Ease of entry: a step beyond entry barriers.
Kunkel, Scott W. ; Hofer, Charles W.
ABSTRACT
The concept of entry barriers has been passed from discipline to
discipline--from Industrial Organization Economics to Strategic
Management to Entrepreneurship. Recent attempts to examine the impact
that entry barriers have on new venture performance (i.e., Yip, 1982,
and McDougall, 1987), have found that the direct impact of entry
barriers on new venture performance is difficult to gauge when entry
barriers are measured in traditional ways. This paper suggests that the
traditional view of entry barriers is incomplete and proposes a new
construct, called "ease of entry," (1) which includes, but is
not limited to entry barriers.
INTRODUCTION
Bain (1956) introduced the concept of "entry barriers" to
the literature of industrial organization economics (IO). Hofer (1975)
brought the concept of entry barriers to the field of strategic
management. Porter (1980) expanded the concept, breaking entry barriers
down into two classes: entry barriers created as a result of the
structural characteristics of the industry ("structural entry
barriers") and entry barriers created as a result of the threat of
retaliation by incumbents ("retaliation entry barriers").
Yip (1982) expanded the understanding of entry barriers by applying
the strategy paradigm to prior IO theories of entry and entry barriers.
Yip expanded entry barrier theory to include entry through acquisition,
rather than limiting entry to new legal entities, as had previously been
done in IO theory. Yip also introduced the term "entry
gateways" to represent situations in which an entrant may not face
barriers to entry but, instead, may actually be in an advantageous
position vis-a-vis incumbents in the industry.
McDougall (1987) attempted to measure the impact that entry
barriers have on new venture performance. In testing this relationship,
McDougall operationalized "entry barriers" as a composite of
five variables. Accepting IO theory, McDougall included as the five most
significant sub-variables of entry barriers:
1. economies of scale (using minimum efficient plant size as a
surrogate for economies of scale)
2. product differentiation (using advertising-to-sales ratio as a
surrogate for product differentiation)
3. industry concentration, (using the four-firm concentration
ratio)
4. capital intensity, (using the assets/value-added ratio as a
surrogate for capital intensity)
5. rate of growth of total market demand in the industry.
McDougall (1987) calculated a composite height of entry barriers
score for each of nine four-digit Standard Industrial (SIC) codes, then
compared this composite height of entry barriers score with the
performance of the firms in that SIC code. McDougall found some support
for the proposition that entry barriers affect profitability of firms
within industries, but no support for the proposition that entry
barriers affect market share or market share growth, measures of
operational performance.
McDougall's (1987) five sub-variables are based on those which
IO theorists have most often suggested as the most important
sub-variables in entry barriers. This paper makes three suggestions:
1. One of the five sub-variables which IO theory suggests as making
up entry barriers (industry concentration) should not be included
in entry barriers at all because it influences entry both
positively and negatively.
2. There is a set of sub-variables called "entry gateways" which
should be included along with entry barriers in the analysis of
entry.
3. The inclusion of entry gateways along with entry barriers in the
analysis of entry into industries suggests a new construct, called
"ease of entry."
EXCLUSION OF INDUSTRY CONCENTRATION FROM ENTRY BARRIERS
IO researchers have consistently hypothesized that "industry
concentration" is an entry barrier. McDougall (1987) included
concentration ratio in the calculation of entry barriers, thereby
implicitly accepting the IO assumption that concentrated industries are
more difficult to enter than less concentrated industries.
Studies by Biggadike (1976, 1979) and by Hobson and Morrison
(1983), on the other hand, indicate that new venture entry is more
successful when the entered industry has a dominant competitor, one with
greater than 49% market share, than when the largest competitor has less
than a 25% share. This indicates that a high concentration ratio, rather
than being a barrier to entry, may be a factor which makes entry easier.
Hofer and Sandberg (1987) explain why this phenomenon may be
exactly the opposite of what had been earlier hypothesized in IO
literature. As they explain, if the few industry leaders have a very
large share of the market, then each of the other competitors has a very
small share of the market.
The key point here is that new entrants almost never compete
head-to-head with the industry leader. Rather, they typically seek entry
into smaller segments (or niches) of the market where they face either
no competition or competition from the smaller competitors in the
industry (p. 13).
Since new entrants usually compete with the smaller competitors in
the industry, when the industry leaders are relatively stronger, the
smaller competitors are relatively weaker and more vulnerable to attack
by a new venture.
