Psychological contracts in enterprises.
Jackson, William T. ; Elenkov, Detelin ; Wright, Peter 等
INTRODUCTION
The separation of ownership and control has been recognized from
different perspectives as a potential major organizational problem
(Berle & Means, 1932; McLean Parks & Schmedemann, 1994; Rousseau
& Shperling, 2003; Veblen, 1923). From an economic perspective, it
has been argued that the alignment of owners' and agents'
interests via the nexus of formal contracts requires attempts in the
resolution of the conflicts between the interests of the principals and
their agents (Berle & Means, 1932; Jensen & Meckling, 1976). The
problem of the separation of owners' and agents' interests
refers to agents promoting their personal interests at the expense of
principals whose interests are best served when their wealth is
maximized through the efforts of the agents. For the principals,
therefore, benefits are primarily relevant in economic terms. The
agents, however, not only prefer enhancements of their wealth, but also
enhancements of their non-economic utilities at the expense of
principals. Note that agents' wealth may be enhanced with their
employment rewards. Their non-economic benefits may encompass "the
physical appointments of the office, the attractiveness of the
secretarial staff, the level of employee discipline, the kind and amount
of charitable contributions ... etc." (Jensen & Meckling, 1976:
486). Effort reduction on the job may also increase the non-financial
utilities of agents at the expense of principals. Both the economic and
the non-economic benefits of agents are conceived to be driven by
self-interest, and self-interest is anticipated to be promoted
deceitfully. Hence according to economic scholars, in the absence of
inducements or monitoring/intervention, managers or employees will
deliberately and guilefully violate the terms of their formal employment
contract (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972; Jensen & Meckling, 1976).
From an organizational behavior perspective, it has alternatively
been contended what economists interpret as agents' propensity to
enhance their economic and non-economic benefits at the expense of
principals may actually occur because of limited information,
misunderstanding, or miscommunication (Morrison & Robinson, 1997;
Rousseau & Shperling, 2003). Consequently, the problems that evolve
from the separation of ownership and control can be traced to gaps in
what employers expect and what employees perceive they should
contribute. Rather than deliberately violating the terms of their
employment agreements, organization behavior scholars propose executives
and workers will honor their employment agreements, as they understand
them. Accordingly, enhancing communication and mutual understanding
among shareholders, managers, and employees may resolve the problem of
the separation of ownership and control of corporate assets. Therefore,
mutual benefits may be expected as mutual understanding is achieved
among these stakeholders (Pierce, Rubenfeld, & Morgan, 1991; Rosen,
Klein, & Young, 1986; Rousseau, 1995). What is recognized in the
behavioral view is that individuals at the outset may seek jobs with
organizations for an economic reason. Although economic exchange may
initially characterize the relationship between the employee and the
enterprise, behaviors of employees within the enterprise are motivated
by more than an economic agenda. Hence, a person's decision to
offer contributions to the firm cannot be explained by economics alone.
Whereas the economic perspective emphasizes the formal contract and
the expectation that agents will seek selfish interests beyond the
provisions of the formal contract, organization behavior theorists
clearly emphasize the informal contract. More specifically, their
argument is that the alignment of shareholders' interests with
those of the firm's executives and workers may require a shared
understanding of the informal psychological agreement that prevails in
the employment relationship (McLean Parks & Schmedemann, 1994;
Morrison & Robinson, 1997; Rousseau & Shperling, 2003). The
psychological agreement or contract consists of employees'
perceptions of the unwritten reciprocal promises and obligations between
themselves and their employer (Robinson, 1996; Turnley & Feldman,
1999). In this vein, organization members' contributions and
rewards exchanged in a psychological contract have pecuniary and
non-pecuniary currency components. Specifically, managers or employees
provide effort on the job not only in exchange for economic and
socioemotional currencies (Macneil, 1985; Rousseau, & McLean Parks,
1993), but also for the ideological currency (Blau, 1964; Thompson &
Bunderson, 2003).
Contrary to the economic perspective, which recognizes both the
financial and nonfinancial components of agents' exchanges to be
selfishly driven, the psychological perspective only recognizes the
financial component of exchanges as self-interested in nature. The
financial component is considered to be self-interested because each
organizational member is expected to contribute efforts in exchange for
receiving monetary or tangible rewards. The socioemotional component,
however, is considered to be group-interested and based on reciprocity
norms. Employees are expected to contribute loyalty and organizational
citizenship to the enterprise in exchange for security, human capital
development, and membership in a desirable work group. The ideological
component is understood as collective- or community-interested (i.e.,
finding a purpose in work that is meant to address a worthwhile cause).
The perceived obligations within the psychological contract are more
crucial to work-related behavior than the obligations specified in the
formal contract in the view of organization behavior scholars (Rousseau
& Tijoriwala, 1998; Thompson & Bunderson, 2003).
We suggest that the informal psychological contract, as a unit of
analysis, provides a more useful theoretical framework for our
understanding of the employment relationship than the formal contract
and the stipulations emphasized by economists. The premise of related
research has been that contributions and rewards exchanged in a
psychological contract may be perceived as economic, socioemotional
(Macneil, 1985; McLean Parks & Schmedemann, 1994), or ideological
currencies (Blau, 1964; Thompson & Bunderson, 2003). Hence, the
ramification is that different currencies may be associated with various
responses to the perception that the contract has been upheld or
breached (Robinson & Morrison, 2000; Rousseau & McLean Parks,
1993). In effect, although the psychological contract may possibly
contain a combination of these distinct currencies, the currencies have
often been considered independently of one another. In this work, we
further elaborate on the independence of each currency by considering
the possibility that for some individuals one currency may substitute
for the others. Moreover, it has been argued that the potential
interdependencies among these currencies have remained under-explored,
and therefore, not well understood (Thompson & Bunderson, 2003).
Consequently, we also strive to shed more light on this issue as we
attempt to address some of the possible interdependencies among the
currencies of the psychological contract.
The remainder of the paper captures our contributions that are
organized as follows. First, by resorting to concepts of identity
orientations and forms of social exchange, we will discuss the notion
that some corporate members may particularly value one currency of the
psychological contract over the others. For these members, our
contention is that satisfied promises on the currency they value may
compensate for limitations of the other currencies. Hence, we suggest a
higher level of the currency they value may substitute for a lower level
of the other currencies associated with the job. The substitution
possibility is indicative of the potential independence of each
currency. Second, we elaborate on breaches of the psychological contract
that can occur when employees believe the currency they especially value
is not supported by the employer. In Table 1 simple linkages are
presented that will be discussed subsequently.
Our discussion is also broadened to encompass the possibility that
other corporate members may adopt multiple identity orientations or
prefer several forms of social exchange, thereby valuing more than one
currency of the psychological contract. In this case, the currencies may
be interdependent as they coexist in the psychological contract. Valuing
several currencies, the organization could be perceived by employees as
offering a means for receiving financial rewards, an environment for
relational satisfaction, and a setting within which efforts could be
made toward a worthy ideal. For these individuals the psychological
contract may also be breached, as will be discussed.
