Matching strategic resources with strategy and industry structure.
Bacon, Calvin M., Jr. ; Hofer, Charles W.
ABSTRACT
Although new ventures have provided many benefits to society, the
failure rate for new ventures has been extremely high. Entrepreneurship
theorists have suggested that strategic resources are a possible
determinant of new venture success and that strategic resources should
be matched to business strategy and environmental situations. However,
few empirical studies have considered strategic resources. Therefore,
this exploratory study empirically examined the influence of resources
on new venture performance in the presence of certain strategic and
industry structure conditions. This study found a significant
relationship between distinctive competencies and new venture
performance when matched to low-cost strategies and between intellectual
resources and new venture performance for firms in industries in the
shakeout stage. T h e s e results imply that entrepreneurs should match
their strategic resources to the situation. New ventures adopting a
low-cost approach should develop administration competencies in order to
establish a competitive advantage over rivals. It is possible that
adding better and more administrative personnel could pay for itself in
a higher return to stockholders.
Furthermore, when new ventures are in industries in the shakeout
stage, intellectual property such as patents and copyrights become more
important. This effect may be particularly important in high-growth
industries considered in this study. Possessing intellectual property
may enable firms to differentiate their goods and services from their
competition or may provide a means of limiting direct competition.
INTRODUCTION
Research on the determinants of new venture performance has focused
on three possible factors: the entrepreneur, industry structure, and
strategy. Of these, studies have identified strategy and industry
structure, and the interaction between strategy and industry structure
as important determinants of new venture success.
Other than strategy, industry structure, and the entrepreneur,
resources have also been identified as a possible determinant of new
venture performance. Resources are instrumental in developing new
products and services in existing markets and in preparing ventures for
entry into new markets (Azzone, Bertele, & Rangone, 1995; Brush,
Greene, & Hart, 2001). Resources are particularly important in
turbulent environments in which long-term competitiveness depends upon
the venture's ability to identify, develop, and exploit critical
resources (Azzone, et al., 1995). Additionally, resources such as
knowledge and technical skills are directly linked to technical
entrepreneurship and innovation (Klavans, 1994) that are vital to
high-growth ventures.
Resource-based theory proposes that resources determine a
firm's strategic advantages and firm performance (Wernerfelt, 1984;
Mahoney & Pandian, 1992; Barney, 1991). In this view, the concept of
resources includes attributes of firms that affect the formulation and
implementation of strategy (Barney, 1991; 2001). There is a progression
of value creation, starting with Generic Resources, and passing through
Capabilities, Distinctive Competencies, Strategic Resources, and finally
to Strategic Advantage (Brush, et al., 2001). Because resources are
critical to the firm's success, the type, amount, and timing of
resources accumulated are vital.
Resource-based theory rests on three major assumptions. The first
major assumption is that firms seek to earn above-average returns
(Wernerfelt, 1984; Conner, 1991; Robinson, 1998). Viewing firms as
seekers of above-average returns is important because it suggests
behaviors which might be different if firms were seeking average
returns. For example, firms seeking average returns may be willing to
adopt strategies that imitate an average firm while firms seeking
above-average returns are forced to consider innovative strategies that
may involve more risks.
The second major assumption within resource-based theory is that
resources are asymmetrically distributed across competing firms (Conner,
1991; Schulze, 1994; Barney, 2001). The heterogeneity of resources may
be caused or maintained by several mechanisms. For example, asymmetries
may arise from resource mobility barriers due to asset specificity (Williamson, 1985); cognitive effects (Fiol, 1991); or social complexity
(Barney, 1991). Also, isolating mechanisms that may develop due to time
compression diseconomies of imitation or due to regulatory requirements
such as patent law, copyright law, or trademark law (Conner, 1991).
Resource-based theory proposes that at least one of these mechanisms
acts to prevent the equal distribution of resources within and between
industries.
The third major assumption is that differences in resources lead to
differences in product characteristics or service characteristics that
result in variation in firm performance (Conner, 1991; Schulze, 1994;
Barney, 2001). Because these differences in product characteristics lead
to strategic advantages, they have been classified into two categories:
characteristics that allow a firm to sell a differentiated product at a
higher price, and characteristics that permit a firm to make an
undifferentiated product at a lower cost (Schumpeter, 1950; Porter,
1991; Peteraf, 1993).