Peters (1987) offers another possible explanation as to why
concentrated industries may be easier to enter than less concentrated
industries. Peters suggests that large firms are often myopic. In
industries populated by a few large firms, each firm frequently fights
for its share of the "mass markets." In making their products
as generic as possible, in order to appeal to the largest number of
potential customers as possible, these firms often leave several smaller
market segments unserved or under-served. These unserved or under-served
market segments offer opportunity for smaller new ventures which are
able to serve these smaller market segments profitably.
It appears, then, that measuring "industry concentration"
is measuring the wrong variable. The fact that an industry is highly
concentrated may act simultaneously to make entry more difficult and to
make entry easier. Whether a few firms have the lion's share of the
market, therefore, is not directly relevant to a potential new entrant.
What is relevant, however, is whether there are market segments which
are unserved or under-served.
As an illustration, assume that one firm holds virtually 100% of a
market (monopoly, the ultimate in "industry concentration").
Assume, however, that it is serving several distinct market segments,
each of which has significantly different needs. It is serving them with
a single generic product which serves the purpose for all market
segments adequately, but does not serve any one segment's needs
completely. This situation would be an open invitation to a new venture
to enter the industry serving one or more market segments with products
which are more specifically tailored to the particular needs of the
market segments. This is the situation which prevailed when General
Motors took the U.S. automobile market from Henry Ford in the 1930s by
offering several models of cars, each designed to appeal more
specifically to a single market segment than the Ford Model T, which was
designed to be the car for everyone. The high "industry
concentration" in this case is not an entry barrier but, rather, an
entry gateway.
On the other hand, assume that several firms, each with a small
market share (low "industry concentration"), serve a market
which is basically homogeneous (an unlikely, yet possible situation). In
this market, the needs of every consumer are basically the same. Each
firm provides a product which fulfills the needs of every consumer and
seen as excellent substitutes for one another. In this case, it would be
difficult for a new venture to enter the industry since there are no
market segments which are unserved or under-served. In spite of low
"industry concentration," the entry barrier is high. Because
of these theoretical weaknesses in the industry concentration construct,
as well as the empirical contradictions (Biggadike, 1976, 1979; Hobson
& Morrison, 1983, versus IO literature), this paper suggests that
"industry concentration" should not be considered to be only
an entry barrier.
ENTRY GATEWAYS
Yip (1982), in his analysis of entry barriers, suggested that there
are certain situations in which mitigating circumstances may neutralize entry barriers, even to the extent of placing a new entrant in an
advantageous position vis-a-vis incumbents in the industry. These
situations Yip called "entry gateways." Yip, unfortunately,
did not expound on the concept of entry gateways other than to suggest
that one such entry gateway is "industry disequilibrium."
According to Yip, "industry disequilibrium" can be caused by
rapid growth of the industry, recent technological change, high capacity
utilization (shortage of supply), and the exit of incumbents from the
industry (p. 39).
Yip's definition of entry gateways, however, suggests that
sometimes entry gateways may be created, not as a result of any
structural condition within the industry, but due to the unique set of
skills and resources which are in the possession of the potential
entrant. It appears, therefore, that there are two kinds of entry
gateways: entry gateways which are a result of the structural
characteristics of the industry ("structural entry gateways")
and entry gateways created by the unique set of skills, resources, and
contacts possessed by the potential entrant ("resource entry
gateways"). This recognition of the impact which entry gateways
have on entry barriers suggests a broader construct, "ease of
entry," which includes entry barriers as affected and mitigated by
entry gateways.
EASE OF ENTRY
Kunkel (1991) surveyed twenty-one works in the fields of Industrial
Organization Economics, Strategic Management, and New Venture
Performance and identified fifty-eight industry structural variables
which have been suggested in those twenty-one works as being significant
contributors to the structure of an industry, thus having an impact on
business unit performance. Thirty-one of the fifty-eight industry
structural variables so identified influence industry structure
primarily by their effect on entry into the industry. Figure 1
classifies these variables based on whether their effect would be as an
entry barrier or an entry gateway, then sub-categorizes the variables
into "structural entry barriers" ("cost based" and
"non-cost based") and "retaliation entry barriers,"
and into "structural entry gateways" and "resource entry
gateways."
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
"Structural entry barriers" are those structural
characteristics of an industry which make entry more difficult. The
effect of these "structural entry barriers" is cumulative;
that is, an industry which exhibits several of the characteristics which
create "structural entry barriers" is more difficult to enter
than an industry which exhibits only a few of these characteristics.
However, one very high structural entry barrier may be more effective at
preventing the entry of a specific potential entrant than several
moderately high structural barriers.