SUBSTITUTION OF CURRENCIES RENDERED BY IDENTITIES AND EXCHANGES
Depending on the individual, our contention is that any one
currency of the psychological contract may serve as a substitute for the
others. Hence, satisfied promises on one currency of the psychological
contract might compensate for shortcomings in the other currencies. We
suggest substitution among currencies may be subject to identity
orientations of individuals and their desired forms of social exchange
in the organization. A number of scholars have argued that identity
orientations assist employees in defining themselves relative to others
(Alpert, Ashforth, & Dutton, 2000; Brewer & Gardner, 1996) and
in preferring a particular form of social exchange (Flynn, 2005).
Consequently, the implication is that employees tend to have specific
identity orientations, and, therefore, may adopt distinct forms of
social exchange. Emphasis should be made that identity orientation
theory elaborates on how the need to maintain positive
self-representation affects our perceptions of interactions with others
(Hogg & Terry, 2000). Social exchange theory describes how we educe
valued resources via interactions with others (Homans, 1958). To further
clarify, we discuss below substitution of currencies rendered by
identity orientations of people and their preferences for various forms
of social exchange. It has been contended that organization members
differently relate to one another (i.e., prefer different exchange
forms--negotiated, reciprocal, or generalized), depending on their
identity orientations that may be personal, relational, or collective
(Brewer & Gardner, 1996; Flynn, 2005).
Personal orientation eliciting negotiated exchange and the
dominance of the economic currency
Executives and workers who have a personal identity orientation
perceive themselves as unique individuals and derive their gratification
from the evaluation of their own characteristics, such as superior
abilities relative to others. Possessing "a personal identity
orientation suggests the focal individual is motivated to act solely on
behalf of his or her own interests rather than on behalf of others'
interests" (Flynn, 2005: 739). Corporate members with personal
orientations not only may prefer competition over cooperation, but might
also find competition at work motivating. They may believe that
self-improvement is more likely if they attempt to outperform one
another. Consistent with this premise, Fama and Jensen (1983) have
proposed that some individuals in seeking employment choose among firms
partly on the basis of the potential for further development of
professional skills in response to intra-firm competition. These
organization members may likewise assume that job performance improves
with more intense rivalry among peers.
Because people with personal orientations value self-serving
exchanges, their concern is with gaining tangible benefits for
themselves as they interact with others. If these individuals need to
cooperate with colleagues on the job, their preferred mode is explicit
negotiated social exchanges (e.g., "I assist you in your job if you
assist me with mine"). In negotiated exchanges, individuals
selfishly concentrate on the concrete value of the exchange, rather than
relational benefits, positive affects, or ideological contentments. The
promotion of selfish interests not only may encompass gaining
convenience or utility via negotiated exchanges, but also potentially
gaining further economically on the job (Guth & Tagiuri, 1965;
Wright, Kroll, Lado, & Elenkov, 2005). Consequently, such
individuals may value their employment primarily for obtaining higher
economic currency. Put in other words, since these employees are not
expected to be enticed by socioemotional or ideological currencies
associated with the organization, they may instead be anticipated to be
motivated by financial rewards or the economic currency.
Moreover, our contention is that for organization members with a
personal orientation the economic currency may extend beyond gaining
material well-being into augmented dimensions of the psychological
domain. Indeed, if human beings are more satisfied with self-improvement
or betterment (Whitehead, 1929), then receiving higher economic currency
may promote further satisfaction by implicitly serving as a proxy for
having been judged more productive or promotable relative to peers in
the enterprise (Rosenbaum, 1984; Wright, et al., 2005). In effect,
receiving greater economic currency may be interpreted by an individual
with a personal orientation as having accomplished more and attained
bolstered status or power in employment. Hence, ego satisfactions
associated with financial rewards may be additional sources of
motivation.
Receiving higher economic rewards may also be indicative of how
organization members are evaluated in relation to their external
counterparts in the relevant labor market. We recognize that financial
rewards offered to the personnel of one firm, relative to competing
enterprises, may lead, match, or lag the market (Milkovich & Newman,
2002). A firm that leads the market in the economic currency, or offers
higher than average financial compensation of the relevant labor market,
may be signaling to its members that they are more valued than their
external counterparts. Consequently, employees who receive higher pay
may interpret such generous rewards as organizational expressions of
further respect and worth for them, responding with superior levels of
performance. Presumably, individuals with personal orientations expect
that, by increasing their levels of performance, they are more likely to
continue to receive greater future economic currency relative to their
counterparts.
As noted, employees with personal orientations, preferring
negotiated social exchanges, are less concerned with relational
benefits, positive affects, or ideological contentments. Thus, for these
employees, a higher level of economic currency may substitute for a
lower level of socioemotional or ideological currencies associated with
the job. The reason is, with respect to their employment, these
individuals tend to derive satisfaction in promoting their own
self-interests rather than group interests or collective interests. We
do recognize, however, that human aspirations are not fulfilled by
economic rewards alone. But non-economic aspirations need not be
fulfilled within the enterprise as their fulfillment may take place
outside of employment. Notwithstanding the latter consideration that is
external to employment, we offer the following proposition.
Proposition 1: The economic currency will substitute for
socioemotional or ideological currencies for organization members who
have a personal identity orientation, preferring negotiated exchanges.
Relational orientation eliciting reciprocal exchange and the
dominance of the socioemotional currency
Organization members with a relational identity orientation
alternatively prefer implicit reciprocal social exchanges because they
derive their satisfaction from return-in-kind exchanges. Implicit
reciprocity in a relational setting normally consists of repayment of a
good deed by the recipient to the provider. The dyadic exchange
relations offer the means for individuals to enhance interactions within
or across work groups in the absence of formal hierarchical authority.
Furthermore, dyadic exchanges can spill over and encompass networks of
reciprocities within or across groups. While concerned with their own
needs, those with a relational orientation are likewise concerned with
the needs of others (Brewer & Gardner, 1996; Markus & Kitayama,
1991). Therefore, such persons ordinarily are motivated to act on behalf
of mutual interests.
Managers and workers with a relational orientation tend to develop
affective bonds (or emotional attachments) in their place of employment.
These bonds are formed as individuals seek mutual acceptance and
camaraderie in the workplace (Alpert, et al., 2000). Affective bonding
often enhances social harmony and cohesiveness (Blau, 1964; Deutsch,
1985). Moreover, organization members with relational orientations are
prone to prefer cooperation over competition at work. Cooperation among
these individuals could prevail beyond what is expected of their task
assignments. Because for employees with relational orientations
cooperation ordinarily is directed at increasing both self-interests and
the interests of others (Brewer & Gardner, 1996), they may
experience symbiotic interdependence (Barnett & Miner, 1992).
