Updated view of potential output and employment.
To prepare forecasts of the actual development in the longer term,
the NIER makes assessments of the potential levels of output and
employment. One important element is the assessment of the level of
equilibrium unemployment. This special analysis presents an updated view
of these variables, with a focus on 2013-2017. In the new assessment,
the level of potential GDP is somewhat higher in 2017 than in the
previous assessment from December 2012.
**********
Potential GDP--Level of Output When the Economy is in Cyclical Balance The NIER regularly publishes medium-term forecasts (in this case
2013-2017) and therefore needs to assess the development of the
potential levels of important macroeconomic variables like GDP and
employment during this time frame. The potential level of output
affects, among other things, the margin for permanent unfunded measures
in the central government budget, or the so-called scope for reforms
(see the special analysis "The NIER's Assessment of the Scope
for Reforms" in this chapter).
The NIER's assessment is that potential GDP grew by an annual
average of 2.3 percent during the period 1980-2012. In the period ahead,
the NIER assesses that potential GDP will grow more slowly, by an
average of 1.8 percent per year in 2013-2015, and then increase by more
than 2 percent per year in 2016-2017 (Table 12). Underlying the
relatively low growth rates in 2013-2015 is a weak tendency in potential
producitivity and slower growth in the potential labour force.
The NIER's assessment of potential GDP, however, is somewhat
higher in 2017 than in the previous assessment (see Table 13). (10) The
explanation is a changed view of the level of potential productivity as
well as a different assessment of the potential number of hours worked.
[GRAPHIC 39 OMITTED]
Potential Productivity
LONG-LASTING SLUMP IN PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH
There are different mechanisms that explain why the actual level of
productivity may be either higher or lower than potential productivity.
The differences be due primarily to variations in the growth and
composition of demand. They may arise from economies of scale or
rigidities in the production processes of firms. One such rigidity is
when firms do not adjust staffing to temporary fluctuations in demand.
The NIER assumes that potential productivity in the business sector
in the long run, after the year 2020, will increase in line with its
historical average of 2.3 percent per year since 1980. Potential
productivity in the business sector rises more slowly in the preceding
years, and by only 1.5-1.8 percent per year in 2012-2015. Growth in
productivity is driven primarily by technological development. It is the
NIER's assessment that the contribution of technological
development to productivity growth in recent years has been less than in
the 1990's and early 2000's, and that this will continue to be
the case for some years to come. (11)
NEW ASSESSMENTS OF PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH
New data published since the previous forecast point to higher
productivity growth in the business sector. The principal revision is in
growth in 2010 (see Diagram 39). This has led to a new assessment of
potential productivity growth in the business sector. It is primarily
the estimated growth during the years 2009-2013 that has been revised,
whereas potential productivity growth in the business sector in
subsequent years is largely unchanged (see Diagram 40).
In addition, productivity growth in public authorities and
nonprofit organizations in the long run is assumed to increase by an
average of 0.2 percent per year, which corresponds roughly to the
historical average rate of increase since 1980. Taken together, the new
assessments mean that the potential level of productivity in constant
prices for the economy as a whole in 2017 is expected to be somewhat
higher than the estimate at the time of the previous forecast. (12)
The level of GDP in current prices is not significantly affected by
the rate of productivity growth in public agencies. The reason is that
the value added in public agencies is calculated from the development of
labour costs and the costs of capital consumption, and the development
of labour costs in public authorities largely follows the development of
earnings in the business sector. (13) The assessment of the long-term
growth of productivity in public authorities is thus of negligible significance for the assessment of the level of potential GDP as
measured in current prices, nor has the calculated level in current
prices in 2017 been revised upward to the same extent as potential GDP
in constant prices (see Table 13). (14)
Potential Number of Hours Worked
The rate of growth in the potential number of hours worked will
drop beginning in 2013, primarily because the potential labour force
will be growing more slowly than it has done through 2012 (see Table
12). Compared with the previous assessment, however, the rate of growth
in potential hours is somewhat stronger, with the result that the level
will be higher in 2017 than before. This will contribute to a higher
potential level of GDP in 2017 (see Table 13).
[GRAPHIC 40 OMITTED]
[GRAPHIC 41 OMITTED]
[GRAPHIC 42 OMITTED]
STRONG GROWTH IN POTENTAL LABOUR FORCE IN RECENT YEARS
The labour supply has grown strongly in recent years despite the
fact that demand for labour has been weak from time to time. This is
partly explainable by the demographic development, where the number of
people of working age has been rapidly increasing. At the same time, the
Government's economic policy reforms to increase the labour supply
have probably had their intended effect. (15) According to the
NIER's assessment, the potential labour force has increased
strongly, and its level is higher than in the previous assessment (see
Diagram 41).
The growth in labour supply the past two years has been largely
among persons 65-74 years of age, with the result that the labour force
participation rate in this group has risen rapidly. In the NIER's
assessment of the potential labour force, labour force participation
among older persons will continue to rise in the period ahead. The
reason is that younger cohorts show a higher rate of labour force
participation than older cohorts, which gradually increases the average
rate of labour force participation.
However, the growth of the potential labour force will drop to a
lower level in coming years (see Diagram 42 and Table 12). This will be
due to a changed population structure and to the fact that the reforms
are likely to have had their full effect. The continued trend of
increased labour force participation among older people, though, will
contribute to a somewhat higher rate of growth than would otherwise have
been the case.
