Legal origins and state economic freedom.
Nattinger, Matthew C. ; Hall, Joshua C.
INTRODUCTION
The subject of economic development has transformed significantly
in the past century. Historically, economic development fixated upon
factors of production like capital and labor and less on the role of
institutional quality in determining economic outcomes (Hall et al.
2010). As a result of the work of Nobel Laureate Douglass North (1990)
and others, institutions have increasingly been considered an important
force characterizing economic progress. North's work in particular,
both in his earlier work (North, 1994) and in his later work (North et
al., 2009) has helped to reshaped the way economists analyze the issue
of economic development and turned attention toward looking at the
effect of institutions--"the humanly devised constraints that shape
human interaction" (North, 1990, 3)--on economic performance. In
recent years, a growing body of research has used the Economic Freedom
of the World (EFW) index (Gwartney et al., 2010) to measure
institutional quality and has found a strong, positive relationship
between quality institutions and economic growth (see, for example,
Dawson, 1998; Gwartney et al., 1999; Cole, 2003; Gwartney et al., 2004;
Gwartney et al., 2006; Hall et al., 2010).
If institutions are important to economic growth, then it is
necessary to understand what factors are associated with institutional
quality. Recently, the empirical literature discussing the relationship
between institutions and economic growth has grown substantially.
However, little focus been given to examining the sources of
institutional quality across countries, with a few notable exceptions
such as such as Crampton (2002), De Haan and Sturm (2003), Boockmann and
Dreher (2003), Heckelman and Knack (2008), and Lawson and Clark (2010).
While these studies are valuable, they limit their focus to recent
causes of institutional change. As a result, they potentially overlook
historical determinants of institutional quality. Countries with poor
institutions in the past tend to have poor institutions today. Thus, we
need to look to history--at least in part--for a better understanding of
the sources of institutional diversity. A series of influential studies
begun by La Porta et al. (1997; 1998) examine the relationship between a
country's current economic condition and the origin of their legal
system. Essentially, contemporary market conditions are potentially
explained by past and present legal conditions, with present legal
conditions represented as a function of past legal conditions.
In this paper we build off these important studies by taking a
first look at the impact of colonial origins of U.S. states on current
state economic freedom, with a particular focus on the role that the
legal system of the settling country has on current institutional
quality. As is recent convention in the empirical institutional
literature, we measure a state's current institutional quality
using the Economic Freedom of North America (EFNA) index, published
annually by the Fraser Institute. We begin our analysis with further
discussion of how the legal origins of state settlers might influence
current institutional quality. We then proceed to describe our data and
empirical approach, present our results, and then summarize our findings
with a few concluding remarks.
LEGAL ORIGINS: CIVIL VS. COMMON LAW
Discovering the relationship between institutional quality and
economic growth has motivated a well-defined body of research focusing
on how good institutions are formed. Arguably, high-quality institutions
are formed when the rule of law is in place because the rule of law
facilitates the formation of other good institutions by creating
certainty and protection from expropriation (North et al., 2009).
Recently, economists have produced empirical evidence that financial
markets contribute to economic growth and strong legal institutions
contribute to the growth of financial markets (Mahoney, 2001). The
question is which legal institutions are best for economic development?
The reason this inquiry is important is because over time, multiple
structures of legal institutions have formed representing different
traditional legal systems (Mahoney, 2001). The two most common legal
systems are civil and common law. The common legal tradition is
primarily associated with England and the civil legal tradition with
France (although its origins are Roman). Hayek (1960) argues that
English and French concepts of law originated from their respective
notions of liberty. English models of liberty are derived from Locke and
Hume, who emphasized individual freedom, while the French model of
liberty is derived from Hobbes and Rousseau who emphasized
government's freedom to pursue the public's interest. In this
way, common law became a law of property. Civil law, on the other hand,
continually faces the risk of the legislature altering existing rights
for political purposes or in the public interest (Mahoney 2001).
