to reduce savings
and also, by putting downward pressure on real wages, raise returns to
investment. Secondly unification with Eastern Germany will open up
considerable scope for further investment both in the Federal Republic,
and also in the East, which for current account purposes has always been
treated as part of Germany. As a result we expect that capital outflows
will fall.
It is easy to predict that capital flows will decline, and to
presume that the D-Mark will be under pressure to appreciate, and the
recent strong appreciation of the D-Mark reflects this pressure. However
it is difficult to judge the level of the D-Mark at which the FEER will
be achieved. If all other exchange rates stay round about their current
levels we would judge that the FEER for the D-Mark against the Dollar
would be around 1.55 to 1.65 D-Mark per Dollar. However there is
considerable uncertainty as to this range. In particular it depends upon
our estimate of the Sterling/D-Mark FEER. it is difficult to assess the
UK FEER as it depends on our estimates of capital flows (see Wren-Lewis
et al where the issue is discussed more fully using the Institute's
domestic model).
The judgement of the level of equilibrium exchange rates is
important when assessing the prospects for stability in the European
Exchange Rate Mechanism, and also for evaluating the prospects of the
successful formation of a European Monetary Union. Even inside a
Monetary Union the current balance of any component member will be
driven toward some sort of equilibrium. If on entry the exchange rate is
such that a large current account deficit exists then there will be a
tendency for wealth to decline. if the rate of change in wealth exceeds
that desired by savers they will adjust their consumption plans in order
to reach their target wealth path. Individuals in the economy will only
reach their target wealth path when the current account deficit is
consistent with that target. Our estimates of the FEER depend upon a
current account that is consistent with domestic equilibrium. Although
there are automatic forces causing adjustment these are likely to be
slow acting, and it would seem desirable for entry to EMU (or even the
ERM) to be judged in the light of the relationship between the real
exchange rate and the FEER for each member of the Union.
We are assuming that these considerations affect the policy making
process in Europe, and that we will see a two speed progression to
union. Given current exchange rates and projected inflation paths and
fiscal policies the core European economies of France, Germany and the
Benelux countries are assumed in our forecast to successfully form a
monetary union in 1995. Italian membership of a Monetary Union will have
to wait until their fiscal stance is less expansionary. Given current
policy plans we think that membership will be a serious possibility by
1997. In that year we are assuming that both italy and the UK will be
able to join the Union without any major disruption to their economies.
Of course, if Italian fiscal policy tightens more rapidly then we are
projecting so that the equilibrium wealth trajectory is reached earlier,
then they may be able to join the Union in 1995. Similar caveats
concerning inflation and the exchange-rate projections have to be made
about our assumption that the UK joins the Union in 1997.
Table 4 gives our forecast for interest rates in 1990 and
thereafter. As we are assuming that the shock to the oil price is
temporary we see no need for a tightening of monetary policy. in the
short term we are expecting that Japanese rates will rise because of
rising concern over inflation. Elsewhere we expect that rates will begin
to decline slowly as inflation falls from its 1990 peak. We assume that
in the long run real interest rates will be around 3 per cent, slightly
higher in current balance deficit countries and slightly lower in
surplus countries. As Monetary Union approaches interest rates in Europe
have to converge. This is only partly because the authorities will be
pushing rates together. The major convergence will, however, result from
market forces. Although it is possible to justify country specific risk
premia even in a monetary union (as there are state specific risk premia
in the US) these must be limited in scale. We assume that there will be
no risk premium on the French Franc (or more correctly to ECU holders in
France) vis a vis the D-Mark, and that as a result of Union German rates
will be a little higher, and French rates a little lower than they would
otherwise have been. We are assuming that Italian rates in general stay
above those in the rest of the Union. Barrell (1990) argued that such
differentials could exist because of portfolio preferences. However, the
'risk premium' must be much lower than the ex-post 4 per cent
observed between Germany and Italy in the 1980s. This was probably the
result of both effective capital controls and a more successful
anti-inflationary stance than the markets had anticipated. The United
States Since our May forecast there has been a revision of the US
national accounts statistics. The revised figures show US GNP growth of
2.5 per cent in 1989 compared to 3.0 per cent in the previous estimates.
The most significant revision has been to consumers' expenditure,
now estimated to have grown by 1.9 per cent in 1989, down from 2.7 per
cent previously. The figures for real personal disposable income have
also been revised sharply from 4.1 per cent to 2.4 per cent for 1989, so
that despite the lower growth of expenditure, the saving ratio in 1989
is also now thought to be lower than previously estimated.
Preliminary estimates of GNP are available for the second quarter
of 1990. These indicate GNP growth of 1.2 per cent compared to a year
previously, with domestic demand growing by 1.1 per cent and net exports
adding 0.1 percentage points to GNP growth. GNP growth in the year to
the first quarter is estimated at 1.3 per cent, with domestic demand
growing by 0.9 per cent. It now appears that GNP growth in 1990 will be
the lowest since the recession of 1982.
The weakening of consumers' expenditure growth that appears
in the revised 1989 figures has continued into the first half of 1990.
in the second quarter of 1990 consumers' expenditure is estimated
to have been only 1. 1 per cent higher than a year previously. The
decline in consumers' expenditure growth is associated with a lower
growth of real personal disposable income, which in turn appears to have
been caused by a lower growth in employment in the fourth quarter of
1989 and the first half of 1990. investment expenditures have also been
weak in recent months. In the second quarter of 1990 housing investment
was 3.5 per cent lower than a year previously and business investment
only 0.2 per cent higher. Domestic demand growth has therefore entered a
cyclical downturn following seven consecutive years in which GNP growth
exceeded 2.5 per cent per annum.
The decline in the rate of growth of demand has not yet had a
significant effect on the rate of inflation. In June consumer price
inflation stood at 4.7 per cent, down from 5.3 per cent in February, but
only fractionally below the 4.8 per cent for 1989 as a whole. The
appreciation of the Dollar over the first 3 quarters of 1989 will have
reduced imported inflation in the early months of this year, but our
forecast of a subsequent depreciation, together with higher oil prices
will cause import prices to rise again in the second half of the year.
The labour market shows some signs of weakening demand. Total
non-farm payrolls increased by 123,000 per month in the second quarter
compared to gains of 160,000 per month in the second half of last year.
Manufacturing employment fell by 27,000 in May and 31,000 in June.