Having relational identity orientations and desiring reciprocal
exchanges, such individuals may be predisposed to particularly value the
socioemotional currency of the psychological contract. Rousseau and
Shperling have proposed "workers with relational agreements demand
less pay than their nonrelational counterparts, effectively giving that
wealth premium to the firm and its investors" (2003: 563). The
implication of this proposal is that organization members who have a
dominant relational orientation may have a higher interest in the
socioemotional currency, but a lower concern for the economic currency.
Likewise, the employees who have a dominant relational orientation may
have a lesser interest in striving for a cause. In this instance, the
implication is that individuals with a higher interest in the
socioemotional currency may have a lower concern for the ideological
currency. Therefore, for individuals with relational orientations,
preferring reciprocal social exchanges, a higher level of the
socioemotional currency may substitute for a lower level of economic or
ideological currencies associated with their employment.
Proposition 2: The socioemotional currency will substitute for
economic or ideological currencies for organization members who have a
relational identity orientation, preferring reciprocal exchanges.
Collective orientation eliciting generalized exchange and the
dominance of the ideological currency
Executives and workers with collective identity orientations also
desire implicit reciprocal exchanges but in a generalized manner. That
is, reciprocity may consist of repayment of a good deed, but not
axiomatically by the recipient to the provider (Yamagishi & Cook,
1993). Indeed, "reciprocation is indirect so that Paul may receive
a benefit from Heather but may reciprocate by giving to Eric, rather
than to Heather. Eventually, Heather can expect reciprocation from
someone other than Paul" (Flynn, 2005: 740). Evidently, implicit
reciprocity in a collective setting takes place among three or more
people. Organization members with collective orientations have a general
interest in others' welfare (Bearman, 1997; Sahlins, 1972). They
frequently prefer cooperation over competition at work and are
predisposed to sacrifice their own interests for the welfare of the
collective. These individuals subscribe to the notion of giving, without
direct reciprocation, although they may expect indirect reciprocation in
the future.
For individuals with a collective identity orientation, however,
sacrificing their own interests for the benefit of the collective may
occur even without anticipation of direct or even indirect
reciprocation. These individuals might thrive by enhancing their
usefulness to the collectivity (Spranger, 1928). Hence, they may be
content with the role of primarily benefiting others in the organization
or the broader community. Emphasis should be made that a collective
identity orientation may correspond to various levels of abstraction,
including the group, department, organization, profession, industry,
nation, or the world (Flynn, 2005). Ordinarily, organization members
with collective identity orientations tend to view their contributions
to colleagues and the community as a reason for their employment
(Conger, 1994; Thompson & Bunderson, 2003). Rather than
concentrating on economic or socioemotional rewards, the focal employees
may cherish ideological rewards. For these employees, pursuing a cause
and advancing ideals are intrinsically rewarding (Blau, 1964; Conger,
1994). The ideological currency, therefore, may serve as a stronger
inducement to elicit these employees' contributions than the other
currencies. "When this is the case, employee perceptions about the
organization's obligations are not grounded solely in personal
entitlements but also in the promotion of a cause they highly
value" (Thompson & Bunderson, 2003: 571). Organization members
with collective identity orientations, preferring generalized exchanges,
may have a greater value for the ideological currency relative to the
economic or socioemotional currencies. Consequently, for such
organization members, the former currency may substitute for the latter
currencies.
Proposition 3: The ideological currency will substitute for
economic or socioemotional currencies for organization members who have
a collective identity orientation, preferring generalized exchanges.
SUBSTITUTION OF CURRENCIES RENDERED BY EXCHANGES AND IDENTITIES
Although identity orientations are rather stable and enduring, they
are not permanently fixed. In the prior discussion, our understanding
has been that identity orientations determine preferences for differing
forms of social exchange. In this section, we alternatively discuss the
premise that the form of social exchange may determine the adoption of
an identity orientation. In effect, we elaborate on the notion that
individuals may conceivably define themselves differently vis-a-vis
others as circumstances vary (Flynn, 2005; Gardner, Gabriel, &
Hochschild, 2002). Hence, people might not hold immutable identities,
but rather their identity orientations could change with the situation.
As discussed next, the reciprocity of identity orientation and exchange
also has ramifications for the substitution of currencies of the
psychological contract.
Negotiated exchange eliciting personal orientation and the
enhancement of the economic currency
Employees of the same organization may begin to have social
exchange without having a history of interaction. These members of the
organization are unlikely to immediately adopt a relational or
collective identity orientation (Flynn, 2005), although they ordinarily
may be predisposed to the adoption of either of such identity
orientations. Because they are unfamiliar with one another or because
they may have uncommon social categories other than common employment
(Chatman, Polzer, Barsade, & Neale, 1998), they may initially adopt
negotiated exchanges, and correspondingly, personal identity
orientations. Unfamiliarity refers to not knowing the others involved in
the interaction. Uncommon social category refers to the dearth of
knowledge regarding potential commonality of interests, and hence, lack
of perception of mutualism.
Evidently, what initially triggers the adoption of negotiated
exchanges and personal identity orientation is the presence of
unfamiliarity or the status of uncommonality of social categories. In
such cases, there may be limited motivation to be responsive to
others' needs; therefore, individuals may focus on their own needs.
Thus, the presence of unfamiliarity or the status of uncommon social
category, triggering negotiated exchanges and personal identity
orientations, promotes interactions on behalf of one's own
interests rather than others' interests. Given these
considerations, select members of the organization might value the
concrete dimension of the interaction, instead of valuing social
utilities, positive affects, or ideological benefits. Presumably, rather
than cooperation, competition could prevail in these circumstances. If
necessary, however, employees may cooperate with each other but probably
by way of negotiated exchanges.
Given our discussion, we anticipate the presence of unfamiliarity
or the status of uncommonality of social categories, triggering
negotiated exchanges and personal orientations, might enhance the value
of the economic currency, but not the value of socioemotional or
ideological currencies for employees.
Proposition 4: The presence of unfamiliarity or the status of
uncommonality of social categories, triggering negotiated exchanges and
personal orientations, will render the substitution of the economic
currency for socioemotional or ideological currencies for organization
members.
Reciprocal exchange eliciting relational orientation and the
enhancement of the socioemotional currency
Employees may change their identity orientation from personal to
relational as circumstances change. Note that settings of unfamiliarity
or uncommonality of social categories may change into circumstances of
familiarity or commonality of social categories with the initiation of
ongoing interactions. Moreover, a greater frequency of social exchanges
may culminate in enhancements of familiarity or recognition of
commonality of social categories. On the one hand, in response to
ongoing interactions, organization members may broaden their conception
of worth as individuals to worth as members of relationships (Brewer
& Gardner, 1996; Markus & Kitayama, 1991). Hence, they might
begin to perceive themselves less as unique individuals and more as
persons fulfilling roles in valuable reciprocal exchange relationships
(Flynn, 2005). In this case, adoptions of reciprocal exchanges and
relational identity orientations are due to increased familiarity and
the potential development of extending positive affects. On the other
hand, employees may adopt reciprocal exchanges and relational identity
orientations with the development of common identity and congruencies of
interests. In effect, repeated social exchanges may work to further
align the interests of those involved (Lawler & Yoon, 1993; Sheriff,
Harvey, White, Hood, & Sheriff, 1954), promoting a perception of
mutualism.