"Retaliation entry barriers" are those characteristics of
an industry which increase the likelihood of strong and effective
retaliation by incumbents. The existence of these characteristics does
not guarantee that retaliation will be strong and effective, or that it
will occur at all; it merely increases the probability that retaliation
will occur. A potential new entrant will increase its estimate of the
risk of prolonged and unprofitable warfare when retaliation is a strong
likelihood, thereby decreasing the expected profits to be gained by
entering the industry.
An application of the "time value of money" concept in
financial theory helps to explain why this decrease in expected profits
occurs. The high probability of retaliation results in a decrease in the
discounted present value of the future income to be derived from
entering the industry. This decrease in the discounted present value of
the future income streams is a result of two factors:
1) estimates of the expected future incomes decrease
2) the riskiness of the estimates of future incomes increases,
thereby requiring a higher discounting interest rate.
This discounting process has the effect of decreasing the
desirability of entering an industry where there is a strong probability
of retaliation, compared to an industry where there is little likelihood
of retaliation. Thus, the threat of retaliation acts as an entry
barrier, and the greater the perceived likelihood of retaliation and the
greater the perceived likely strength of that retaliation, the greater
the discounting of future income flows and the lower the expected value of entry into the industry.
"Structural entry gateways" are those characteristics of
an industry which create influences which mitigate the severity of
structural entry barriers or decrease the likelihood of effective
retaliation. Structural entry gateways are also cumulative, i.e., an
industry which exhibits several structural entry gateways is easier to
enter than an industry which exhibits only one, but one large opening as
a result of a structural entry gateway may make more of a difference to
a particular prospective entrant than several small structural entry
gateways. These entry gateways are created as a result of the
characteristics of the industry and do not rely on special skills or
resources of the entering firm.
"Resource entry gateways," on the other hand, are
particular skills, resources, or contacts which a potential new entrant
may possess which act as a mitigating influence on the structural and
retaliation entry barriers the potential new entrant faces in the
industry it hopes to enter.
Based on the recognition that entry gateways act to mitigate the
effect of entry barriers, a more complete construct seems to be
"ease of entry," which is a function of entry barriers as
mitigated and influenced by entry gateways. "Structural ease of
entry" includes those factors which are identifiable as part of the
industry structure, including "structural entry barriers,"
"retaliation entry barriers," and "structural entry
gateways."
A major shortcoming of the "entry barriers" construct as
developed by Bain (1956) and expanded by Porter (1980) is that each of
the sub-variables (for example, "gross margins") is
categorized in only two classes, high and low. Low gross margins are
viewed as an entry barrier and high gross margins are viewed as the
absence of the entry barrier. A much richer construct becomes apparent,
however, when gross margins are categorized into three classes, high,
average, and low.
Exceptionally low gross margins create an entry barrier, as
hypothesized by Porter (1980). Average gross margins imply the absence
of this barrier. Exceptionally high gross margins, however, create an
entry gateway, making it easier for a new venture to enter the industry
since it is so easy to recover entry costs with the exceptionally high
gross margins. Many potential investors, entrepreneurs, and corporations
are scanning the environment to discover opportunities. Gross margins
which are much higher than average invite new entrants.
Many of the sub-variables in Figure 1 appear in more than one list.
For example, although industry concentration should not be considered an
entry barrier without considering its impact as an entry gateway, Figure
1 includes industry concentration in three lists. First, industry
concentration can be considered a structural entry barrier to the extent
that concentration encourages powerful competitors to defend their turf.
Industry concentration also presents a potential retaliation barrier,
since a small number of competitors, at least theoretically, can more
easily act in concert to prevent entry and/or retaliate against new
entrants. Industry concentration is also an entry gateway, however,
because concentrated industries frequently have smaller, weaker
competitors and/or unserved/under-served market niches.
Other sub-variables appear in more than one list, with a high (or
low) value acting as an entry barrier and the opposite value acting as
an entry gateway. For instance, high entry costs (including high capital
intensity, high advertising intensity, high selling intensity, high
R&D intensity, large marginal plant size, etc.) all act as cost
based structural entry barriers. Extremely low entry costs (including
low capital intensity, low advertising intensity, low selling intensity,
low R&D intensity, small marginal plant size, etc.) act as an entry
gateway, making industries with such characteristics easier to enter and
making it more difficult for incumbents to build barriers to deter
entry.
The construct presented in Figure 1 is involved and includes a
large number of sub-variables. This model can be simplified by grouping
the sub-variables into sets, as shown in Table 1.