According to Merryman (1985), common law developed to protect the
property rights of citizens from the monarch. Because of the ever
present risk of government expropriation of property under civil law,
Hayek (1960) argued that the British common legal tradition was superior
to the French civil legal tradition.
In recent years, empirical research in law and economics has gone
beyond a discussion of the differences between the two legal traditions
and instead focused on possible differences in economic outcomes between
the two types of legal traditions. Common and civil legal traditions
have spread throughout the world by conquest and imitation and thus many
countries legal systems have their roots in either British common law or
French civil law. The ability of common law countries to provide
investors greater protection from expropriation by corporate insiders
led La Porta et al. (1997) to look at differences in investor
protections between common law and civil law countries. From their
initial research comes a large body of work suggesting the
"economic consequences of legal origins are pervasive" (La
Porta et al., 1998, 298). They find that, when compared to countries
employing some version of the French civil legal system, common law
countries have more developed financial markets, lighter government
ownership, less regulation, less corruption, and more independent
judiciaries. These economic consequences tend to be related to improved
resource allocation; thus, it is not surprising that Mahoney (2001)
finds that British common law countries grew 0.6 percentage points
faster that French civil law countries from 1960 to 2000.
In three papers, Berkowitz and Clay (2004; 2005; 2006) utilize the
fact that ten of the U.S. states were settled by France, Spain, or
Mexico and thus had civil law systems prior to the American Revolution.
While all ten states, except for Louisiana, eventually transitioned to
the common law, their work finds that these states civil law origins
explain several important institutional features of these states today,
the most important of which is the impact of legal origins on the
quality of state courts today. Berkowitz and Clay (2005) find that civil
law states have had a higher degree of constitutional instability over
time, which is negatively related to the quality of state courts.
Berkowitz and Clay (2006) investigate the relationship between legal
origins and state court quality more in-depth and find a negative
relationship between the number of years a state was a civil law state
and state court quality in the early 2000s. Given the pervasiveness of
economic outcomes related to legal origins from an international
perspective, Berkowitz and Clay's research is important because it
points toward the significance of legal origins in understanding current
economic institutions as well as legal institutions.
DATA AND EMPIRICAL APPROACH
In order to test the hypothesis that legal origins are related to
current economic institutions, we need data on both legal origins and
economic institutions. Our data on the legal origins of states was
obtained from Berkowitz and Clay (2004; 2005; 2006). They note that
there are ten current states that initially had civil law origins
because they were initially settled by France, Mexico, or Spain. These
states are Alabama, Arizona, Arkansas, California, Florida, Louisiana,
Mississippi, Missouri, New Mexico, and Texas. Eventually all of these
states, except for Louisiana, adopted common law. The adoption of common
law by most of these states occurred after the American Revolution in
1776. Arguably, those states that shifted from civil to common legal
structures retained some of the elements of the civil legal system.
The remaining states were settled with common legal structures,
either through British settlement or American expansion. For the purpose
of this analysis these two will be grouped into common law states. There
are mild variations in these two forms of common law, but they are
extremely similar and are also distinctly different from the civil legal
tradition. American states are denoted as settler states and British
states were colonized states (Berkowitz and Clay, 2006).
The dependent variable for this analysis is the North American Economic Freedom Index (EFNA) published annually by the Fraser
Institute, a Canadian think tank (Karabegovic and McMahon, 2008). The
EFNA measures the extent to which a state's economic institutions
are consistent with resource allocation being guided by personal choice
in markets, rather than by collective decision-making. The authors of
the EFNA gather third-party data on ten variables in three policy areas
to measure the economic freedom of each state (and Canadian province).
Since we are measuring the effect of legal origins on economic
institutions, it is important to note that there are zero variables in
the EFNA that directly measure legal institutions such as the rule of
law. Each variable, such as total tax revenue as a percentage of GDP, is
placed onto a zero-to-ten scale and then aggregated into a zero-to-ten
overall freedom score. Thus, higher scores represent higher levels of
economic freedom. Since the data used in the EFNA are published with a
lag, the fact that we employ the 2008 edition of the report means that
we are using index scores representing state economic freedom in the
year 2005. In that year the most free state at the all-government level
was Delaware with a score of 8.5 and the least free was West Virginia with a score of 5.3.