Ordinarily, instead of competition, cooperation may prevail in
these settings. That is because individuals tend to cooperate where they
find relationships composed of familiarity and positive affects (Markus
& Kitayama, 1991) or relationships with congruencies of interests
(Lawler & Yoon, 1993). Our elaboration indicates that, with the
initiation of ongoing interactions, circumstances may change to those of
familiarity or commonality of social categories, triggering reciprocal
exchanges and relational orientations. Hence, the value of the
socioemotional currency may rise, but not necessarily the value of the
economic or ideological currencies.
Proposition 5: Contexts of familiarity or commonality of social
categories, triggering reciprocal exchanges and relational orientations,
will render the substitution of the socioemotional currency for economic
or ideological currencies for organization members.
Generalized exchange eliciting collective orientation and the
enhancement of the ideological currency
As circumstances change with the initiation of ongoing
relationships, organization members alternatively may adopt generalized
exchanges, and correspondingly, collective identity orientations. Given
ongoing relationships, employees may develop common identities and
alignments of interests, striving toward the achievement of something
that benefits a broader collectivity than the intra-organization group
or even the enterprise. In this case, individuals might broaden their
perception of worth as members of intra-organizational relationships to
worth as corporate contributors to an ideology or something truly
worthwhile (e.g., as corporate members of a biotechnology firm whose
mission is: "To improve the health of the world's
citizens").
The desire to be a corporate contributor to an ideology is not only
a theoretical notion. "Practitioners and the practitioner
literature often explicitly invoke ideology in describing a fulfilling
employment exchange" (Thompson & Bunderson, 2003: 572). The
formation of a commonality of a cause should limit intra-firm
competition, but further promote intra-organizational cooperation. Put
in other words, "high ideals are the basis for the persistence of
cooperation" (Barnard, 1938: 282). Circumstances that facilitate
the formation of a commitment to an ideal bring forth altruistic roles.
That is, individuals tend to value the role of benefiting others within
the firm or in the broader community without necessarily an anticipation
of reciprocation. The reason is that advancing a cause or an ideal is
intrinsically rewarding.
Proposition 6: Contexts facilitating the development of common
identities and alignments of interests, triggering generalized exchanges
and collective identity orientations, will render the substitution of
the ideological currency for economic or socioemotional currencies for
organization members.
BREACH OF THE PSYCHOLOGICAL CONTRACT
Our discussion on the substitution of the currencies of the
psychological contract revolved around the notion that individuals with
distinct identity orientations, or in particular social exchange
contexts, may value one currency over the other currencies. In this
section of the paper, we elaborate on the possible breaches of the
psychological contract that can occur when employees believe that the
currency they especially value is not supported by the organization.
Breach due to lack of support for the economic currency
Evidently, employees who have a personal identity orientation, or
in negotiated social exchange contexts, may value the economic currency.
Consequently, these employees are likely to consider that the
psychological contract is upheld, if they perceive their pecuniary
rewards as satisfactory, compensating for possible shortcomings or
limitations in the socioemotional or ideological aspects of the
contract. In contrast, the psychological contract could be breached if
they view their financial rewards as unsatisfactory. More specifically,
an enterprise that begins to lag the external labor market in pay
policies, or commences to offer lower than average compensation of the
relevant external labor market, may be viewed by the employees with
personal orientations as breaching the psychological contract. These
employees might believe that they are progressively less valued by the
employer than their external counterparts.
Individuals with personal orientations may also consider their
psychological agreement as breached if they begin to be paid less than
their counterparts in the relevant internal labor market. We shall
remember when organization members perceive their inputs relative to
rewards are similar to those of peers, they recognize that equity exists
(Adams, 1965). In contrast, if employees perceive that for the same
level of input their peers are rewarded more, they will believe inequity
exists. Nevertheless, individuals have greatly exaggerated perceptions
of their own inputs relative to others. Put in other words, individual
inputs are subject to self-enhancing perceptual biases that influence
employees to give themselves more credit than is warranted, and others
less than deserved (Cook & Yamagishi, 1983; Cowherd & Levine,
1992). With exaggerated self-assessments and discounted assessments of
others, any higher reward given to peers might be related to inequity
and possible breach of the psychological contract.
It has been argued that a breach of the psychological contract may
lead to feelings of violation, promoting negative attitudes, reductions
in employee contributions, or greater turnover (Robinson & Morrison,
2000; Rousseau & McLean Parks, 1993; Turnley & Feldman, 2000).
We agree, but speculate that feelings of violation may promote greater
turnover of individuals with personal orientations, preferring
negotiated exchanges, if their levels of financial rewards are less than
the reward levels of the relevant external labor market. In contrast,
our conjecture is that for these individuals feelings of violation may
promote negative attitudes or reduction in contributions, rather than
turnover, if their compensation remains more than the relevant external
labor market, but lags the relevant internal labor market.
Proposition [7.sub.a]: For individuals with a personal orientation,
preferring negotiated exchanges, the psychological contract will be
breached if their compensation begins to lag the relevant external labor
market. This will lead to feelings of violation, promoting higher
turnover rates.
Proposition [7.sub.b]: For individuals with a personal orientation,
preferring negotiated exchanges, the psychological contract will be
breached if their compensation begins to lag the relevant internal labor
market, even if their compensation remains more than the relevant
external labor market. This will lead to feelings of violation,
promoting negative attitudes or reduced employee contributions.
Breach due to lack of support for the socioemotional currency
Our anticipation is that organization members who have relational
identity orientations, or in reciprocal social exchange contexts, tend
to value the socioemotional currency. Hence, these individuals are
likely to perceive that the psychological contract is upheld, if their
socioemotional needs are satisfied, compensating for possible
shortcomings in the economic or ideological currency components of the
contract. The psychological agreement could be breached if they
alternatively view that their socioemotional needs are not supported.
Presumably, compared to transactional contract breach (involving the
economic currency), relational contract breach (encompassing the
socioemotional currency) may be more sensitive to subjective judgments
(McLean Parks & Kidder, 1994; Thompson & Bunderson, 2003).