According to resource-based theory, above-average returns occur as
firms create value through the accumulation and deployment of resources
(Conner, 1991). Determining new combinations of resources is an
innovative activity which requires entrepreneurial vision (Schumpeter,
1950). Because the combinations of resources must be unique, some
researchers have suggested it may be impossible to generalize ways to
systematically create strategic advantages (Dierickx & Cool, 1989;
King & Zeithaml, 2001). However, other researchers believe that
there may be general configurations of resources that influence the
survival and growth of firms (Hall, 1993; Miller & Shamsie, 1995).
Strategic management theory generally proposes that the return of
above-average profits comes from strategic advantages. These advantages
are the result of two mechanisms: product differentiation or low cost
(Schumpeter, 1950; Porter, 1980; Conner, 1991). That is, firms may
either create products that are superior to others and thereby command a
relatively high price while maintaining moderate costs, or they may
provide common products at reasonable prices that are relatively
inexpensive to make.
This research suggests a relationship between new venture
performance and resources. Because previous studies have confirmed the
importance of strategy and industry structure in determining new venture
performance, strategy and industry structure are included in the general
model used in this study. Therefore, the general model for this research
include new venture performance (NVP), industry structure (IS), strategy
(S), and resources (R) as given by:
NVP = (S, IS, R)
While the relationship may be simple and direct, there are also
other possibilities. First, it is possible that resources explain the
same variation as do industry structure and strategy. Therefore, this
study examines resources in the presence of strategy and industry
structure. Second, the influence of resources may be through an
interaction with strategy or industry structure. Third, resources may
not influence new venture performance at all.
DEVELOPMENT OF HYPOTHESES
Generic Strategy and Distinctive Competencies Prior Findings
Chandler and Hanks (1994) found an interaction effect on new
venture performance between generic strategy and distinctive
competencies. They noted that new ventures adopting differentiation
strategies and possessing competencies in service areas performed better
than other firms. This effect was particularly evident when the
firms' capabilities allowed them to provide customer service
training and to implement process technologies.
In addition, the results in Chandler and Hanks (1994) indicate that
low-cost strategies were more successful when matched with the
appropriate resource-based capabilities. This was most apparent in new
ventures for which there were few customers. The authors suggested that
firms with dedicated products going to few customers were able to lower
marketing costs and product development costs to create low-cost
advantages. In keeping with prior findings, this research expected to
find that low-cost strategies will be more successful when matched with
product competencies or administration competencies. Furthermore, this
study expected to find firms with strategies dealing with
differentiation to be superior when new ventures have competencies in
research and development or in marketing. Generic Strategy and
Distinctive Competencies Hypotheses
1a: Ventures adopting low-cost strategies and possessing production
competencies will perform better than other ventures.
1b: Ventures adopting low-cost strategies and possessing administration
competencies will perform better than other ventures.
1c: Ventures adopting differentiation strategies and possessing R&D
competencies will perform better than other ventures.
1d: Ventures adopting differentiation strategies and possessing
marketing competencies will perform better than other ventures.
Stage of the Industry Life Cycle and Intellectual Resources Prior
Findings
In their study of Hollywood film studios from 1936 to 1965, Miller
and Shamsie (1996) found a relationship between industry structure and
strategic resources. The research showed that ventures with
knowledge-based resources performed better than other firms in the late
stages of the industry life cycle. According to Miller and Shamsie
(1996), firms in late stages of the industry life cycle face
uncertainties that knowledge-based resources handle best due to their
inherent flexibility. This research expected to confirm Miller and
Shamsie's (1996) findings. It was expected that ventures entering
late stages of the industry life cycle will perform better than other
firms when they possess intellectual resources.
Stage of the Industry Life Cycle and Intellectual Resources
Hypotheses
2a: Ventures entering late stages of the industry life cycle and owning
patents will perform better than other ventures.
2b: Ventures entering late stages of the industry life cycle and owning
trademarks will perform better than other ventures.
2c: Ventures entering late stages of the industry life cycle and owning
copyrights will perform better than other ventures.
OPERATIONALIZING THE VARIABLES
Strategic Resources
This investigation concentrated on two types of intangible
resources: intellectual resources and distinctive competencies.