Summary statistics for all the variables can be found in Table 1.
Our control variables that might be related to long-run institutional
quality were also obtained from Berkowitz and Clay (2004; 2005). These
control variables are the initial population of the state, its climate,
percentage slave population, and the southern states. For further
documentation on each variable see Table 1 of Berkowitz and Clay (2005).
The intuition for each of these control variables is straightforward.
For example, the size of a state's initial population is positively
related to vote cycling and thus negatively related to the stability of
a state's constitution over time, thus it might be positively
related to current state institutional quality. Similarly, climate,
slave population, and the a binary variable for a Southern Confederacy state are attempting to control for the influence of slavery and the
extractive institutions often associated with hotter climates.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
In this section we estimate the effect legal origins have on
contemporary economic performance using the North American Economic
Freedom Index of 2005. The independent variable of interest is the
binary variable that represent if a state is a descendent of a civil
legal tradition (1=civil, 0=common). Table 2 depicts the model's
results, estimated using ordinary least squares (OLS). The coefficient
on the legal origins variable is negative and significant at the 10
percent level, suggesting a negative relationship between a state being
founded by a civil law country and its current economic institutions as
measure by the Economic Freedom of North America index. This result
holds while controlling for other important historical variables such as
being a member of the Confederacy, a state's climate, and its slave
population.
It is interesting to note that states that were members of the
Confederacy have higher economic freedom today, ceteris paribus,
contrary to what a priori theorizing would suggest. Perhaps this occurs
the EFNA measures primarily areas like taxation and spending
policy--areas where the legacy of slavery indirectly leads to less
economic freedom because of reduced provision of publicly-provided
goods--then areas like property rights and the rule of law where's
slavery's legacy has been to inhibit economic freedom. Further
research is needed to reconcile this finding with the work of Carden
(2009) and others on the impact of slavery and the Confederacy on
institutions.
CONCLUSION
In this paper we analyzed the role of legal origins in explaining
current institutional quality at the U.S. state level using the Economic
Freedom of North America index. Building on previous work by Berkowitz
and Clay (2004; 2005; 2006), we exploit the fact that ten states were
settled by the civil law countries of France, Spain, and Mexico. After
controlling for initial conditions, including climate and membership in
the Confederacy, a state that descended from a civil law legal tradition
has lower economic freedom today, ceteris paribus, when compared to a
state that was initially settled by a common law country. This finding
creates further support for the importance of legal origins to current
economic institutions as well as getting towards a better understanding
of the historical origins of present-day institutions.
Further research is needed, however, to further explore the role of
other factors in explaining current economic institutions. In
particular, it would be interesting to note if this result holds up
after controlling for other factors that might be related to a
state's legal origins. For example, common law states tended to
have industrial economies and civil law states were more agricultural.
If civil law states are more likely to have extractive economic and
political institutions (Acemoglu et al., 2001) in a manner not
controlled for with the percentage of slave population and the South
binary variable, then our results might overstate the relationship
between legal origins and current levels of economic freedom. It is also
possible that rather than directly influencing economic institutions,
legal origins could work indirectly through these and other factors,
such as culture. Following from Tollison (2007), we would urge future
researchers to explore the rich data on political and economic
institutions available in the Book of the States (Council of State
Governments, 2010).
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, & J. Robinson. 2001. The colonial
origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. American
Economic Review 91(5), 1369-1401.
Berkowitz, D., & K. Clay. (2004). Initial conditions,
institutional dynamics and economic performance: evidence from the
American states. mimeo.
Berkowitz, D., & K. Clay. (2005). American civil law origins:
implications for state constitutions. American Law and Economics Review,
7(1), 62-84.