As can be seen in Table 1, each of the five major impacts on entry
(existence of opportunity for entry, economics of entry, potential
effectiveness of entry, likelihood of retaliation, and potential
effectiveness of retaliation) is influenced by groups of sub-variables.
First, the "non-cost based structural entry barriers" as
offset by the "structural entry gateways" determine the
"existence of the opportunity for entry." Second, the
"cost-based entry barriers" combined with the "gross
margins" available in the industry determine the "economics of
entry." Third, since control of the resources for entry is
essential for successful and effective entry, the "resource-based
entry gateways" determine the "potential effectiveness of
entry." Fourth, the "retaliation entry barriers"
determine the "likelihood of retaliation." Fifth, the
"control of resources by incumbents" determines the
"potential effectiveness of the retaliation."
A DESCRIPTIVE METAPHOR
In order to capture the effect that "entry barriers" and
"entry gateways" have on "ease of entry," a metaphor
is useful (2). A new entrant into an industry can be likened to a
burglar attempting to gain entry to a mansion. Different barriers are
effective against different potential burglars because different
burglars have different talents, skills, and resources for overcoming
different barriers. For instance, a cat burglar may find walls to be of
little or no deterrence, whereas the electronics expert is not foiled by
a security system.
The best defense of the mansion is attained by having several types
of barriers, high walls, locked doors, security systems, etc. Different
barriers will provide different deterrent value to different burglars,
but if they can be combined, they can provide a formidable obstacle for
any burglar.
The cat burglar who discovers that the mansion has a security
system may retreat. The electronics expert who finds that the only
unbarred window is on the third floor may choose another target. Whether
a specific barrier is effective against a specific potential entrant is
a function of the barrier as it matches the particular skills and
resources of the potential entrant. Nonetheless, the more barriers there
are, the lower the likelihood that any potential entrant will have the
skills and resources necessary to overcome them all.
Following the logic of the mansion metaphor, it may be that no
combination of locks, doors, walls, and security systems can keep a well
equipped and determined professional burglar from entering the mansion.
This is not to say, however, that a well secured mansion is as
vulnerable to invasion as one which is totally unprotected and open. The
walls and door-locks keep the amateur burglar and the casual passer-by
from entering, as well as making it more difficult for even the
professional burglar to get in, thereby decreasing the probability that
anyone will successfully breach the security of the mansion.
From the point of view of the incumbents in the industry, the
existence of higher entry barriers increases the profitability of the
industry as a whole, as Bain (1956) and other IO researchers suggest.
Sandberg (1984, 1986) found that raising the height of entry barriers
after the new venture has entered the industry (thereby becoming an
incumbent in the industry) significantly increases the performance of
the venture.
Orr (1974) established that entry barriers decrease the occurrence
of entry, thereby increasing the profitability of the incumbents in an
industry with high entry barriers over that of firms in industries with
low entry barriers. Orr only classified entry barriers as high or low,
however. If the concept of entry gateways mitigating the influence of
entry barriers has validity, it would seem that moderate entry barriers
would eliminate the majority of potential entrants, whereas even a high
level of entry barriers would not totally eliminate the possibility of
an individual potential entrant being able to overcome the barriers to
entry.
If this were the case, raising entry barriers from low to moderate
would have a greater impact on deterring entry than raising entry
barriers from moderate to high. This was exactly the finding in one
study by Mann (cited in Caves, 1987). Although Mann was at a loss to
explain his observations, they are directly in line with what would be
expected according to the above discussion of the effect of entry
gateways on entry barriers.
THE NEXT STEPS
This paper has made three major points. First, it has recommended
that at least one of the five sub-variables which IO theory suggests as
making up entry barriers (industry concentration) should not be
considered an entry barrier at all, since it has the simultaneous
effects of both discouraging and encouraging entry. By showing the mixed
contributions which industry concentration makes, this paper has argued
that industry concentration, contrary to IO theory, is not strictly an
entry barrier.
Second, this paper developed the concept of entry gateways, as
introduced by Yip (1982), and has shown that entry gateways should be
included along with entry barriers in any analysis of entry into
industries. The development of the concept of entry gateways, however,
indicates the need for a broader construct than entry barriers when
analyzing entry.
Third, therefore, this paper developed and presented the conceptual
construct called "ease of entry" to better represent the
factors influencing entry. Moving from the general model of ease of
entry which included over 30 sub-variables, this paper then simplified
the construct to include five influences on entry:
1. the existence of the opportunity for entry
2. the economics of entry
3. the potential effectiveness of entry
4. the likelihood of retaliation by incumbents
5. the potential effectiveness of retaliation by incumbents
This paper has suggested a broadening of existing theory on entry
barriers. Nevertheless, much work remains to be done before the theory
of ease of entry is fully developed. Among the more important steps are
the following:
1. Methods need to be devised to operationalize the five groups of
sub-variables.