Intellectual resources include number of copyrights, number of patents,
and number of trademarks. Distinctive competencies include: research and
development, production/operations, marketing/sales/distribution, and
administration. Strategic resources were operationalized from previous
studies of intangible resources. In specific, patent count and patent
citation count categories were from studies by Wright (1994), and Finkle
(1996). Cooperative agreement categories were adapted from McGee (1994),
Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven (1996), Miller and Shamsie (1995; 1996), and
Mosakowski (1991). Trademarks and copyrights as predictors of
performance were not found in the strategic resources literature. This
research extended prior studies by including these measures of
intangible resources. Competencies were adapted from Rangone (1999).
Intellectual Resources
Indicators of patents and patent applications were found in the S-1
documents. The self-disclosed IPO data were considered to be the best
data for measuring patents. Trademarks were operationalized as
registered or unregistered trademarks self-disclosed in the initial
public offering statement. The prospectus documents were chosen as the
best source of data because companies have a high level of
responsibility in reporting the information. Copyrights were
operationalized from the Library of Congress database. In comparing the
results of the database search with the initial public offering
statements, it was noticed that some companies do not choose to report
copyright information in the prospectus statements. Apparently the
writers of the documents did not see copyrights as information that is
material to the prospective investor. Therefore, this research used the
Library of Congress information.
Distinctive Competencies
Distinctive competence was operationalized by evaluating the
relative strength of the functional areas of the firm. Four functional
areas were assessed: research and development; production/operations;
marketing/sales/distribution; and administration. Each functional area
was assigned a value of strong, average, or weak, based on the
company's ability compared to the competition (referred to as
strategic competence on the classification grid).
When firms had more than one strong functional area, the internal
capabilities rankings were used to determine the firm's distinctive
competence. Therefore, when the firm has more than one strong functional
area relative to the competition, the distinctive competence was defined
as the strong functional area which has the highest internal
capabilities ranking.
Generic Strategy
Generic strategy was adopted from the model proposed by Porter
(1987). There are two possible generic competitive advantages: low cost
and differentiation. Companies were classified as low cost if their
prospectus said the company was "price competitive." It was
inferred that low prices were associated with low cost. Companies were
classified as differentiation if the prospectus indicated that the firm
provided unique products or services.
Stage of the Industry Life Cycle
This study used a seven-stage model of the industry life cycle
(Robinson, 1998; Robinson & McDougall, 1998). The seven stages were:
startup, growth, shakeout, maturity, saturation, decline, and
rejuvenation. Each stage in the industry life cycle was operationalized
with certain indicators: industry growth rate, long-term trend in the
industry growth rate, and gross national product.
New Venture Performance
Shareholder value created was a ratio based on changes in common
stock prices and dividends of ventures. It was calculated by the
following equation (Robinson & McDougall, 1998):
SVC = (SP4 - SP1) + D2-4) / SP1
where SVC represents shareholder value created, SP4 was the stock
price at the end of year four, SP1 was the stock price at the end of
year one, and D2-4 was the cumulative dividends for years two through
four. Stock prices were adjusted for stock dividends and stock splits.
METHOD
The Selection of the Industries to be Studied
In addition to the three criteria listed above, one additional
criterion was used to select the sample for this study. The sample had
to account for the degree to which the industries involved had
contributed to job growth. This criterion was added because one of the
major contributions of new ventures to society is job growth. And, since
job growth is closely associated with rapid growth in total demand, the
first step in the selection process was to identify high-growth
industries in the U.S. economy.
An analysis of the 100 fastest-growing firms in the U.S. (Fortune,
1996) helped to identify the highest-growth industries. Of the 100
fastest-growing firms, 38 were in the High-Technology Sector, 12 were in
the Health Care Sector, and 7 were in the Energy Sector. This suggested
that many high-growth industries would be in these sectors of the
economy.
A list of industries with at least 10 new ventures conducting
initial public offerings during 1987 through 1993 is presented in Table
1 (Inc. Magazine, 1987-1993). The list shows that the most frequently
occurring industrial codes were 7372 (prepackaged software), 2834
(pharmaceutical preparations), and 6712 (bank holding companies).
Furthermore, an analysis of the types of new ventures that went public
indicates that 12 of the 17 most frequently occurring new venture
industry codes were in the high-technology or health care sectors. This
evidence supported the idea that high-technology and health care sectors
were growing rapidly.