THE NIER'S ASSESSMENT OF EQUILIBRIUM UNEMPLOYMENT
Equilibrium unemployment is determined mainly by structural factors
such as how effectively job openings are matched with jobseekers and by
the actions of the social partners. (16) Equilibrium unemployment is
also affected by the degree to which extended periods of high
unemployment give rise to so-called persistence effects. A deep and
prolonged recession may have long-lasting effects on unemployment and
employment, partly because prolonged periods of unemployment make the
unemployed less competitive on the market. (17)
It is the NIER's assessment that the prolonged period of high
unemployment will raise equilibrium unemployment by almost 0.6
percentage point (about 30 000 persons) in 2016. This is somewhat higher
compared to the previous assessment, which is explainable primarily by
the fact that Statistics Sweden has revised upward the level of
unemployment for the period 2010-2012 (see Diagram 43). (18) Long-term
unemployment is also at a somewhat higher level. At the same time,
unemployment has risen during the course of 2012 and is expected to be
at a high level in the next few years as well.
For this year equilibrium unemployment is forecast to be al-most 7
percent (see Table 12). Persistence effects are not anticipated to
affect equilibrium unemployment permanently. By 2020 most of the
persistence effects are expected to have subsided, and equilibrium
unemployment will be about 6 percent (see Diagram 43). (19) The reason
why equilibrium unemployment will be decreasing is that previously
implemented economic policy reforms, such as the tax credit on earned
income (jobbskatteavdraget) and the changes in the unemployment
insurance system, will reduce equilibrium unemployment gradually. The
adjustment to the new equilibrium, however, is expected to take time,
one reason being that wages and salaries are rigid. (20)
[GRAPHIC 43 OMITTED]
Potential Variables
Potential GDP refers to the level of output that would be achieved
if the economy were in cyclical balance.
In the NIER's assessment, potential GDP is divided into
potential productivity and the potential number of hours worked. By
potential productivity is meant the level of productivity that would
have been observed in the absence of cyclical variations.
The potential number of hours worked is determined by potential
employment, that is, the number employed when there is cyclical balance
on the labour market, and by their average hours of work. Potential
employment is determined in turn by the potential labour force and by
equilibrium unemployment, that is, the labour force and unemployment
when the labour market is in balance.
(10) The previous assessment refers to the forecast in The Swedish
Economy, December 2012.
(11) See Report on Wage Formation, 2012, for a discussion of the
factors on which the assessment is based.
(12) It was previously assumed that there would be no productivity
growth for public authorities and nonprofit organizations. In constant
prices refers to volume in 2011 price levels.
(13) Public agencies can choose to take out productivity gains in
the form of higher quality for an unchanged number of hours worked at
the same cost, or obtain lower costs for unchanged quality with fewer
hours worked. In the first case, the value added of public agencies in
current prices is unaffected by productivity growth. In the latter case,
value added will be lower in public agencies, but labour is freed up to
work in the private sector, where value added is thus higher.
(14) Potential GDP in current prices is calculated on the basis of
the actual development of the GDP deflator.
(15) According to the NIER's assessment, the economic policy
reforms implemented since 2007 are increasing the potential labour force
by 2.6 percent. See the special analysis "Long-Term Effects of
Economic Policy Reforms on the Labour Market" in The Swedish
Economy, December 2011.
(16) See Wage Formation in Sweden 2012.
(17) See, for example, Guichard, S. and E. Rusticelli,
"Assessing the impact of the financial crisis on equilibrium
unemployment in OECD countries", OECD Economic Department Working
Papers no. 767, 2010.
(18) The number employed has averaged 17 000 persons fewer, and
unemployment has averaged 0.3 percentage point higher than was
previously known; see www.scb.se/Ifs
(19) For a more thorough description of the driving forces that
contribute to lower equilibrium unemployment, see Wage Formation in
Sweden 2012.
(20) See the special analysis "Long-Term Effects of Economic
Policy Reforms on the Labour Market" in The Swedish Economy,
December 2011.
Table 12 Potential Variables
Percentage change and percent, respectively
2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
Potential GDP (1) 1.5 1.7 1.8 2.0 2.1 2.1
Potential productivity (2) 0.8 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.6 1.6
Potential productivity,
business sector 1.5 1.5 1.6 1.8 2.1 2.1
Potential hours worked 0.8 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
Potential employment 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.4
Potential labour force 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.3
Equilibrium unemployment (3) 6.9 6.9 6.8 6.7 6.6 6.5
(1) Market price. (2) Whole economy, market price. (3)
Percent of potential labour force.
Source: NIER.
Table 13 Revisions to Potential Variables
Revisions to levels compared to previous assessment,
percent
2012 2017
Potential GDP, current prices 0.2 0.3
Potential GDP, constant prices (1) 0.3 0.7
Potential productivity,
whole economy (1) 0.2 0.4
Potential productivity,
business sector (2) 0.4 0.3
Potential hours worked 0.1 0.3
(1) Market prices, 2011 price level. (2) Basic prices,
2011 price level.
Note. Previous assessment is the forecast in Konjunkturldget
(The Swedish Economy), December 2012.
Source: NIER.