2. A data base needs to be built which will provide information on a
significant number of these sub-variables on several to many
industries.
3. Finally, tests of the validity of the new construct need to be
conducted so that the theory may be tested and expanded.
Because new venture entry has been shown to be such a major
contributor to growth in employment and the health of the economy as a
whole (Kunkel, 1991), it is crucial that new venture researchers develop
a better understanding of the factors which influence entry into
industries and contribute to the success and failure of new ventures.
Only by better understanding the barriers to entry and the factors which
influence ventures' ability to overcome such barriers can the high
costs of new venture failure be reduced.
REFERENCES
Bain, J. S. (1956). Barriers to new competition. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
Biggadike, E. R. (1976). Entry, strategy, and performance.
(Doctoral Dissertation, Harvard University). Dissertation Abstracts
International. 37, 3006A.
Biggadike, E. (1979). Corporate diversification: Entry, strategy,
and performance. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Caves, R. E. (1987). American industry: Structure, conduct,
performance (6th ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Hobson, E. & Morrison, R. (1983). How do corporate start-up
ventures fare? Frontiers in entrepreneurship research, 390-410.
Hofer, C. (1975). Toward a Contingency Theory of Business Strategy.
Academy of Management Journal, 18, 784-810.
Hofer, C. & Sandberg, W. (1987). Improving new venture
performance: Some guidelines for success. American Journal of Small
Business, 12(1), 11-25.
Kunkel, S. (1991). The impact of strategy and industry structure on
new venture performance. (Doctoral Dissertation, University of Georgia).
McDougall, P. (1987). An analysis of strategy, entry barriers, and
origin as factors explaining new venture performance. (Doctoral
dissertation, University of South Carolina). Dissertation Abstracts
International, 48, 980A.
Orr, D. (1974). The determinants of entry: A study of the Canadian
manufacturing industries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 56, 58-66.
Ortony, A. (1975). Why metaphors are necessary and not just nice.
Educational Theory, 25(1), 45-53.
Peters, T. (1987). Thriving on chaos: Handbook for a management
revolution. New York: Harper & Row.
Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: The Free
Press.
Sandberg, W. R. (1984). The determinants of new venture
performance: Strategy, industry structure and entrepreneur. (Doctoral
dissertation, University of Georgia). Dissertation Abstracts
International, 46, 464A.
Sandberg, W. (1986). New venture performance: The role of strategy
and industry structure. Lexington: Lexington Books.
Weick, K. E. (1979). The social psychology of organizing, Reading,
MA: Addison-Wesley.
Yip, G. S. (1982). Barriers to entry: A corporate strategy
perspective. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
END NOTES
(1) The Ease of Entry concept can be viewed either from the
perspective of the new venture attempting to enter the industry or from
the perspective of the incumbents in the industry attempting to keep new
ventures out. Either positive or negative terms may be used. For
example, from the point of view of the incumbents in the industry,
positive terms for this concept include "security against
entry" and "entry defensibility" and negative terms
include "entry vulnerability" and "entry
susceptibility." From the point of view of the new venture,
positive terms include "ease of entry" and "entry
opportunity," and negative terms include "entry
difficulty," and "obstacles to entry." Since the
perspective of this paper is new ventures, the term "ease of
entry" is used.
(2) Ortony (1975) argues that when trying to understand complex
phenomena, metaphors are not just nice, they are necessary. Weick (1979)
explains that although metaphors are only partially complete
representations of reality, as are models, metaphors provide three
benefits: (1) metaphors provide a compact version of an event without
the need to spell out all the details; (2) they enable people to
predicate characteristics which are unnameable; and (3) they are closer
to perceived experience, more vivid emotionally, sensorially, and
cognitively. Therefore, like models, metaphors are tools for enhancing
communication.
Scott W. Kunkel, University of San Diego Charles W. Hofer,
University of Georgia
TABLE 1: Ease of Entry Sub-Variables
Non-cost Based Structural Entry Determine Existence of
Barriers and Structural Opportunity for
Entry Gateways Entry
Cost Based Structural Entry Determine Economics of Entry
Barriers
Resource Based Entry Gateways Determine Potential Effectiveness
(Control of Resources of Entry
by Entrant)
Retaliation Entry Barriers Determine Likelihood of
Retaliation
Control of Resources by Determine Potential Effectiveness
Incumbents of Retaliation