More economics in the movies: discovering the modern theory of bureaucracy in scenes from conspiracy and Valkyrie.
Mixon, Franklin G., Jr.
INTRODUCTION
This essay describes how the elements of the modern theory of
bureaucracy (Breton and Wintrobe, 1982), and its application to (1) the
Nazi Holocaust (Breton and Wintrobe, 1986; Mixon, Sawyer and Trevino,
2004a and 2004b; Mixon and King, 2009; Mixon and Trevino, 2009) and (2)
the 20 July 1944 plot to kill Adolf Hitler (Mixon, Sawyer and Trevino,
2004b), can be integrated, and in an innovative way, into the
"Bureaucracy Theory" portion of an undergraduate course in
public choice economics. Specifically, this article shows how the theory
and its applications above are reconstructed in the movies Conspiracy
(HBO Films, 2001) and Valkyrie (United Artists, 2008), respectively, and
it suggests scenes from each movie that can be incorporated into
classroom discussion of the modern theory of bureaucracy.
Given the paucity of specialized undergraduate textbooks in this
genre of economics, an "economics in the movies" approach to
pedagogy like that described in Mateer (2004 and 2009), Dixit (2006),
Sexton (2006) and Mateer and Li (2008) could be quite beneficial. As
Mateer and Li (2008: 303) point out, among the pedagogical advantages to
using short film scenes to introduce economic concepts are (1) increased
student engagement, (2) an enhanced ability to critically analyze core
content, and (3) the availability of an alternative to the
lecture-discussion format. They also add that this new approach can,
unlike some other pedagogical techniques, complement the traditional
development of economic theory without sacrificing a significant amount
of class time (Mateer and Li, 2008: 303).
This essay begins with a brief review of the relevant literature,
including a summary of the modern theory of bureaucracy. This summary is
followed by a description of how the theory has been applied to the Nazi
Holocaust and other elements of the history of Nazi Germany. From there,
some scenes from the movies Conspiracy and Valkyrie are presented as
useful tools for teaching undergraduate economics students about the
modern theory of bureaucracy.
A BRIEF REVIEW OF THE RELEVANT LITERATURE
It is not often that a new way of approaching a subject is
accompanied by an example as compelling as that Breton and Wintrobe
(1986) used to illustrate the applicability of their modern theory of
bureaucracy (Breton and Wintrobe, 1982). The traditional theory of
bureaucracy in Niskanan (1971) argues that government bureaucrats seek
to increase their power, influence, and other job-related perquisites by
engaging in the process of budget-maximization (Shughart, 2008; Olson,
2008). (1) In this formal model, bureaucrats are able to capitalize on the lack of technical know-how exhibited by those in the legislature who
provide resources for the bureaucracy, and on what Downs (1957)
characterized as the "rational ignorance" of voters (the
electorate), who represent the other principals (along with
legislatures) who might constrain the activities of bureaucrats and
bureaus (Shughart, 2008; Olson, 2008). At the same time bureaucracies
seek growth, there is a general consensus that they are inefficient and
inflexible, a conclusion that stems partly from a lack of information
they confront as a result of their output being indivisible and
unmarketable (Olson, 2008).
Breton and Wintrobe's (1982) modern theory of bureaucracy is
based in large part on the ideas of "vertical trust networks"
and "informal payments." According to the model, subordinates
within a bureaucracy provide top-level bureaucrats with "informal
services" that are the result of their own enterprise and
initiative, and that advance the aims of the bureaucracy's
leadership. The bureau's subordinates also trust that the
bureaucrats will later reward them informally by providing opportunities
for more rapid advancement (promotion), better offices, travel, etc.
These perquisites are all quid pro quos that are not part of formal
contracts between bureaucrats and a bureau's subordinates, and
often result from trades that are described above as inter-temporal in
nature (Breton and Wintrobe, 1982 and 1986; Mixon, Sawyer and Trevino,
2004a and 2004b). Use of such an informal payments mechanism allows
bureaucrats to establish a competitive process in the promotion of the
bureau's goal(s), and one which provides greater efficiency and
flexibility.