Unemployment, on the other hand, also fell in June to 5.2 per cent,
suggesting that the labour market remains fairly tight. Weekly earnings
in the second quarter were 3.7 per cent higher than a year earlier, up
from 3.4 per cent in the first quarter.
Monetary policy has remained unchanged, despite the evidence of a
deceleration of the rate of growth. This has led to some speculation
that the Federal Reserve would lower interest rates. The Fed Funds rate
was eased from 8.25 per cent to 8.0 per cent in mid-July, but the
official discount rate remained unchanged at 7 per cent. Our assumption
is that the Fed is likely to maintain interest rates at current levels
for the remainder of the year. A reduction might occur, however, if
third quarter GNP figures suggest that the downturn was developing into
a recession, although the inflationary impetus of the rise in oil prices
is likely to reinforce the case for maintaining current levels.
Our forecast for the United States is presented in Table 5. The
data available for the first half of this year suggest that 1990 will
see the lowest growth-rate since 1982, at 1.5 per cent. The main cause
is the slower growth of domestic demand, with consumers'
expenditure and non-housing investment growing less strongly, and
housing investment again in recession. Net exports should however
continue to add to GNP growth, aided by a depreciation of the Dollar
since the third quarter of 1989, and by the slow growth of domestic
demand while export markets remain relatively buoyant.
Some commentators have expressed a fear that the decline in the
growth of economic activity may develop into a recession. This is a risk
that cannot be completely discounted, especially if the disruption in
the oil market further reduces business optimism. We expect, however
that consumers' expenditure will pick up again in the second half
of the year, providing a stimulus for investment and GNP growth. Our
forecast for 2% per cent growth in 1991 is based on an oil price of $20
per barrel by the middle of the year. The simulation contained in Annex
1 indicates that if oil prices remain $25 per barrel then US growth in
1991 would be around 21/4 per cent.
Inflation this year is expected to be 4.7 per cent. On the
assumption of oil prices of $20 per barrel we expect that inflation will
decline to 3.9 per cent next year, but an oil price of $25 per barrel
would result in inflation remaining at around 4.5 per cent. In these
circumstances it is unlikely that the gradual easing of interest rates
that we have assumed in our main forecast would actually take place.
The US current account deficit is a half solved problem. The
depreciation of the Dollar from its peak in early 1985 has enabled a
deficit of $144 billion in 1987 to be reduced to $1 1 0 billion last
year. Our forecast, presented in Table 6, indicates further declines
this year and next. As a proportion of GNP the deficit has reduced from
3.2 per cent in 1987 to a forecast 1.8 per cent in 1990. it is unlikely
that gains will be as rapid in the years to come, primarily because we
expect that the nominal value of the Dollar will remain at around its
current level against a basket of other currencies. Our medium-term
forecast suggests that the current account deficit has now been reduced
to a sustainable level, but that the problem has not been completely
eliminated since the size of the deficit will constrain the rate of US
domestic demand growth. We anticipate that fiscal policy in particular
will have to remain tight in order to prevent a re-escalation of both
the current account and the public sector deficits.
Table 7 gives our projections for the US fiscal deficit. The
Federal deficit for the first 9 months of fiscal 1990 stood at $163.1
billion, well in excess of the Budget prediction of $124 billion and the
Balanced Budget net target of $1 00 billion. The target for fiscal 1991
is $64 billion, but it seems very unlikely that it will be achieved.
Growth has been slower than anticipated this year and hence revenues are
likely to be lower than originally forecast. In the longer term there
remains the prospect of cuts in defence expenditure, but the cost of
guarantees extended to the troubled savings and loan sector will also be
higher than estimated a year ago. We are projecting that these could add
over $10 billion to spending in the short run, although this may be
offset by asset sales in the longer run. President Bush has now conceded
that tax increases will be necessary to reduce the deficit, but there
are still doubts about political resolve, especially since there are
Congressional elections later this year. We anticipate that the Federal
deficit will be gradually reduced, but at a slower rate than prescribed by the Balanced Budget Act. The deficit of the public sector as a whole
is currently around $40 billion less than the Federal deficit, and is
forecast to be in surplus by 1997, mainly because of an increased
surplus on the Social Security Fund.
Japan
A sustained bout of uncertainty afflicted the financial side of the
Japanese economy in the first half of this year. The Yen depreciated by
10.5 per cent between the end of January and the end of April,
stock-market prices fell by 28 per cent between the end of December and
the beginning of March, and long-term interest rates rose by 1.2
percentage points between December and March. These developments cannot
be attributed directly to the performance of the real economy, which
grew by 5.6 per cent in the year to the first quarter of 1990. Nor do
they seem related to the prospects for inflation, which while rising
from 1.7 per cent in 1989, registered only 2.6 per cent in the first
quarter of 1990.
The adverse reaction of both financial and foreign-exchange markets
is probably best explained in terms of a correction of their previous
misalignment. Shares on the Japanese stock-market have for some years
had markedly higher price-earnings ratios than similar shares in other
markets, which could only be economically justified if there was a
compensating expectation of substantially higher earnings growth for
Japanese firms. The appreciation of the Yen between 1985 and 1988
resulted in a reduction of the current account surplus from 4.3 per cent
of GNP in 1986 to 2.0 per cent in 1989. This was perhaps excessive given
the extent of Japanese capital outflows, necessitating some depreciation
of the Yen to bring current and capital account flows into balance. The
simultaneous adjustment of stockmarket portfolios may have resulted in a
temporary increase in capital account outflows, exacerbating the
short-term depreciation of the Yen. We retain our assumption that the
Yen will appreciate in the second half of this year to 146 Yen/Dollar in
the fourth quarter, as this temporary outflow subsides.
The Japanese monetary authorities have faced a dilemma in
responding to these developments. On the one hand the weakness of the
Yen could lead both to an increase in imported inflation and to an
increase in external demand for Japanese goods. Indicators of capacity
utilisation suggest that the economy is already close to capacity
output, and hence there is a high risk that extra demand will further
fuel inflation. Our model equations for Japanese wholesale and consumer
prices contain significant effects from capacity utilisation. On these
grounds there was a case for raising interest rates. On the other hand
an increase in interest rates risked throwing financial markets into
greater turmoil. in the event the official discount rate was raised by 1
percentage point in March to 5.25 per cent, following rises of 0.5
percentage points in October and December of last year. Monetary policy
is therefore much tighter than a year ago. This has helped to stabilise the value of the Yen, which appreciated 3.5 per cent between the end of
April and the end of July. Even so the Yen was 12.5 per cent lower than
in July 1989, and there are fears that interest rates will have to be
raised further in order to dampen the inflationary consequences. Renewed
weakness in the Yen evident in early August and the rise in the oil
price following Iraq's invasion of Kuwait make a further increase
more likely. We have assumed that interest rates are increased 0.5
percentage points in the third quarter of 1990, and start to come down
again during 1991.