A number of scholars have concluded that psychological contracts
change from relational to transactional, after the agreement is breached
in response to lack of support in the socioemotional domain (Herriott
& Pemberton, 1996; Rousseau & McLean Parks, 1993). This
conclusion is intuitively appealing to us. Moreover, we suggest a
changed psychological contract that begins to emphasize a transaction
aspect (provision of employee effort in exchange for pecuniary rewards),
rather than a return-in-kind aspect of the agreement, is unlikely to
remain motivational for individuals with relational identity
orientations, preferring reciprocal exchanges. Instead, such individuals
may become dissatisfied with their employment in response to the changed
contract. Therefore, we anticipate for these corporate members, the
psychological contract may be breached, as their socioemotional needs
are no longer supported. This may lead to feelings of violation,
promoting negative attitudes, reduced contributions, and higher
turnover.
Proposition 8: For individuals with a relational orientation,
preferring reciprocal exchanges, the psychological contract will be
breached in response to lack of support for the socioemotional domain.
With the breach, the agreement changes from relational (an emphasis on
socioemotional currency) to transactional (an emphasis on economic
currency). This will lead to feelings of violation, promoting negative
attitudes, reduced contributions, and higher turnover.
Breach due to lack of support for the ideological currency
We have discussed the proposition that corporate members who have a
collective identity orientation, or in generalized social exchange
contexts, may value the ideological currency. Consequently, they could
consider the psychological contract as upheld if their pursuit of a
cause is in congruence with the activities of the enterprise. Moreover,
even if the enterprise pursues the relevant ideological goals, but with
few realized victories, these corporate members might still be satisfied
with the psychological agreement (Thompson & Bunderson, 2003). The
reason is that pursuing ideals is itself intrinsically rewarding. The
satisfaction of such corporate members with the ideological currency may
compensate for possible limitations in the economic or socioemotional
currencies. This may explain why some individuals continue to be loyal
to the enterprise despite shortcomings in the economic and
socioemotional currencies of the psychological agreement.
In contrast, for employees who value the ideological currency, the
employment agreement could be breached if the firm shifts its actions
away from ideological pursuits. The breach of the psychological contract
is more likely if the redirection of activities is not forced upon the
enterprise by macroenvironmental trends (political-legal, economic,
social, technological) or industry forces (customers, suppliers, rivals,
substitute products, threat of new entrants). For instance, if
redirection of energies away from the pursuit of ideals is not forced
upon the organization by economic necessities (Morrison & Robinson,
1997) or customer demands (Thompson & Bunderson, 2003), a breach of
the psychological employment agreement becomes more probable.
Axiomatically, the potential for breach is not due to personal
mistreatments of employees, but rather due to abandonments of
ideological obligations. It will be recalled that breaches of the
psychological contract, because of lack of support for the economic or
socioemotional currencies, led to feelings of violation, promoting
negative attitudes, reduced contributions, or high turnover rates. These
are reactive responses. A breach of the psychological agreement due to
lack of support for the ideological currency, however, is anticipated to
lead to feelings of violation, promoting more proactive responses
(Thompson & Bunderson, 2003). Indeed, such responses may be in the
form of attempts to rectify the breach via organizational dissent.
Proposition 9: For individuals with a collective orientation,
preferring generalized exchanges, the psychological contract will be
breached if the enterprise redirects its activities away from
ideological pursuits. This will lead to feelings of violation, promoting
attempts to rectify the breach via organizational dissent.
MULTIPLE IDENTITIES, EXCHANGES, AND CURRENCIES
Up to this point we have anticipated for individuals with personal
orientations, or in contexts of negotiated exchanges, that values of
socioemotional or ideological currencies may be of lesser concern,
yielding prominence to the value of the economic currency. Thus,
fulfilled obligations on the economic component of the psychological
contract may compensate for possible unfulfilled obligations on the
socioemotional or ideological currency components. In contrast, we have
anticipated that the socioemotional currency may be important for people
with relational orientations or in circumstances of reciprocal
exchanges. In this case, fulfilled obligations on the socioemotional
currency might compensate for unfulfilled obligations on the economic
and ideological currency components. Alternatively, we have anticipated
the ideological currency may be crucial for organization members with
collective orientations or in settings of generalized exchanges. Here,
fulfilled obligations on the ideological currency may compensate for
unfulfilled obligations on economic and socioemotional currency
components. Our anticipations are consistent with the possibility that
some individuals might adopt one identity orientation and prefer one
form of social exchange. For these individuals a currency of the
psychological contract ordinarily assumes high value. In this setting,
the psychological contract may be breached if the currency valued by the
individual is not acted upon or supported by the organization. Similar
to Thompson, we realize that "organizations only act as the result
of action taken by their members" (1967: ix).
The theme of our paper is that identity orientations and forms of
social exchange can be conceived narrowly or more broadly with
corresponding currency valuations. Some organization members may
narrowly focus on themselves, adopting personal identity orientations,
preferring negotiated exchanges, and valuing the economic currency.
Here, the psychological contract can be characterized as transactional.
Others may more broadly focus on themselves as well as their peers. They
may adopt relational identity orientations, prefer reciprocal exchanges,
and value the socioemotional currency. In this case, the psychological
contract can be characterized as relational. Yet other employees may
focus still more broadly on an aggregation of people involving a cause.
Such employees may adopt collective identity orientations, prefer
generalized exchanges, and value the ideological currency. In this
instance, the psychological agreement is principled in nature.
Expectably, a narrow focus on the individual himself or herself may be
associated with the economic currency, whereas broader foci may be
progressively associated with socioemotional or ideological currencies.
The prior elaborations, however, do not rule out the possibility
that other organization members may adopt more than one identity
orientation or prefer several forms of social exchange. Perhaps these
employees in addition to being associated with the firm economically and
with colleagues relationally are also inclined to associate themselves
by way of the enterprise with the broader collectivity ideologically
(Guth & Tagiuri, 1965). This implies that more than one currency of
the psychological contract may be valued by them. For such employees the
enterprise may provide a means for deriving financial benefits, a
setting for relational fulfillment, or a context in which contributions
can be made to a worthy cause. Moreover, as stated subsequently, there
may be interdependencies among the currencies.
Considering various possibilities that encompass organization
members adopting multiple identity orientations, preferring more than
one form of social exchange, and valuing several currencies of the
psychological contract that may be interdependent is beyond the scope of
our work. We only focus on the possibility of an interdependency that
encompasses the economic currency activating the socioemotional
currency, and the activated socioemotional currency triggering the
ideological currency. Given these possibilities, the psychological
contract also may be subject to breach, as discussed in a forthcoming
section. Our approach is exploratory in nature as we attempt to address
the issues of plurality and interdependency.
The psychological contract and interdependencies of currencies
We mentioned that defining the self as a unique being reflects a
personal identity orientation and a self-interested predisposition
(i.e., a predisposition of seeking self-interest in isolation of
others' interests). This identity orientation tends to be
especially compatible with receiving the economic currency based on
individual effort. Here, the financial rewards of employees would be
independent of one another. The economic currency, however, instead
could involve receiving group commissions or group bonuses, based on
group effort (Deutsch, 1949). In this case, corporate members'
self-interests and group-interests become congruent. Congruencies of
interests due to group rewards may promote ongoing interactions and a
spirit of cooperation (Lawler & Yoon, 1993; Sheriff, et al., 1954).