Berkowitz, D., & K. Clay. (2006). The effect of judicial
independence on courts: evidence from the American states. Journal of
Legal Studies, 35(2), 399-400.
Boockmann, B., & A. Dreher. (2003). The contribution of the IMF and the World Bank to economic freedom. European Journal of Political
Economy, 19(3), 633-649.
Carden, A. (2009). Inputs and institutions as conservative
elements. Review of Austrian Economics, 22(1), 1-19.
Cole, J. (2003). The contribution of economic freedom to world
economic growth: 1980-99. Cato Journal, 23(2), 189-198.
Council of State Governments (2010). Book of the States. Lexington:
Council of State Governments.
Crampton, E. (2002). You get what you vote for: voter preferences
and economic freedom. Journal of Private Enterprise, 18, 32-56.
De Haan, J., & J. Sturm. (2003). Does more democracy lead to
greater economic freedom? new evidence for developing countries.
European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 547-563.
Gwartney, J., R. Lawson, & J. Hall. (2010). Economic Freedom of
the World: 2010 Annual Report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.
Gwartney, J., R. Holcombe, & R. Lawson. (2004). Economic
freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income
and growth. Cato Journal, 24(3), 205-233.
Gwartney, J., R. Holcombe, & R. Lawson. (2006). Institutions
and the impact of investment on growth. Kyklos, 59(2), 255-273.
Hall, J., R. Sobel & G. Crowley. (2010). Institutions, capital,
and growth, Southern Economic Journal, 77(2), 385-405.
Heckelman, J., & S. Knack. (2008). Foreign aid and
market-liberalizing reform. Economica, 75, 524-548.
Hayek, F.A. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Karabegovic, A., & F. McMahon. (2008). Economic Freedom of
North America: 2008 Annual Report. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute.
La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, & R. Vishny.
(1997). Legal Determinants of External Finance. Journal of Finance,
52(3), 1131-1150.
La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, & R. Vishny.
(1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 6, 1113-1155.
Lawson, R., & J. Clark. (2010). Examining the Hayek-Friedman
hypothesis on economic and political freedom. Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization 74, 230-239.
Mahoney, P. (2001). The common law and economic growth: Hayek might
be right. Journal of Legal Studies, 30(2), 503-525.
Merryman, J. (1985). The Civil law tradition: an introduction to
the legal systems of Western Europe and Latin America. Stanford:
Stanford University Press.
North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic
performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.
North, D. (1994). Economic performance through time. American
Economic Review, 84(3), 359-368.
North, D., J. Wallis, & B. Weingast. (2009). Violence and
social orders: a conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human
history. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Tollison, R. (2007). Old wine, new wine. Public Choice, 132(1-2),
3-5.
Matthew C. Nattinger, University of Iowa
Joshua C. Hall, Beloit College
Table 1: Descriptive Statistics
Variable Mean Std. Dev.
North American Freedom Index (2005) 6.688 0.58
Ln Per Capita Income (2005) 10.405 0.145
Ln Initial Population -0.369 2.377
Civil Legal Origin 0.2292 0.4247
Climate 13.13 7.5
% Slave Population in State 10.29 17.74
Southern States 0.229 0.424
Variable Min Max
North American Freedom Index (2005) 5.3 8.5
Ln Per Capita Income (2005) 10.123 10.778
Ln Initial Population -3.912 1
Civil Legal Origin 0 3.797
Climate 1.99 39.79
% Slave Population in State 0 57.2
Southern States 0 1
Table 2: Economic Freedom and Legal Origin: OLS Results
Variable Coefficient T-Score
Constant 7.08# 36.6
Civil Legal Origin -0.4314# -1.98
Ln Initial Population 0.009 0.27
Climate -0.0154 -0.91
% Slave Population in State -0.017 -1.19
Southern States 1.231# 2.26
N 48
R-sq 0.1
Note: Variables statistically significant at least at the 10% level
are in bold.
Note: Variables statistically significant at least at the 10% level
are indicated with #.