Breton and Wintrobe's (1986) application arrived through their
article in the Journal of Political Economy titled "The bureaucracy
of murder revisited," wherein they point out that the traditional
theory of bureaucracy fails to explain how the Nazi bureaucracy formed
as a conglomeration of competing agencies that (for a time) carried out
the large-scale "Final Solution" to the "Jewish
question" (Mixon, et al. 2004b). As Mixon et al. (2004b: 372)
explain, the Breton and Wintrobe (1986) model is not only well-suited to
explain how a quasi-government bureaucracy carried out the systematic
murder of six million people in a relative short period of time, it is
also adept at establishing the guilt of the bureau's subordinates
who claimed (in judicial proceedings and interviews) to simply have been
carrying out orders from superiors in the bureaucracy. (2) The Breton
and Wintrobe (1986) story of the Nazi Holocaust is built mainly around
that of Adolf Eichmann, the SS- Obersturmbannfuhrer in Subsection IV-B-4
(Jewish affairs) of the Reich Central Security Office, who (for a time)
showed significant enterprise and initiative in the promotion of the
systematic murder of Europe's Jews throughout the early 1940s. As a
result, Eichmann advanced from the 45th percentile of the Nazi Holocaust
bureaucracy to the 65th percentile, all from 1938-1941 (Mixon, et al.
2004a: 863).
The following section describes how the elements in the modern
theory of bureaucracy (Breton and Wintrobe, 1982), and in its
application to the Nazi Holocaust (Breton and Wintrobe, 1986; Mixon et
al. 2004a and 2004b) and the 20 July 1944 plot to kill Adolf Hitler
(Mixon et al. 2004b), can be integrated, and in an innovative way, into
the "Bureaucracy" portion of an undergraduate course in public
choice economics. Specifically, section 2 below shows how the modern
theory of bureaucracy and its application are reconstructed in the
movies Conspiracy (HBO Films, 2001) and Valkyrie (United Artists, 2008),
respectively. In doing so, this article highlights scenes from each
movie that can be incorporated into classroom discussion of the theory
and its application to the Nazi bureaucracy of the 1940s.
THE MODERN THEORY OF BUREAUCRACY: A LOOK AT THE MOVIES
As stated earlier, there are few instances where an application of
a model or theory is more compelling that that represented by the Breton
and Wintrobe (1986) application of their own modern theory of
bureaucracy (Breton and Wintrobe, 1982) to events constituting the Nazi
Holocaust. The kinds of bureaucratic entrepreneurship that give rise to
informal services and payments that are part of vertical trust networks
described by Breton and Wintrobe (1982) fit well into the
"Bureaucracy" portion of an undergraduate course in public
choice economics, and they are relatively easy to impart to students
without the requirement that students acquire Breton and Wintrobe's
1982 book. (3) After such an exposition, Breton and Wintrobe's
compelling 1986 article on bureaucratic entrepreneurship in the Third
Reich is accessible to, and appreciated by, students. (4)
Another option for integrating the Breton and Wintrobe (1982)
modern model of bureaucracy in a public choice economics course is to
employ a Hollywood adaptation of one of the more important aspects of
the Nazi Holocaust--the Wannsee Conference of 1942. That adaptation
comes via HBO Films' 2001 movie Conspiracy, and pedagogical use of
a television movie adaptation of the 1942 Wannsee Conference follows the
recent wave of using movies and television to teach undergraduate
economics that is emphasized in Mateer (2004 and 2009), Dixit (2006),
Sexton (2006) and Mateer and Li (2008).
Conspiracy was written by Loring Mandel, who won an Emmy Award for
Best Writing, and it received 10 total Emmy nominations. (5) Another of
the 10 nominations turned into a victory for Kenneth Branagh, who
received a Lead Actor Emmy for his portrayal of Reinhard Heydrich, Chief
of the Reich Central Security Office (RHSA) who "chaired" the
1942 Wannsee Conference. The role of Adolf Eichmann, the leading figure
in Breton and Wintrobe (1986), is played by Stanley Tucci, an Emmy and
Golden Globe Award winner for his work in the movie Winchell. Most of
the Conference participants, and their Conspiracy counterparts, are
listed in Table 1.
Conspiracy is rich in instances wherein aspects of Breton and
Wintrobe's (1982 and 1986) competitive model of bureaucracy--one
which provides greater efficiency and flexibility than that depicted in
earlier models of bureaucracy--are superbly reconstructed in the story
of the Nazi bureaucracy's goal of genocide. Several instances have
significant pedagogical value, such as the scene in the movie wherein
Heydrich reads aloud a memo which is believed to have been penned by
himself, but was actually signed and sent to Heydrich by German Reich Marshall Hermann Goring, authorizing a "solution" to "the
Jewish question." The memo authorizes a solution involving
"emigration or evacuation in the most favorable way possible"
of the Jews living in the German sphere of influence within Europe.