Ongoing interactions and a spirit of cooperation may correspondingly be
associated with recognition of commonality of social categories and
enhancements of familiarity (Flynn, 2005). Our discussion indicates that
the economic currency could activate the socioemotional currency where
pecuniary rewards consist of group financial rewards. In effect, group
compensation might serve as an impetus for employees to broaden their
conception of self-interests to group interests.
Additionally, in some firms the economic currency may encompass
ownership stakes (e.g., grants of options, restricted stock, matching of
company stock in retirement plans). It has been proposed that grants of
ownership stakes can extend beyond employees gaining economically into
augmented dimensions of the psychological sphere (Pierce, et al., 1991;
Rousseau & Shperling, 2003). The reason is that ownership not only
denotes possession of wealth but also the right to gain information and
influence decisions about what is owned. The rights of gaining access to
information and participation in decision-making may encourage further
interactions among employees. Interactions among employees because of
ownership stakes may also culminate in enhancements of familiarity and
recognition of commonality of social categories (Brewer & Gardner,
1996; Flynn, 2005). Hence, what might be stated is that "ownership
operates from both a formal and a psychological experience
platform" (Pierce, et al., 1991: 126). Consequently, the economic
currency in the form of ownership stakes could activate the
socioemotional currency.
Viewed from another perspective, what may contribute to the
activation of the socioemotional currency are the multiple roles that
employees play in some enterprises due to holding ownership stakes.
Playing multiple roles blurs the boundaries among shareholders,
managers, and workers (Rousseau & Shperling, 2003). Approximately
40% of members of publicly traded corporations are holders of equity
stakes in their employer (Rosen, Case, & Staubus, 2005).
Accordingly, these organization members not only play the role of an
employee, but also a shareholder. Furthermore, decentralized work
practices within many of such enterprises have resulted in
self-management. Because members of these organizations can self-manage,
and since both executives and workers hold equity stakes, these
individuals frequently assume multiple roles, potentially promoting
recognition of commonality of social categories. In addition to group
bonuses or group commissions, therefore, the economic currency, in the
form of ownership stakes, may likewise activate the socioemotional
currency.
Enhancements of familiarity or recognition of commonality of social
categories, associated with intra-firm interactions and the activated
socioemotional currency, may further broaden organization members'
conceptions of worth as group members to worth as contributors to
something truly worthwhile. Our statement is compatible with the
proposal that some firms as organized groups of interacting people, by
design or informally, socially also evolve to stand for certain moral
values or causes (Barnard, 1938; Blau, 1964; Selznick, 1957).
Apparently, within the business community, many successful enterprises
tend to explicitly and by design subscribe to cause-driven missions in
order to capture the moral imagination of their members (Collins &
Porras, 1996; Thompson & Bunderson, 2003). In this setting,
corporate members may enjoy relational as well as collective pursuits in
their employment.
Moreover, we suggest that it is possible for the socioemotional
currency to informally trigger the ideological currency because the
viability of the former may be enhanced with the presence of the latter.
We shall remember that identity orientation theory addresses how the
need to maintain positive self-representation affects perceptions of
interacting people. It is easier to positively convey one's own
self-image if interactions with others are perceived to be in congruence
with norms of reciprocity as well as with moral values. Also, conflicts
between two individuals or among several people are less likely in the
presence of reciprocity and moral values. Presumably, the integrity of
interactions of socioemotionally related employees could be safeguarded
with continued reciprocity and the prevalence of moral values. Indeed,
actions of interacting employees that contradict moral values may pose a
threat to interacting associates' self-concepts, reducing their
desire to participate, thereby devaluing the socioemotional currency.
Alternatively, actions that demonstrate moral values improve the
interacting employees' mutually conveyed self-representations,
enhancing the value of the socioemotional currency.
Additionally, it may be said that the good will and feelings of
socioemotionally related employees represent the perceived reciprocal
acts of these persons and the imputed intentions behind the acts. The
augmentation of broader cause-related moral intentions that are imputed
to the related acts of interacting employees may support the value of
the socioemotional currency because the presence of moral values could
be perceived as assurance that the quality of implicit reciprocation in
the present and in the future will be maintained. This contention is
based on the argument that people evaluate facts as well as render
intentions to the others involved in any interaction (LaFave, 2000;
O'Toole, 1993). Furthermore, the relevant facts of the interaction
and the imputed intentions between two or among several persons are
often more positively perceived if they are presumed congruent with
moral or ideological concerns (Goffman, 1997).
Proposition 10: The economic currency will activate the
socioemotional currency, and the activated socioemotional currency will
trigger the ideological currency for organization members subject to
group rewards or corporate ownership stakes. These organization members
will have multiple identity orientations, preferring several forms of
social exchange, and valuing more than one currency of the psychological
contract.
Breach of the psychological contract and interdependencies of
currencies
We have suggested that the economic currency in forms of group
financial rewards and grants of ownership stakes might activate the
socioemotional currency. Moreover, our contention has been that the
activated socioemotional currency could trigger the ideological
currency. The psychological contract may be considered as upheld if
these currencies are consistently supported by the enterprise. In
contrast, the psychological contract may be breached if the firm begins
to reduce its support of the currencies. Our expectation, however, is
that, if organization members value more than one currency of the
psychological contract, the ideological component may play a
particularly crucial role with respect to possible breach of the
employment agreement.
Following the tradition of common law, we suggest for breach of the
psychological agreement to occur, it is necessary for a bad act and a
bad mind to be present. A bad act may constitute a conduct that
represents an infraction of an obligation. However, a bad act may not
immediately lead to a breach, unless a bad mind is also presumed
(Khanna, 1999; LaFave, 2000). The presumption that a breach may require
a bad act and a bad mind is likewise in conformance with
Aristotle's (1941) view that a bad act and a bad desire must
coexist in order to constitute a breach. In contrast, a good act and a
good mind are necessary to constitute virtue. We recognize that
organizations are social or legal constructions (Jensen & Meckling,
1976; Ouchi, 1981; Weick & Roberts, 1993) and have no minds per se.
They are, as fiction, conceived by people to better understand their
arenas. But organizations do create volitions that can be construed as
good or bad acts and intentions (Khanna, 1999; Werhane, 1985). Perhaps
for a breach to occur, bad acts may need to be accompanied by bad
intentions.