To further investigate which industries should be included in this
study, the Standard Industrial Classification Codes were classified as
Health Care Sector and High-Technology Sector for the initial public
offerings between 1987 and 1993 as given in Table 2. The Pharmaceutical,
Biotechnology, and Medical Equipment industries comprised almost 6
percent of the 2,371 initial public offerings during that period. The
Computer, Semiconductor, and Software industries contributed another 6
percent.
High-technology and health care sectors each had more initial
public offerings than any other sector in the U.S. from 1987 to 1993 and
the industries within the high-technology and health care sectors had
more initial public offerings than any other industry except for
banking. Due to the high rates of reorganization and because no banking
firm was listed on the top 100 fastest-growing firms, the banking
industry was not included in the sample for this study.
Venture Selection
Because this research dealt with the performance of new ventures,
three criteria were required. First, the age of the venture was eight
years or less (Biggadike, 1979; Weiss, 1981). Second, ventures were
independent startups rather than corporate ventures (Hofer &
Sandberg, 1987). Third, the ventures were involved in the creation of
goods and services rather than serving as types of financial
instruments.
An initial search found 303 firms qualified for this study. Twenty
five firms were randomly selected from each of the six industries in the
study. The three industries of the health care sector each contribute 25
firms for a total of 75 firms from health care and the three industries
of the high-technology sector each contribute 25 firms for a total of 75
firms from high-technology. The six industries combine for a total
sample of 150 firms. The ventures in the sample were blocked to ensure
equal representation in all 6 industries.
Data Collection
There were four major reasons for selecting Securities and Exchange
Commission initial public offering prospectus filings as a source of new
venture data. First, these filings must meet Securities and Exchange
Commission content standards, and therefore they offer a reliable source
of new venture data (Marino, Castaldi, & Dollinger, 1990). Second,
the standardized form used in initial public offering filings
facilitated the use of content analysis. Third, Securities and Exchange
Commission filings were considered more comprehensive than proposals
submitted to venture capitalists. Finally, because of Securities and
Exchange Commission oversight, the filings were thought to provide more
objective information than questionnaires that may be subject to
rationalization of actions by self-reporting entrepreneurs (McGee,
1994).
High-growth new ventures for this study were taken from the list of
all initial public offerings between 1987 and 1993 as given by
Investment Dealer's Digest (1987-1994). This time period was
selected for three reasons. First, 1987 through 1993 was a time of high
levels of activity for high-growth ventures. Therefore, there was a
relatively large number of new ventures with public information
available. Second, one of the industries in the study, software, was
first identified as a separate industry by the standard industrial
classification system in 1987. Consequently, it was decided that all
data should begin in 1987 to facilitate intra-industry comparisons.
Third, due to need to operationale new venture performance over a three
year period, 1993 was the latest initial public offering date in which
performance data were available. N e w venture performance data included
stock prices, dividends, stock splits, and number of employees. Stock
prices were gathered from the Daily Stock Report (1987-1996). Dividends,
stock splits, and number of employees were gathered from Moody's
Investment Services (1995-1997a, b, c). Copyright data were gathered
from the Library of Congress Information System.
Because data came from initial public offering registration
statements, the researcher had performed content analysis to code the
data collection forms. To check coding accuracy, the study included an
inter-rater reliability procedure. In all, the researcher included 29
data points on 150 observations for a total of 4,350 individual pieces
of data. Due to the magnitude of the data collection effort, it was
deemed impractical to conduct an inter-rater reliability check on the
full sample. Instead, this study adopted the procedure discussed in
Kachigan (1986) whereby a sub-sample of 18 ventures were used to infer
the reliability for the full sample. A chi-square test was used on the
18 observations to check the reliability. Every measure except stage of
industry life cycle indicate positive inter-rater reliability
(p<.0001 in all cases).
Sample Description
The average performance of ventures included in this study as
measured by shareholder value created was -0.42751. In other words, on
the average, shareholders lost 42.7 percent of their investment
(adjusted for the NASDAQ average return during the period of the study).
The range of shareholder value created was from -1.6255 to 3.7296. So
some shareholders lost over 100 percent of their investment (after
adjusting for the market return) while some shareholders almost
quadrupled their money in three years. The average age was 5.3 years,
the range was from 1 to 8 years, and the mode was 6 years. Ventures in
this sample had about 5 to 6 years of history before going public.