Japanese GNP grew by 5.6 per cent in the year to the first quarter
of 1990, up from 4.8 per cent for 1989 as a whole. Domestic demand grew
by 5.5 per cent and net exports added 0.1 percentage points to GNP
growth. Domestic demand growth continued to be led by business
investment, which was up by 14.5 per cent in the year to the first
quarter of 1990 following rises of 15.7 per cent and 17.7 per cent in
1988 and 1989. In its May Short-term Economic Outlook the Bank of Japan
reported that many manufacturing firms had revised up their capital
investment plans from an increase of 7.5 per cent to one of 16.5 per
cent for the year ending March 1991. Other business survey evidence
suggests both continuing optimism about production prospects and a high
level of capacity utilisation. It therefore seems likely that the high
level of investment will continue for a third successive year. This
should raise productive potential and ease existing capacity
constraints.
Japanese labour market indicators reveal that the market is
extremely tight. Seasonally adjusted unemployment stood at 2.1 per cent
in May, up slightly from March, but still around the lowest level for 1
0 years. The ratio of job vacancies to job seekers rose to 1.37 in
February, the highest for 16 years, and has since eased marginally.
While employment growth has been strong, the tight labour market has
been eased by the increasing participation of female workers,
particularly in service industries. The effect of the tighter labour
market was also evident in the settlements reached in the annual spring
wage round, which averaged around 6 per cent this year, compared with
5.1 per cent in 1989 and 4.4 per cent in 1988.
Our forecast for Japan is presented in table 8. We expect GNP
growth to increase to 5.9 per cent this year. Domestic demand growth is
expected to fall to 4.9 per cent but net exports could add 1.0
percentage points to GNP growth. Net exports are also expected to add 1.
1 percentage points to GNP growth in 1991. This strong performance is a
consequence of the depreciation of the Yen, which fell by 11.5 per cent
between the fourth quarter of 1988 and the fourth quarter of 1989, and a
further 1 1.0 per cent by the second quarter of 1990. The Yen is
expected to appreciate in our forecast by around 2 per cent per annum,
and so does not reach its 1989 fourth quarter level until the first
quarter of 1996. In the interim there is a strong competitiveness gain.
In this forecast we have used the new Japanese trade equations reported
in Annex II. The new equations for export volumes and non-oil import
volumes both have high competitiveness elasticities, and hence suggest
that the depreciation of the Yen will have a significant effect.
Domestic demand growth is expected to be sustained by continued
strong growth in business investment, in line with survey evidence. The
growth of consumers' expenditure is likely to be around 3.0 per
cent, slightly less than last year. Real personal disposable income
growth has been reduced by higher than expected inflation, and
consumers' expenditure has also been curbed by higher interest
rates and a new sales tax introduced last year.
Inflation is expected to rise to 3.0 per cent this year. This
increase can be attributed in part to the recent weakness of the Yen
which may have contributed up to 1/2 of the increase. However, tight
labour markets and high capacity utilisation have also put upward
pressure on costs. Inflation in 1990 will however no longer be boosted
by the new sales tax introduced in April 1989.
Our main forecast is based on an oil price of $20 by the middle of
next year. This leads to a decline in Japanese growth to 41/4 per cent
in 1991. The principal cause is a decline in domestic demand, following
the increase in interest rates which we are expecting in the second half
of this year. The growth in business investment declines to 3.5 per cent
and the level of residential investment falls by 2.3 per cent. We
anticipate a further increase in inflation to 31/2 per cent, as the
effects of the Yen's depreciation and the increase in oil prices
continue to be felt. However we also expect the Yen to start
appreciating, so that the inflationary impulse arising from a weak
currency will start to reverse.
Germany
German GNP grew by 4.4 per cent in the year to the first quarter of
1990. This was stronger than the growth-rates of 3.0 per cent and 3.7
per cent recorded in the year to the third and fourth quarters of 1989.
German GNP is forecast to grow strongly this year and next, partly
through the stimulus expected from German economic union, and the
expected political union. However the pattern of expenditure contained
in the first quarter GNP figures cannot be wholly attributable to the
effects of reunification. Consumers' expenditure benefited from
cuts in direct taxation at the start of the year, and investment in
construction was boosted by another mild winter. Export growth was also
strong in the first quarter.
Germany is now entering its eighth consecutive year of economic
growth and third consecutive year of growth in excess of 3 per cent.
During the latter period the rate of capacity utilisation in
manufacturing industry has risen from 84.1 per cent to 89.7 per cent.
However inflation has remained under control. There was a temporary rise
to 3.1 per cent in 1989, following the increase in indirect taxes at the
start of that year, but inflation in 1990 has eased slightly. This is
due both to the absence of the indirect tax effect which increased
inflation in 1989, and to the appreciation of the D-Mark in late 1989
which has resulted in lower imported inflation. In May 1990 import
prices were 5.4 per cent lower than a year earlier, wholesale prices 0.2
per cent lower and consumer prices 2.3 per cent higher.
In the short term further progress in reducing inflation is likely
to be limited, given rising cost pressures in the labour market. Recent
wage settlements of 6.3 per cent in the construction industry and 6.8
per cent in the printing industry are well above the rate of inflation.
Good company profits, a high rate of capacity utilisation, and the
expectation that strong economic growth will be sustained in both the
short and medium-term have all contributed to the increases. However,
the influx of migrants into the labour force should be putting immediate
downward pressure onto wages and prices.
After raising interest rates on four occasions in 1989, the
Bundesbank has maintained them at the levels set last October. Monetary
policy has therefore remained constant despite some expectations that
German economic and monetary union might lead to further tightening. The
decline in inflation that has occurred this year may be seen as
justifying this stance. There seems to be little evidence that German
economic union has resulted in a surge of consumer spending, but there
is a possibility that a further interest-rate rise may be provoked by
the consequences of economic union. Interest rates are unlikely to fall
until the Bundesbank is convinced that inflationary pressures have been
curtailed. As we expect strong economic growth to continue this year, we
do not anticipate any reductions in interest rates until next year at
the earliest.