We shall remember enterprises that are prominently cause-driven may
capture the moral imagination of their members (Collins & Porras,
1996; Thompson & Bunderson, 2003), amalgamating significant moral
capital. Moral capital may provide some protection for possible breach
of the psychological contract due to commencements of lack of
significant support for the currencies. That is, for a period of time an
enterprise with moral capital may be forgiven by its members for less
than fully supporting the currencies of the psychological agreement. In
this case it may be reasonable to assume, where the currencies are not
fully supported, the employees may invoke the cognitive template that
the lack of support is not due to bad intentions for firms with moral
capital. In effect, moral capital might guard against a breach, or at
least, postpone a breach of the psychological contract. In contrast, the
psychological agreement may be immediately breached in response to bad
corporate acts involving the currencies, if a bad corporate mind is
simultaneously perceived by enterprise members.
Proposition 11: The psychological contract will be immediately
breached in response to bad corporate acts (involving the currencies),
if a bad corporate mind is also perceived by employees. In contrast, the
presence of the ideological currency and moral capital will mollify the
effects of bad corporate acts because of a presumption of an absence of
a bad corporate mind, guarding against a breach, or at least, postponing
a breach of the psychological agreement.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
We began this paper with the observation that from different
perspectives the separation of ownership and control is recognized as a
potential major organizational problem. From an economic perspective,
the problem consists of employees promoting their personal interests at
the expense of relevant others and the enterprise. In contrast, from the
perspective of organization behavior scholars, the problem can be traced
to gaps in what employers expect and what employees perceive they should
contribute. The economists have emphasized the formal employment
contract, whereas the behavioral scholars have focused on the informal
psychological agreement. Our contention has been that the informal
psychological contract proposed by behavioral scholars provides a more
useful framework for our understanding of the employment relationship,
or its problems, than the formal contract and the stipulations stressed
by economists. In this final section of the paper, justifications are
provided for our contention.
Agency theory within the economic framework holds that employment
relationships can be studied as an interaction of a principal and an
agent (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). The principal delegates authority
to the agent to perform a function on behalf of the principal. The focus
of analysis is on the individual. What is assumed in the economic
paradigm is that agents or employees seek selfish personal utilities,
but are effort-averse, similar to the anticipation of Theory X
(McGregor, 1960). Hence, employees are considered to be opportunistic
because, if possible, they attempt to maximize their utilities, but
minimize their effort on the job.
The notion that agents shirk is inconsistent with the possibility
that employees could be prone toward productivity because efficient job
performance may lead to increases in the economic currency. Indeed, some
employees may substantially exert themselves on the job in order to
improve their economic status (Guth & Taguiri, 1965). Nor does the
notion of shirking allow for the possibility that human beings are
naturally happier with betterment (Whitehead, 1929). Thus, with improved
productivity at work and the garnering of higher compensation, employees
may perceive they are better off. In this view, if individuals are more
satisfied with self-improvement, then receiving higher economic currency
in response to efficient job performance may also be interpreted by them
as having achieved more professionally (Rosenbaum, 1984; Wright, et al.,
2005). Receiving an increased economic currency for greater effort on
the job is also compatible with the reality that some organization
members may exert themselves because they find their tasks intrinsically
satisfying (McGregor, 1960). The economic perspective does not recognize
these possibilities, but the organization behavior view allows for them.
The focus on the individual is also problematic regarding an
economic analysis of the employment relationship. The reason is that
only some employment relationships lend themselves to an association
between one principal and one agent, in isolation of other employees.
These relationships consist of the agent performing a task for the
principal and receiving pecuniary compensation. The behavioral view
allows for this possibility by recognizing that for some enterprise
members the psychological agreement is transactional. That is, the
employee performs a job for a supervisor and receives the economic
currency. The economic perspective, however, is silent on the relevance
of the socioemotional and ideological currencies that could induce
employee contributions. In contrast, the psychological contract,
proposed by behaviorists, explicitly encompasses the reality that for
some organization members the socioemotional and the ideological
currencies may be especially prominent. Consequently, the employment
contract not only may be transactional (with the focus on the individual
agent or the principal), but also relational and principled in nature
(with foci on a plurality).
Approached from a broader psychological contract perspective, it
may be argued that, although firms purchase the employees' time,
the more relevant factor for job performance may be the extent of effort
expended by the employees. The amount of effort put forth may hinge on
appealing to pecuniary as well as nonpecuniary rewards (Etzioni, 1988;
Thompson & Bunderson, 2003). Moreover, organizational efficiency
achieved through increased employees' efforts is not an end in
itself, but the satisfaction of corporate members' aspirations may
be interdependent with that efficiency (Barnard, 1938; Whitehead, 1929).
In effect, corporate efficiency may be related to betterment of
employees since efficiency may facilitate the achievement of economic,
socioemotional, and ideological goals of firm members.
A significant vulnerability of the economic perspective continues
to be its emphasis on self-interest and the expectation of zero-sum
outcomes. Thus the separation of ownership and control, as an
organizational problem, is not subject to resolution (Jensen &
Meckling, 1976). The promise of the behavioral view is that it allows
for self-interest as well as mutual interests and the possibility of
nonzero-sum outcomes. Therefore, the resolution of the problem of the
separation of ownership and control remains a hopeful possibility. In
this work our attempt has been to further enrich the concept of the
psychological agreement, as research continues on this vital topic.
REFERENCES
Adams, S. J. 1965. Inequity in social exchange. In L. Berkowitz
(Ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 2: 267-299. New York:
Academic Press.
Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. 1972. Production, information
costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62: 777-795.
Alpert, S., Ashforth, B., & Dutton, J. 2000. Organizational
identity and identification: Charting new waters and building new
bridges. Academy of Management Review, 25: 13-18.
Aristotle 1941. Rhetoric. New York: Random House.
Barnard, C. 1938. The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Barnett, W. P., & Miner, A. S. 1992. Standing on the shoulders
of others: Career interdependence in job mobility. Administrative
Science Quarterly, 37: 262-281.
Bearman, P. 1997. Generalized exchange. American Journal of
Sociology, 102: 1383-1415.
Berle, A., & Means, G. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private
Property. New York: Macmillan.
Blau, P. M. 1964. Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York:
Wiley.
Brewer, M.B., & Gardner, W. 1996. Who is this "we"?:
Levels of collective identity and self-representations. Journal of
Personality and Social Psychology, 71: 83-93.
Chatman, J., Polzer, J., Barsade, S., & Neale, M. 1998. Being
different yet feeling similar: The influence of demographic composition
and organizational culture on work processes and outcomes.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 43: 749-780.
Conger, J. A. 1994. Spirit of Work: Discovering the Spirituality of
Leadership. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Collins, J. C., & Porras, J. I. 1996. Building your
company's vision. Harvard Business Review, 74(5): 65-77.
Cook, K. S., & Yamagishi, T. 1983. Social determinants of
equity judgments: The problem of multidimensional input. In Messik, D.,
& Cook, K. (Eds.). Equity theory: Psychological and Sociological
Perspectives. New York: Praeger.
Cowherd, D. & Levine, D. 1992. Product quality and pay equity
between lower-level employees and top management: An investigation of
distributive justice theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37:
302320.