Statistical Methods
Data in this study were extremely non-normal (SAS Institute, 1988).
A normal probability plot of the residuals using the final sample
clearly indicated non-normality, and the W statistic for normality in
the SAS procedure was 0.944576 with a corresponding p-value of 0.001.
So, it was extremely unlikely that the residuals were normally
distributed. Because the data were very non-normal, it was decided that
the analysis should proceed with SAS nonparametric statistics.
Specifically, the research used the Kruskall-Wallis analysis of variance
procedure for testing the equality of medians from three or more
samples. This non-parametric procedure was used because non-parametric
statistics were more robust than parametric statistics when parametric
assumptions are violated (Gibbons, 1985; Daniel, 1990).
Results
The results for the possible interaction between generic strategy
and strategic resources are given in Table 3. These results generally
support the research hypothesis that new venture performance varies
based on the possible interaction between generic strategy and
distinctive competencies. In particular, new ventures adopting low-cost
generic strategies perform better when they possess administration
distinctive competencies.
The results for the possible interaction between intellectual
resources and stage of the industry life cycle are presented in Table 3.
These results support the research hypothesis that new venture
performance varies based on a possible interaction between stage of the
industry life cycle and intellectual resources. Specifically, this study
shows that new ventures owning patents or owning copyrights perform
better than other new ventures when they are entering late stages of the
industry life cycle.
Discussion
Findings from this study have implications for entrepreneurship
practice. For example, these results may be helpful in the
decision-making process for venture capitalists, investment bankers,
angel investors, or other new venture investors. In addition, these
findings may be instructive to entrepreneurs in their understanding of
elements necessary in the enterprise-creation process.
Theorists have long speculated that performance is related to
strategic resources, but few empirical studies have been conducted to
confirm or disconfirm the relationship. This research provides
much-needed evidence to add to the discussion of resource-based theory
as well as to the study of entrepreneurship. Furthermore, this study
identifies multiple measures of strategic resources that may be used in
future studies of new venture performance. In particular, this work
indicates the importance of intangible resources which may provide a
link between resource-based theory and knowledge-based theory in future
research.
This study has shown that the current model of new venture
performance should be revised to include strategic resources in certain
situations. Prior studies have shown the importance of intellectual
resources (Chatterjee & Wernerfelt, 1991) and distinctive
competencies (Chandler & Hanks, 1994; Markides & Williamson,
1996). However, none of the previous studies considered strategic
resources and the other variables in the research model, namely strategy
and industry structure, in the same study.
It is suggested that future research help overcome the limitations
of this study and extend the scope of this research based on the
findings here. One suggestion for future research design is to
incorporate methods of normalizing data, so parametric statistics may be
utilized. As entrepreneurship research advances, studies should begin
testing causal models. In addition, this research could be extended
through development of a broader, more representative sample to make the
conclusions more generalizable. Further, extending the research sample
by additional time periods may provide for longitudinal testing, and
future entrepreneurship research may benefit from using alternative
forms of data-gathering techniques such a direct observation,
interviews, or surveys.
There are several theoretical extensions of this study which may
help to explain the overall effect of new venture performance. The most
pressing is probably the testing of strategy, industry structure,
strategic resources, and entrepreneurial team in the same model. Other
theoretical extensions might include the influence, if any, of
organizational learning, of employee knowledge, skills, and abilities,
or of rates of technology development on new venture performance.
CONCLUSIONS
These results imply that entrepreneurs should match their strategic
resources to the situation. New ventures adopting a low-cost approach
should develop administration competencies in order to establish a
competitive advantage over rivals. It is possible that adding better and
more administrative personnel could pay for itself by a higher return to
stockholders.
Furthermore, when new ventures are in industries in the shakeout
stage, intellectual property such as patents and copyrights become more
important. They may be particularly important in high-growth industries
such as explored in this study. Possessing intellectual property may
enable firms to differentiate their goods and services from their
competition or may provide a means of limiting direct competition.
REFERENCES
Azzone, G., Bertele, U., & Rangone, A. (1995). Measuring
resources for supporting resource-based competition. Management
Decision, 33(9), 57-62.
Barney, J.B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive
advantages. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120.