Economic and monetary union has altered the likely stance of fiscal
policy. Government spending will rise in order to finance unemployment
benefits and pensions. In addition East Germany requires considerable
investment in its infrastructure, and much of this may have to come from
public spending. Government revenue grew more strongly than had been
expected in 1989 due to the higher than expected rate of growth, and
continued strong growth of economic activity will help to finance some
of the extra spending.
Our forecast for West Germany is presented in table 10. Following
the strong growth of GNP in the first quarter we now expect that growth
for the year will be 3.8 per cent. Consumers' expenditure is
expected to grow by 4.5 per cent, boosted by the tax cuts at the start
of the year, and by the spending of the immigrants who entered Germany
at the end of last year. investment expenditure is also likely to grow
strongly, with investment in housing boosted by the extra demand
associated with immigration, and business investment by the stimulus of
monetary
We expect that GNP growth will decline to 31/4 per cent next year,
as consumers' expenditure grows less strongly. The stimulus of
direct tax cuts will no longer be operating, although there will be some
additional impetus provided by continuing immigration and higher demand
for West German goods from the East. Investment expenditure should also
remain strong as the German economy is re-structured to supply its
expanded market.
Our forecast for inflation is 2.9 per cent for 1990, and 3.0 per
cent for 1991. it is still somewhat early to judge the effect of German
monetary union, although preliminary evidence suggests that the surge in
demand for West German goods that some commentators had feared did not
occur. The East Germans appear to have been cautious in their spending,
which is understandable given the likelihood of rising inflation and
unemployment in the East.
The effect on East German unemployment appears to be in line with
the more pessimistic predictions. Many of the old East German
enterprises appear to be unviable within the union without substantial
investment from the West. Unfortunately investment from the West has
been less vigorous than many had hoped. An important factor here is the
confusion that remains over ownership of East German firms' assets.
The initial monetary union agreement embodied the right of repossession by some pre-1948 owners of assets. This is an area that requires urgent
attention in order to speed up the integration of the economies of East
and West. Failure to tackle the problem will mean that East Germany will
continue to suffer from insufficient investment, and the consequent high
unemployment will mean that it will act as a drain rather than a spur to
the German economy.
Table 12 presents our forecast for the German public sector. Strong
revenue growth in 1989 led to a surplus of D-Mark 5 billion, equivalent
to 0.2 per cent of GNP. This was the first annual surplus since 1973,
and represented a sharp improvement from the deficit of D-Mark 45
billion recorded in 1988. As 1990 is forecast to be another year of
strong growth, revenues should again grow strongly, although the income
tax cut introduced at the start of the year will cost the government
D-Mark 25 billion. Expenditures will also rise strongly this year
because of the costs of economic and monetary union. The Federal Budget
of December 1989 has had to be supplemented by two further budgets
making provisions for D-Mark 11.8 billion of extra spending. We
anticipate that the general government will return to deficit this year
of around D-Mark 18 billion. The costs associated with political union
are likely to lead to to continuing deficits in the early 1990s despite
buoyant revenue growth derived from the continuing strength of German
economic activity.
BOX 1. THE TREATMENT OF GERMAN UNIFICATION IN OUR FORECAST
Our forecast is constructed using our econometric model, GEM. The
equations in GEM have been estimated from data on the West German
economy, and reflect its performance over the last twenty-five years.
The following special adjustments have had to be made to allow for the
likely effects of German unification on the behaviour of the West German
economy over our forecast period. Some are discussed more fully in the
World Economy chapter of the May 1990 National Institute Economic
Review.
(a) Consumers' expenditure. We expect this to grow by more
than our equation would predict because of the extra expenditures by
immigrants into West Germany, and because of additional spending in the
West by East Germans following monetary union. This latter effect will
be included in the National Accounts as spending by West German
citizens.
(b) Investment This too should grow by more than our equations
would predict. Residential investment will be boosted by the extra
demand arising from immigration. Business investment is expected to be
higher as German industry equips itself for meeting both the demand of
the expanded German market for both consumer and producer goods, and
also increased demand from other East European countries.
(c) Employees' wages and salaries. We expect downward
pressure on average earnings as the economy absorbs an expanded labour
supply, both from immigrants and also from workers crossing the border
from lower wage areas in East Germany where they are not used to
receiving western levels of pay. This downward pressure will help to
reduce some of the inflationary pressures arising from higher demand,
and should help the German economy to grow more rapidly than in the
1980s without incurring inflationary bottlenecks.
(d) Public sector. We have made various adjustments to our model of
the German public sector. Firstly transfers have been increased, by DM
15 billion a year, in the early years of the decade. This represents
both payments to migrants and support for the East German economy.
Secondly we have raised West German public debt by DM30 billion. This
represents the sum that the Federal government has taken over at par to
ensure that the banking sector in the East remains solvent.
(e) Balance of payments. We have made some adjustments to our trade
equations. The German authorities have never treated intra German trade
as external trade, and hence although exports to the East appeared in
the national accounts they did not appear in the trade accounts. Our
export volume data came from the trade accounts and hence should be
basically unaffected by the changes in East Germany. We have however
made some adjustment to our German exports forecast on the assumption
that they increase their share of Central European markets over the next
decade.
France
French GDP rose by 3.6 per cent in 1989. Although this was lower
than the 3.9 per cent growth experienced in 1988 it was nonetheless
higher than the government's forecast of 3 to 31/2 per cent. The
growth of the French economy during 1989 can be attributed to the
sustained expansion of business investment and buoyant exports, as well
as strong growth in consumers' expenditure. Business investment
grew by 7.2 per cent in 1989, reflecting both the profitability of and
capacity constraints on French industry. Capacity utilisation was 86.0
per cent in the fourth quarter of 1989, its highest level since 1973.
The volume of exports grew by 8.3 per cent in 1989, aided by a lower
exchange rate, lower labour costs (trend unit labour costs fell for the
third year in succession), and strong demand growth in the rest of the
world. Net exports contributed positively to the growth of the French
economy for the first time since 1984. Unemployment continued to fall in
1989, whilst inflation increased modestly from 2.7 per cent in 1988 to
3.3 per cent in 1989.