Deutsch, M. 1949. A theory of cooperation and competition. Human
Relations, 2: 129-152.
Deutsch, M. 1985. Distributive Justice. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
Etzioni, A. 1988. The Moral Dimension: Toward a New Economics. New
York: The Free Press.
Fama, E. & Jensen, M.C. 1983. Separation of ownership and
control. Journal ofLaw and Economics, 26: 301-325.
Flynn, F. J. 2005. Identity orientations and forms of social
exchange in organizations. Academy of Management Review, 30: 737-750.
Gardner, W., Gabriel, S., & Hochschild, L. 2002. When you and I
are "we," you are not threatening: The role of self-expansion
in social comparison. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 83:
239-251.
Goffman, E. 1997. Self-preservation. In C. Lemert & A. Branaman
(Eds.), The Goffman Reader. Oxford: Blackwell: 21-26.
Guth, W. D., & Taguiri, R. 1965. Personal values and corporate
strategy. Harvard Business Review, 123-132.
Herriott, P., & Pemberton, C. 1996. Contracting careers. Human
Relations, 49: 759-790.
Hogg, M. A., & Terry, D. 2000. Social identity and
self-categorization processes in organizational contexts. Academy of
Management Review, 25: 121-140.
Homans, G. C. 1958. Social behavior as exchange. American Journal
of Sociology, 63: 597-606.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. 1976. Theory of the firm:
Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of
Financial Economics, 3: 305-360.
Khanna, V.S. 1999. Is the notion of corporate fault a faulty
notion? The case of corporate mens rea. Boston University Law Review,
79: 355-415.
LaFave, W. R. 2000. Criminal Law (3rd ed.), St. Paul: West Group.
Lawler, E., & Yoon, J. 1993. Power and the emergence of
commitment behavior in negotiated exchange. American Sociological
Review, 58: 465-481.
Macneil, I. R. 1985. Relational contract: What we do and do not
know. Wisconsin Law Review, 483-525.
Markus, H., & Kitayama, S. 1991. Culture and the self:
Implications for cognition, emotion, and motivation. Psychological
Review, 98: 224-253.
McGregor, D 1960. The Human Side of the Enterprise. New York :
McGraw-Hill.
McLean Parks, J., & Kidder, D. L. 1994. "Till death do us
part . . ." Changing work relationships in the 1990s. In C. L.
Cooper, & D. M. Rousseau (Eds.), Trends in Organizational Behavior:
111-136. New York: Wiley.
McLean Parks, J., & Schmedemann, D. A. 1994. When promises
become contracts: Implied contracts and handbook provisions on job
security. Human Resource Management, 33: 403-423.
Milkovich, G. T., & Newman, J. M. 2002. Compensation. Chicago:
Irwin.
Morrison, E. W., & Robinson, S. L. 1997. When employees feel
betrayed: A model of how psychological contract violation develops.
Academy of Management Review, 22: 226-256.
Ouchi, W. G. 1981. Theory Z. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
O'Toole, J. 1993. The Executive's Compass. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Pierce, J. L., Rubenfeld, S. A., & Morgan, S. 1991. Employee
Ownership: A conceptual model of process and effects. The Academy of
Management Review, 16: 121-144.
Robinson, S L., & Morrison, E. W. 2000. The development of
psychological contract breach and violation: A longitudinal study.
Journal of Organizational Behavior, 21: 525-546.
Robinson, S.. 1996. Trust and breach of the psychological contract.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 41: 574-599.
Rosen, C. M., Case, J., & Staubus, M. 2005. Every employee an
owner. Harvard Business Review, 83: 122-130.
Rosen, C., Klein, K. J.& Young, K. M. 1986. Employee Ownership
in America. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Rosenbaum, J. 1984. Career Mobility in Corporate Hierarchy. New
York: Academia Press.
Rousseau, D. M., & McLean Parks, J. 1993. The contracts of
individuals and organizations. Research in Organizational Behavior, 15:
1-47.
Rousseau, D.M. 1995. Psychological Contracts in Organizations:
Understanding Written and Unwritten Agreements. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Rousseau, D. M., & Shperling, Z. 2003. Pieces of the action:
Ownership and the changing employment relationship. Academy of
Management Review, 28: 533-570.
Rousseau, D. M., & Tijoriwala, S. A. 1998. Assessing
psychological contracts: Issues, alternatives and measures. Journal of
Organizational Behavior, 19: 679-695.
Sahlins, M. D. 1972. Stone age Eeconomics. Chicago:
Aldine-Atherton.
Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in Administration: A Sociological
Interpretation. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Sheriff, M., Harvey, O., White, B., Hood, W., & Sherif, C.
1954. Experimental Study of Positive and Negative Intergroup Attitudes
Between Experimentally Produced Groups: Robbers Cove Experiment. Norman:
University of Oklahoma Press.
Spranger, E. 1928. Types of Men. Halle, Germany: Niemeyer.
Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in Action. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Thompson, J. A., & Bunderson, J. S. 2003. Violations of
principle: Ideological currency in the psychological contract. Academy
of Management Review, 28: 571-586.
Turnley, W. H., & Feldman, D. C. 1999. The impact of
psychological contract violations on exit, voice, loyalty, and neglect.
Human Relations, 52: 895-922.
Turnley, W. H., & Feldman, D. C. 2000. Re-examining the effects
of psychological contract violations: Unmet expectations and job
dissatisfaction as mediators. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 21:
25-42.
Veblen, T. 1923. Absentee Ownership and Business Enterprise in
Recent Times: The Case of America. New York: Viking.
Weick, K. E., & Roberts, K. H. 1993. Collective mind in
organizations: Heedful interrelating on flight decks. Administrative
Science Quarterly, 38: 357-381.
Werhane, P. H. 1985. Persons, rights, and corporations. Englewood
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Whitehead, A. N. 1929. The function of reason. Boston: Beacon
Press.
Wright, P., Kroll, M., Lado, A., & Elenkov, D. 2005. Influences
of relative rewards of top managers on firm performance. Strategic
Organization, 3: 311-335.
Yamagishi, T., & Cook, K. S. 1993. Generalized exchange and
social dilemmas. Social Psychology Quarterly, 56: 235-248.
William T. Jackson, University of South Florida St. Petersburg
Detelin Elenkov, Angelo State University
Peter Wright, University of Memphis
Barbara Davis, University of Memphis
Table 1: Identity Orientations, Forms of Exchange,
Valuation of Currencies, Breach, and Responses to Violation
Personal Negotiated Economic Transactional
Relational Reciprocal Socioemotional Relational
Collective Generalized Ideological Principled
Personal Lack of Support for the Negative Attitudes,
Economic Currency Reduced
Contributions, or
Turnover
Relational Lack of Support for the Negative Attitudes,
Socioemotional Reduced
Currency Contributions, or
Turnover
Collective Lack of Support for the Organizational
Ideological Currency Dissent