Barney, J. B. (2001). Is the resource-based "view" a
useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes. Academy of
Management Review, 26 (1), 41-56.
Biggadike, E. R. (1979). The risky business of diversification.
Harvard Business Review, May-June, 103-111.
Brush, C. G., Greene, P. G., & Hart, M. M. (2001). From initial
idea to unique advantage: The entrepreneurial challenge of constructing
a resource base. Academy of Management Executive, 15(1), 64-78.
Chandler, G., N., & Hanks, S. H. (1994). Market attractiveness,
resource-based capabilities, venture strategies, and venture
performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 9, 331-349.
Chatterjee, S. & Wernerfelt, B. (1991). The link between
resources and type of diversification: Theory and evidence. Strategic
Management Journal, 12, 33-48.
Conner, K. R. (1991). A historical comparison of resource-based
theory and five schools of thought within industrial organizational
economics: Do we have a new theory of the firm? Journal of Management,
17(1), 121-154.
Daniel, W. W. (1990). Applied nonparametric statistics (2nd
Edition). Boston: PWS-Kent Publishing Company. Daily Stock Reports
(1987-1996)
Dierickx, I., & Cool, K., (1989). Asset stock accumulation and
sustainability of competitive advantage. Management Science, 35(12),
1504-1510.
Eisenhardt, K. M., & Schoonhoven, C. B. (1996). Resource-based
view of strategic alliance formation: Strategic and social effects in
entrepreneurial firms. Organization Science, 7 (2), 136-150.
Finkle, T. A. (1996). The relationship between technological
strength and initial offering size in small high-tech firms: The case of
biotechnology. Academy of Management Conference Proceedings.
Fiol, C. M. (1991). Managing Culture as a Competitive Resource: An
identity-based view of sustainable competitive advantage. Journal of
Management, 17(1), 191-212.
Gibbons, J. D. (1985). Nonparametric methods for quantitative
analysis (2nd edition). Columbus, OH: American Sciences Press, Inc.
Hall, R. (1993). A framework linking intangible resources and
capabilities to sustainable competitive advantage. Strategic Management
Journal, 14, 607-618.
Hofer, C. W. & Sandberg, W. (1987). Improving New Venture
Performance: Some guidelines for success. American Journal of Small
Business, Summer.
Inc. magazine. (1987-1993). The Inc. 100.
Investment Dealer's Digest. (1987-1994). Directory of
Corporate Financing.
Kachigan, S. K. (1986). Statistical analysis: An interdisciplinary introduction to univariate and multivariate methods. New York: Radius
Press.
King, A. W., & Zeithaml, C. P. (2001). Competencies and firm
performance: Examining the causal ambiguity paradox. Strategic
Management Journal, 22, 75-99.
Klavans, R. (1994). The measurement of a competitor's core
competence. In G. Hamel and A. Heene (Eds.), Competence-based
competition NY: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., 171-182.
Mahoney, J. T. & Pandian, J. R. (1992). The resource-based view
within the conversation of strategic management. Strategic Management
Journal, 13, 363-380.
Marino, K. E., Castaldi, R. M. & Dollinger, M. J. (1989).
Content analysis in entrepreneurship research: The case of initial
public offerings. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Fall: 51-66.
Markides, C. C. & Williamson, P. J. (1996). Corporate
diversification and organizational structure: A resource-based view.
Academy of Management Journal, 39(2), 340-367.
McGee, J. E. (1994). Cooperative strategy and new venture
performance. New York: Garland Publishing, Inc.
Miller, D., & Shamsie, J. (1996). The resource-based view of
the firm in two environments: The Hollywood film studios from 1936 to
1965. Academy of Management Journal, 39(3), 519-543.
Moody's Investment Services, Inc. (1995, 1996, 1997).
Moody's Industrial Manual. New York: Dun & Bradstreet.
Moody's Investment Services, Inc. (1995, 1996, 1997).
Moody's OTC Industrial Manual. New York: Dun & Bradstreet.
Moody's Investment Services, Inc. (1995, 1996, 1997).
Moody's OTC Unlisted Industrial Manual. New York: Dun &
Bradstreet.
Mosakowski, E. (1991). Organizational boundaries and economic
performance: An empirical study of entrepreneurial computer firm.
Strategic Management Journal, 12, 115-133.
Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A
resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal, 14(3), 179-192.