The overriding objective of French monetary policy has been to
maintain the value of the Franc vis-a-vis the D-Mark. To this end,
monetary policy was progressively tightened during 1989 as interest
rates were raised in Germany. This tightening led the Franc to
appreciate to its highest level in effective terms since mid-1986,
causing the Banque de France to cut its intervention rate by 0.5
percentage points in April of this year. Our forecast assumes firstly
that the exchange rate moves in line with risk adjusted interest-rate
differentials and also that a monetary union between France, Germany and
the Benelux countries is formed in 1995.
The growth of real GDP slowed to 0.6 per cent in the first quarter
of 1990 from 0.9 per cent in the fourth quarter of 1989. Strong growth
in consumer spending and also in fixed investment was more than offset
by a decline in industrial output and stocks. The slowdown in the French
economy has manifested itself both in terms of higher unemployment and
lower inflation. Unemployment rose by 3200 to 2.512m in June, although
unemployment is still 0.6 per cent lower than it was a year ago.
Consumer prices rose by only 0.2 per cent in June and the inflation rate
fell to 3.0 per cent, the lowest since 1988.
Our forecast for the French economy is set out in table 13. in 1990
we are forecasting that the growth of the French economy will slow
further to 2.6 per cent. Consumption growth is forecast to remain strong
through 1990, reflecting buoyant real personal incomes. (We have
recently recast our French personal income database and re-estimated all
the associated equations giving us a much firmer base for our forecast.)
Although higher interest rates will result in a slowing of private
investment growth to 4.2 per cent in 1990, compared to 5.7 per cent in
1989, we expect the growth of domestic demand to decline only
marginally. Therefore the slowing of the French economy in 1990 may be
attributed almost entirely to the deterioration in the external
environment. A higher exchange rate and a slowing in the growth of world
trade will result in net exports reducing GDP growth by 0.8 per cent in
1990. However, a higher exchange rate and higher interest rates are
likely to exert renewed downward pressure on inflation, and we are
forecasting that inflation will fall to 2.7 per cent this year. These
developments, coupled with the strong growth of domestic demand in
Germany, are liable to result in French inflation falling below that in
Germany, albeit marginally. This is likely to give the authorities the
opportunity to make further cuts in interest rates later this year, and
we are assuming that short-term interest rates are reduced by 0.4
percentage points between the second and fourth quarters of 1990.
The deterioration in the external environment and the slowing of
the French economy are liable to have a profound effect upon the export
and import volume of goods in 1990. We are forecasting a significant
reduction in the growth of trade volumes in 1990: exports of goods are
forecast to grow by only 4.2 per cent in 1990 after their strong
performance in 1989, whilst imports are set to grow by 4.4 per cent in
1990 as compared to 7.3 per cent in 1989. We are forecasting that the
current account will move further into deficit in 1990 despite an
improved visible balance. The immediate decline in the invisibles
balance in response to an appreciation is forecast to more than offset
the J-curve effect on the visible balance. This improvement can be
attributed to an improvement in the terms of trade. In 1991 we are
forecasting a significant deterioration in, the current account,
reflecting both the continued movement into deficit of invisibles and a
worsening in the terms of trade. Italy
Italian GDP grew by 3.2 per cent in 1989, lower than the 4.2 per
cent growth experienced in 1988. The economic slowdown in 1989 may be
attributed partly to the tightening of economic policy implemented
during the latter half of the year. The move to a more restrictive
policy stance checked the growth of domestic demand, which grew by 3.3
per cent in 1989 as compared to 4.7 per cent in 1988. The strength of
demand in the rest of the world, however, meant that the contribution of
net exports to GDP growth, although still negative, improved during
1989. Inflation rose during 1989, rising to 6.1 per cent from 4.8 per
cent in 1988, reflecting both persistent pressures on capacity and an
acceleration in unit labour costs (which rose by 7.6 per cent in 1989 as
compared to 3.4 per cent growth in 1988).
The monetary authorities cut the discount rate by 1 percentage
point in May as the decision to incorporate the Lira within narrow bands
in the ERM resulted in large capital inflows and upward pressure on the
Lira. Our assumption of a two-speed Europe implies that the Lira moves
in line with risk adjusted interest-rate differentials until 1997,
thereafter becoming irrevocably fixed against the D-Mark and the Franc
as Italy begins to participate in the monetary union formed between
Germany, France and the Benelux states in 1995.
In May 1990 the italian government introduced a fiscal programme
aimed at reducing the budget deficit in line with the targets contained
in the 1990 Finance Act, even though the 1990 budget projections were
revised upward in March. In its Economic Outlook published in June this
year the OECD has assessed the sustainability of fiscal policy in each
of its member states. Significantly the OECD use a forward-looking
indicator of sustainability which not only takes account of foreseeable changes in spending and revenues, but also the degree of expenditure
reduction/revenue enhancement which is required to maintain a stable
debt-to-income ratio. On the basis of current and expected budgetary
measures the OECD concludes that italian fiscal policy is unsustainable.
(This is in line with the argument presented in Barrell (1990) where
Italian membership of a monetary union was only seen as feasible if
fiscal policy tightened considerably.) We are assuming therefore that
fiscal policy will tighten further during the 1990s reducing the deficit
from 10 per cent of GNP to around 4-5 per cent of GNP by the end of the
decade. A tighter fiscal stance will not only restrain the growth of the
national debt and lower the cost of capital, but will in the short term
also increase national savings. An increase in national savings, ceteris
paribus, will tend to improve the current account. A tighter fiscal
policy will also bear down on inflation. These latter two consequences
of a tighter fiscal policy will not only reduce the differential between
Italian inflation and inflation in Germany and France, but will also
reduce the possibility of a major realignment of the Lira before Italy
participates in monetary union.
Our forecast for the italian economy is set out in table 15. With a
higher exchange rate and continued high interest rates, and an expected
decline in world demand, the Italian economy is expected to grow more
slowly this year. Domestic demand growth is forecast to slow to 2.5 per
cent this year as consumption and investment are restrained by higher
interest rates. Net exports are forecast to reduce the growth of GDP by
0.7 per cent in 1990. However, the current account is expected to
improve this year, despite a deterioration in the invisibles balance.
This improvement can be attributed to the favourable movement in the
terms of trade that we are forecasting for 1990. Whilst we are not
anticipating any marked change in the italian inflation rate this year,
we expect inflation to fall in the long run as continued membership of
the ERM disciplines the behaviour of wage and price setters.
Canada
In 1989 Canadian GDP grew by 3.0 per cent, lower than the 4.4 per
cent growth experienced in 1988. This slowdown can be attributed to both
a reduction in the rate of growth of domestic demand and a significantly
more negative contribution from net exports. The growth of domestic
demand slowed to 4.1 per cent in 1989 from 5.0 per cent in 1988, partly
in response to the sustained high level of Canadian interest rates. The
Canadian Dollar continued its appreciation against the US Dollar during
1989, rising by some 3.8 per cent, this in turn reflected an unexpected
widening of the differential between Canadian and US interest rates.
During 1989 the current account deficit widened to 2.6 per cent of GDP
from 1.7 per cent of GDP in 1988. This deterioration in the current
account is the result of a deterioration in the invisibles balance. This
improvement can be attributed to the favourable movement in the terms of
trade that we are forecasting for 1990. Whilst we are not anticipating
any marked change in the italian inflation rate this year, we expect
inflation to fall in the long run as continued membership of the ERM
disciplines the behaviour of wage and price setters.
Canada
In 1989 Canadian GDP grew by 3.0 per cent, lower than the 4.4 per
cent growth experienced in 1988. This slowdown can be attributed to both
a reduction in the rate of growth of domestic demand and a significantly
more negative contribution from net exports. The growth of domestic
demand slowed to 4.1 per cent in 1989 from 5.0 per cent in 1988, partly
in response to the sustained high level of Canadian interest rates. The
Canadian Dollar continued its appreciation against the US Dollar during
1989, rising by some 3.8 per cent, this in turn reflected an unexpected
widening of the differential between Canadian and US interest rates.
During 1989 the current account deficit widened to 2.6 per cent of GDP
from 1.7 per cent of GDP in 1988. This deterioration in the current
account is the result of a worsening in the visible balance, which can
be attributed to the sustained appreciation of the Canadian Dollar over
the last three years.
After initially falling in early 1990, interest rates were raised
to seven-year highs in March as the exchange rate came under intense
pressure. We anticipate that Canadian interest rates will stay around
their present high levels for the remainder of the year and that the
Canadian Dollar will appreciate further, albeit modestly, against the US
Dollar in 1990. in the longer run we expect the Canadian Dollar to
depreciate against its US counterpart as the exchange rate moves down
the risk adjusted open-arbitrage path.
Our forecast for Canada is presented in table 16. We anticipate
that the growth of the Canadian economy will slow during the course of
1990 as high interest rates bear down on the growth of domestic demand.
Canadian GDP is forecast to grow by only 1 per cent in 1990 despite some
recovery in net exports. Industrial production is set to fall by almost
1 percentage point this year. The slowdown in 1990 will be accompanied
by both higher unemployment and lower inflation. The unemployment rate
is forecast to increase to about 8 per cent in 1990 as compared to 71/2
per cent in 1989. Consumer price inflation is projected to decline to
4.4 per cent this year, reflecting both the slowdown in domestic demand
and the strength of the Canadian Dollar. However, inflation is set to
rise in 1991 following the introduction of the Goods and Services Tax.
The strength of the Canadian Dollar, together with a slowing in demand
in the rest of the world is likely to result in a further deterioration
in Canada's external position. The current account deficit is
forecast to widen to 3.9 per cent of GDP in 1990, a position which is
not reversed by the end of the decade. Such a deficit can only be
sustained in the long run if Canada is able to attract the requisite
capital flows form the rest of the world. We think that the resource
rich Canadian economy will be able to-attract such funds. If these flows
are not forthcoming then there will be a need to adopt an even more
restrictive policy stance.
REFERENCES Barrell, R. (1 990), 'European currency union and
the EMS', National Institute Economic Review, No. 132, pp.59-66.
Barrell, R.J. and Wren-Lewis, S. 1989),'Fundamental equilibrium
exchange rates for the G7', National Institute Discussion
Paper No. 155. Pain, N. (1990), Financial liberalisation and
foreign portfolio investment in the United Kingdom', National
Institute Discussion
Paper No. 184. Wren-Lewis, S., Westaway, P., Soteri, S. and
Barrell, R. (1989), Choosing the rate: an analysis of the optimum level
of entry
for sterling into the ERM', National Institute Discussion
Paper No. 171. Recent events in the Gulf indicate that there is a
possibility that the world economy may see a significant rise in oil
prices. On 6th August 1990 the iraqis were still occupying Kuwait, and
their annexation of the country gave them control of 8 per cent of the
worlds oil supplies. Their intention is to use their bargaining power to
lever up oil prices. These had been relatively weak for some time as
Iraqi and Iranian production had both returned to full capacity after
the Gulf war and some producers, such as Kuwait, were producing above
quota. This annex investigates the effects of a rise in oil prices and
compares the estimates to those produced by the OECD in 1986. We
concentrate on a $5 pb rise to $25 pb, but we also include some results
for a $10 pb rise to $30 pb.
(a) A temporary rise in oil prices
We have assumed for our main simulations that the rise in oil
prices is only temporary. The oil price is assumed to rise by $5 pb and
stay 25 per cent above base for 3 years. Table Al given the effects on
output and inflation in the G7, along with the effects on world trade.
Table A2 gives the associated effects on exchange rates. We have assumed
that: - (1) Exchange rates are forward looking.
(2) Monetary policy is not accommodating. and (3) Fiscal policy
is unchanged from base
assumptions.
These assumptions are more fully spelled
out below.
The rise in world oil prices shifts resources from the advanced
world to the oil producers in OPEC, in Latin America, Africa and to the
CPES. It initially raises inflation by half a per cent in the first year
and then by a quarter of a per cent in each of the subsequent two years.
Output initially declines in the major economies as higher prices and
higher interest rates reduce both consumption and investment. We project
that output would be 0.3 per cent below base by the second year, with
some recovery thereafter. Industrial production would also be below
base. However world trade displays a different pattern. Lower incomes in
the advanced world would initially reduce trade relative to base levels,
but as oil producers receive extra revenue they increase their imports.
World trade rises above base in the second year of the simulation and
continues increasing in the third year. This rise in the ratio of trade
to output is the real concomitant of the change in the terms of trade
against the advanced economies.