Porter, M. E. (1987). From competitive advantage to corporate
strategy. Harvard Business Review, May/August: 149-160.
Rangone, A. (1999). A resource-based approach to strategy analysis
in small-medium sized enterprises. Small Business Economics, 12,
233-248.
Robinson, K. C. (1998). An examination of the influence of industry
structure on eight alternative measures of new venture performance for
high potential independent new ventures. Journal of Business Venturing,
14, 165-187.
Robinson, K. C. & McDougall, P. P. (1998). The impact of
alternative operationalizations of industry structural elements on
measures of performance for entrepreneurial manufacturing ventures.
Strategic Management Journal, 19, 1079-1100.
SAS Institute, Inc. (1988). SAS/STAT User's Guide, Release
6.03. Cary, NC: SAS Institute, Inc.
Schulze, W. S. (1994). The two schools of thought in resource-based
theory: Definitions and implications for research. In P. Shrivastava, A.
Huff & J. Dutton (Eds). Advances in strategic management:
Resource-based view of the firm, Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, 127-158.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1950). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. (3rd
Ed.) New York: Harper & Row.
US Copyright Office, (1997) Library of Congress Information System
Database. Washington, D.C.: Library of Congress
Weiss, L. A. (1981). Start-up businesses: A comparison of
performances. Sloan Management Review, 23, 37-53.
Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic
Management Journal, 5, 171-180.
Williamson, O. E., (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism.
New York: Free Press.
Wright, R. W. (1994). The effects of tacitness and tangibility on
the diffusion of knowledge-based resources. Academy of Management Best
Papers Proceedings. 52-56.
Calvin M. Bacon, Jr., University of Arkansas at Little Rock
Charles W. Hofer, University of Georgia
Table 1: Frequency of New Venture Industry Codes of Initial Public
Offerings for 1987 through 1993
Industry Code Name SIC Code Frequency
Pharmaceutical Preparations 2834 57
Prepackaged Software 7372 57
Bank Holding Companies 6712 44
Surgical & Medical Instruments 3841 35
Biological Products Except Diagnostic 2836 34
Semiconductor & Related Products 3674 34
Computer Peripheral Equipment 3577 25
Electromedical Equipment 3845 24
Eating Places 5812 24
Fire, Marine, & Casualty Insurance 6331 24
Telephone & Telegraph Apparatus 6331 24
Surgical Appliances & Supplies 3661 20
Diagnostic Substances 2835 16
Electronic Computers 3571 16
Radiotelephone Communications 4812 14
Electronic Components 3679 13
Health & Allied Services Nec 8099 13
Table 2: Initial Public Offerings Between 1987 and 1993 by Sector
Sector Industry SIC Name
Health Care Pharmaceutical Pharmaceutical Preparation
Health Care Biotechnology Biological Products
Health Care Medical Eqmt. Surgical & Medical Instr.
Health Care Medical Eqmt. Electromedical Equipment
Total Health Care
High Technology Computers Electronic Computers
High Technology Computers Computer Storage Devices
High Technology Computers Computer Terminals
High Technology Computer Computer Peripheral Eqmt.
High Technology Semiconductor Semiconductors
High Technology Software Computer Programming
High Technology Software Prepackaged Software
High Technology Software Computer Integrated Syst
Total High Technology
Total New Ventures
Sector SIC Count
Health Care 2834 60
Health Care 2836 34
Health Care 3841 35
Health Care 3845 24
Total Health Care 153
High Technology 3571 34
High Technology 3572 7
High Technology 3575 4
High Technology 3577 29
High Technology 3674 36
High Technology 7371 9
High Technology 7372 63
High Technology 7373 11
Total High Technology 193
Total New Ventures 346
Table 3: Summary of Results
H Measures p
1a Production Competencies, Low Cost > Others, 0.4102
Low Cost
1b Administration Competencies, Low Cost > Others, 0.0222
Low Cost
1c R&D Competencies, Differentiation > Others, 0.7493
Differentiation
1d Marketing Competencies, Differentiation > Others, 0.1043
Differentiation
2a Patents, Shakeout > No Patents, Shakeout 0.0364
2b Trademarks, Shakeout > No Trademarks, Shakeout 0.7287
2c Copyrights, Shakeout > No Copyrights, Shakeout 0.0078