These differences from base are slightly smaller (for a similar
shock) than those given by the OECD in the May 1986. Economic Outlook
May 1986 pp164-165). The OECD ready reckoner has OECD output in the
major 7 0.2 per cent below base in the first year and 0.4 per cent in
the second. This is in part the result of declining energy intensity of
output. We have assumed that the monetary stance will not be
accommodating, and hence that real interest rates will be unchanged in
response to the shock. Table A2 gives the effects of the oil price shock
on interest rates and exchange rates amongst the major seven. Table A3
gives the associated changes in inflation and output. It is clear that
we should expect some diversity of outturn. US inflation rises more than
elsewhere. The US is both more energy intensive (although less oil
intensive) and has freer energy markets than any of the other major
economies. Unlike in Europe and Japan, gas, coal and electricity prices
can be expected to quickly follow oil prices. Our model reflects this
sensitivity and oil prices directly affect producer and consumer prices.
As a result we would expect the US Dollar to fall relative to other
major currencies and US interest rates to rise more than elsewhere.
The effects on exchange rates elsewhere depends upon a number of
diverse factors. Countries such as Germany and Japan that have rather
slow rates of pass through of external shocks to domestic prices are
likely to gain in terms of competitiveness relative to those with a more
rapid pass through to prices. However the Japanese are more dependent on
free market imported energy sources, and the effect on their balance of
payments is worse than that for Germany. We expect the Yen to depreciate
initially along with the Dollar.
Not all currencies can depreciate, and as the Yen and Dollar tall,
the D-Mark strengthens. This is not only because of the small effect of
the oil price rise on inflation but also because they trade relatively
heavily with oil producers. This link is particularly strong with the
CPEs whose exports are over 20 per cent made up of oil and related
products. The increase in world trade associated with higher oil prices
will have differential effects depending on the pattern of trade links.
Those countries that benefit will be those that trade with the high
absorbers such as the CPES, Africa and Latin America.
Tables A2 and A3 also indicate that higher oil prices could produce
some strain in the EMS. Initially we would expect France and Italy to
appreciate, but the delayed inflationary consequences of the oil price
rise are likely to induce higher interest rates and subsequent
depreciations. As the model is forward looking these higher interest
rates in years two and three are already taken into account when the
initial exchange rate is calculated. (These results are essentially the
same as those in Barrell 1990).
Both the UK and Canada are oil producers and net energy exporters,
and hence the rise in the oil price improves their balance of payments
and both currencies appreciate. This offsets the initial inflationary
impact of the oil price rise and hence there is much less need for an
increase in interest rates in order to maintain the monetary stance. UK
output is above base because the UK gains from the increase in world
trade without having to suffer a tighter monetary policy. UK prices are
only 0.6 per cent higher after 3 years, the exchange rate initially
appreciates by .5 per cent." b) Long term effects Table A4 presents
some summary statistics covering the effects of a permanent rise of 25
per cent in real oil prices. The simulation is run over 15 years with
the same assumptions as for the temporary shock. Output in the major
seven settles slightly below base after five years and inflation is a
little above base. The change in output results in part from a change in
relative prices which reduces the consumption wage and hence reduces the
supply of labour. The trade/output ratio, as indicated by the ratio of
col 2 to col 7, rises slightly.
The model stabilises with inflation about one quarter of a per cent
above base. As a result domestic demand falls relative to output to
ensure that more resources flow into net exports. This rise in inflation
is a result of our assumptions as well as of the model. The reduction of
absorption in the advanced world could take place through one of four
channels. Wealth effects are one possible channel. A sequence of current
account deficits reduces wealth and hence demand. However the estimated
wealth effects on the model are both rather weak and take a long while
to have an effect. Fiscal policy could be tightened to induce the
transfer or real interest rates could be raised. Both are assumed
unchanged in these simulations. The only remaining alternative is to
induce the transfer of resources by allowing inflation to be higher. The
policy responses that we assume to hold produce this result.
The authorities in each of the countries in the advanced world have
a number of policy options open to them, and if the effects of wealth on
adjustment are too slow then either tighter monetary policy raising real
rates or a tighter fiscal policy than we have assumed (which would
reduce wealth more quickly by reducing the stock of government debt)
might well be chosen. Indeed a tighter fiscal policy may be necessary
for equilibrium because the shock will change the debt income ratio, and
adjustments would have to be made to return it to a stable path. (c) A
50 per cent rise in the oil price Our model is such that a $1 0 rise in
the oil price has around twice the effects of a $5 rise. Table A5
reports a simulation with oil prices 50 per cent above base levels for 3
years, and thereafter they return to our base path. Output in the major
seven would be over half a per cent below base levels after two years,
and US output in particular would be almost a full per cent below base
by 1991. This however is not enough to push the US into a recession, as
we are forecasting over two and a half per cent growth in that year.
inflation in the major seven would be one per cent higher in the first
year, and US inflation would be around one and a quarter per cent
higher. We would expect the US authorities to raise interest rates
substantially and also that the effective exchange rate for the Dollar
would fall. The assumptions of constant real interest rates and constant
fiscal policy are commonly used in large model simulations. Our exchange
rate assumptions are more innovative. When we solve the model in forward
looking mode we assume that the real exchange rate changes along the
uncovered real interest parity path. The exchange rate in the first
period has to be such that the real exchange rate stabilises toward the
end of the run and that the current account as a per cent of GNP also
returns to its base level. We are assuming that all countries including
the US have to return to the base current balance to GNP ratio. The
current balance trajectory on our base reflects the growth path of the
world economy and the pattern of savings and investment in the world.
The equilibrium trajectories for these variables, and hence for the
current account depend upon demography, preferences for consumption now
and on relative rates of return. Hence we would expect the world economy
to return to the equilibrium set of current accounts after a shock.
However we expect that this process will take some time and we allow up
to 10 years after the shock has been removed for adjustment to take
place.
GEM THE NATIONAL INSTITUTE'S GLOBAL ECONOMETRIC MODEL
GEM is a 640 equation macroeconomic model covering the whole of the
world economy, but focusing particularly on the seven major industrial
countries. The National Institute publishes the current version of GEM
together with a user-friendly, menu-driven operating package designed to
enable economists to produce their own forecasts and simulations.
Background
GEM is used by the National Institute to produce forecasts and
analyse events and policy options in the world economy. it was developed
from a model maintained by HM Treasury to produce internal world
forecasts. In the last two years it has established itself as one of the
leading half dozen world econometric models, participating (as the only
UK based model) in comparative exercises organised by the US Federal
Reserve and the Brookings Institution in Washington. it has been used in
academic studies of international policy co-operation, and research and
development of it is financed by the Economic and Social Research
Council. The Institute has already provided the model to the Bank of
England, HM Treasury and the World Bank for use in their published
forecasts. Scope and coverage GEM is divided into sixteen sectors. Each
of the G7 country sectors contains around 60 variables covering
individual components of demand, price indices, exchange rates and
interest rates, trade and the current account. Much smaller sectors
exist for Belgium, Netherlands and the rest of OECD. The remaining six
sectors cover OPEC, Asia, Latin America, Africa, the Centrally Planned
Economies and Miscellaneous developing countries. These sectors contain
equations for trade volumes and prices, which depend on five commodity
price indices.
The model package
The published model package comes with a 'front-end'
specifically designed for GEM (by Bahram Pesaran who co-wrote the
estimation package MICROFIT) to enable economists with little or no
previous experience to produce forecasts and policy analysis. A
user's guide is provided, but this menu-driven programme is largely
self explanatory. A base forecast is provided each quarter with the
latest version of the model, and the user can inspect numerically and
graphically the judgements that lie behind this forecast. By changing
these judgements, or by adding new data, the users can produce their own
forecast. Alternatively by using the model in simulation mode the user
can look at the global effects of events such as a US fiscal expansion
or an oil price fall.
A comprehensive model manual lists individual equations and
describes the theoretical basis of the model's relationships. A
full data listing gives the definition and source for each model
variable, allowing the user to update the forecast in between quarterly
releases.
Hardware requirements
The package requires a 80386 based PC, such as the IBM P/S2 Model
70 or 80, with a minimum of 2 megabytes of memory (although we recommend
4 megabytes). A maths co-processor (80387) is also recommended. The
computer should also have at least 20 megabytes of hard disk and a VGA graphics board.
The annual subscription is 94,500 plus VAT with a reduced rate of
2500 for academic users. The Japanese economy has been becoming more
open over the last four to five years. This has been partly the result
of pressure from overseas, and especially from America. Non price
barriers to trade have been removed, and Japanese consumer goods markets
have become more open. There has, as a result, been a significant rise
in the level of imports into Japan in the last five years. Chart Al
plots recent data for both total and non oil import penetration in the
Japanese economy along with our forecast over the next three years.
There has been a corresponding, but less marked change in Japanese
export performance over the same period. A number of Japanese firms have
been undertaking considerable programmes of direct investment overseas.
They have in particular been setting up plants around the Pacific rim,
to substitute for domestic production for both the home market and for
export markets. Chart A2 plots the share of Japanese exports in World
trade and Japanese direct investment outflows as a per cent of GNP.
The trade equations for Japan on GEM were last re-estimated in
1986-87, and we have suspected that the post sample period for these
equations exhibited structural change. Chart A3 plots the equation
residuals for both exports and imports of (non-oil) goods for Japan.
There appears to be a downward trend in the export equation residual and
a step change in the import equation residual. The combination of a
belief that the structure has been changing along with the deteriorating performance of our equations has led us to re-estimate them. We have
delayed doing this for some time in order to ensure that we had
sufficient data for sensible stability testing.
(a) Japanese Imports
We re-estimated our equation for Japanese imports of non oil goods
starting with the general form: - [Delta M] = a + bTFE(-l) + cRPM(-1) +
dM(-1) + [Lambdal.(L).Delta.M] + [Delta.(L).Delta.TFE +
[Phi.(L).Delta.RPM + [e.sub.t] and tested down by sequential elimination
until the final parsimonious form was reached. This is reported in the
first column of table B1. The equation is statistically acceptable.
However, our prior is that there has been a change in the structure
around 1986. Column two in the table reports the same equation estimated
up to 1985Q4. There are two stability tests reported. The first is Chows
predictive test, and the regression comprehensively fails. The second
Chow test for internal parameter stability is much weaker in this
situation, but the equation also fails it. Both the income and the
competitiveness elasticities are lower in the equation estimated up to
1985Q4 then they are over the whole sample period.
Column three of table Bl reports the final equation we have chosen.
We investigated a number of possibilities for structural change in the
long run coefficients, and found that there was a case for allowing the
impact elasticity of TFE to change as well as for allowing the long run
elasticities on TFE and competitiveness to increase. In order to model
these changes we included the lagged levels of TFE and non oil imports
for the period 1986Ql to 199001. These dummied variables have slowed the
effects of TFE and competitiveness as well as raising the long run
effects. b) Japanese exports We also re-estimated our equation for
Japanese exports of goods starting with the general form:AX = a + XTIME
+ b(X(- 1) - S(- 1)) + CRULT(- 1) + D(L)AX + E(L)AS + f L)ARULT + et
and tested down in the usual way. Table B2 reports our results. The
equation estimated over the whole time period has a competitiveness
elasticity of 1.00, and market share grows by 2 per cent la year at
constant competitiveness. The same equation estimated up to 1985Q4 in
column 2 of table B2 has a lower competitiveness elasticity and a higher
rate of gain in world trade share. Although it passes a predictive
failure test it fails the usual Chow internal parameter stability test.
After some experimentation with split time trends around 1986 we decided
that the best description of the data generation process involved using
a time trend for world trade share gain up to 1985Q4 and thereafter to
have an equation that would display a constant world trade share at
constant competitiveness. The resulting equation is reported in column 3
of table B2. The competitiveness elasticity is just below one, and
before 1986 world trade share would have grown by 2.25 per cent at
constant competitiveness.
(c) Consequences for the Japanese balance of payments
The new equations for Japanese trade change model properties.
Although we had taken account of these perceived changes in structure by
adjusting residuals in our forecasts, this adjustment would not have fed
through to simulation properties. They now do so. in particular, at
constant competitiveness we would now expect Japanese exports to grow
around two per cent a year more slowly than they have in the past, and
we would expect Japanese import growth to be around one per cent higher
than it would otherwise have been. These changes are likely to reduce
the Japanese surplus by a cumulating $9 billion per annum. They are a
major factor behind our forecast of a fall of 1 per cent of GNP in the
Japanese current account surplus over the next decade.