As Breton and Wintrobe (1986) state, one indicator of competition
among bureaus (bureaucrats) or within bureaus concerns the imprecision
of orders from higher echelons within the bureau or bureaus (Mixon et
al. 2004a: 858). In Conspiracy, Heydrich and the other Wannsee
Conference participants wrangle with the lack of precision in the term
"evacuation," which Heydrich takes to mean the
"cleansing" of Europe's Jews, itself an imprecise term.
As Mixon et al. (2004a: 866) point out, the fact that Heydrich had to
interpret (for others) a memo that he penned himself is itself
interesting; that Heydrich's interpretation was also imprecise
remarkably supports the Breton-Wintrobe thesis that vague and imprecise
directives motivate would-be bureaucratic entrepreneurs into devising
innovative and enterprising initiatives that assist the bureau in
achieving a goal. (6) These ideas are reinforced through some of the
pre-Conference conversations portrayed in Conspiracy. It is in one of
these that Josef Buhler, the Secretary of State in the Office of the
Government General of Poland, who is portrayed in Conspiracy by British
actor Ben Daniels, offers dialogue that supports the discussion above
concerning Heydrich's memo. In a pre-Conference conversation scene
Buhler says ". . . we will soon discover what new concepts our SS
friends have in mind [for addressing 'the Jewish question'] .
. ." It is through statements like this one that enterprise and
initiative in putting forward "solutions" to "the Jewish
question" included new and innovative ideas, concepts, initiatives,
and policies (Mixon et al. 2004a: 866). (7)
Once the framework for bureaucratic competition and
entrepreneurship is established, as it was with the Nazi's Wannsee
Conference of 1942, the role of vertical trust networks, with the
attendant informal payments and informal services that are discussed
above, take over the process of achieving the Nazi Holocaust
bureaucracy's goal of genocide. The benefits of these relationships
to the Nazi bureaucracy's superiors, and their attendant trades,
are not seen in Conspiracy. However, pre-Conference vertical trust
networks, along with some of the concepts used in the genocide of
Lithuania's Jews (during the fall of 1941), are described by Mixon
et al. (2004b: 374-376) in a way (i.e., non-technical, brief) that
allows public choice economics instructors to supplement scenes from
Conspiracy with passages and tables from some of the historical
episodes. (8)
The antithesis of vertical trust networks in the Breton and
Wintrobe (1982) model are "horizontal trust networks." These
are networks that exist between officials who operate at roughly the
same level of a bureaucracy's management structure. They are seen
as being inefficient, in a large numbers setting such as in the Nazi
Holocaust bureaucracy, from the leadership's perspective because
cooperation among similarly-situated subordinates often works to thwart
the goals of the bureau's leadership (Breton and Wintrobe, 1982 and
1986; Mixon et al. 2004b). According to Mixon et al. (2004b: 376),
"[t]he history of the Nazi regime provides an insightful example of
an extreme form of horizontal network inefficiency: the 20 July 1944
plot to kill Adolf Hitler." In just a few pages, Mixon et al.
(2004b: 376-378) provide details of the plot as an example of horizontal
trust networks in a way that both generalizes and supplements Breton and
Wintrobe's essay on the Nazi Holocaust bureaucracy and Adolf
Eichmann's role in advancing it. In that way, Mixon et al. (2004b)
can be integrated into the bureaucracy discussion of a public choice
economics class relatively easily.
As in the case of vertical trust networks described above, the
academic literature on horizontal trust networks in the Nazi Holocaust
bureaucracy (i.e., Mixon et al. 2004b) can also be supplemented with
scenes from a movie. In this case that is the motion picture Valkyrie,
released by United Artists in 2008, and starring Tom Cruise as German
Reserve Army Colonel Claus Schenk Graff von Stauffenberg, the central
figure in the 20 July 1944 plot to kill Hitler.
As Table 2 points out, Cruise is joined in Valkyrie by Kenneth
Branagh who portrays Henning von Tresckow, and by Tom Wilkinson, Bill
Nighy, and Terence Stamp, who play German Reserve Army Commander
Freidrich Fromm, German Reserve Army Colonel General Freidrich Olbricht
and retired Chief of General Staff Ludwig Beck, respectively. Directed
by the critically acclaimed Bryan Singer, each of these actors performs
solidly in their respective roles.
The scenes and dialogue also provide a portrayal of the concept of
horizontal trust networks found in Breton and Wintrobe (1982 and 1986).
Though Valkyrie is more of an action movie than Conspiracy, one critical
scene in Valkyrie depicts Stauffenberg meeting, for the first time, the
plot's original conspirators. To set the scene, Stauffenberg has
only recently recovered from wounds suffered during the German retreat
in North Africa, and he is, at the time of the meeting scene described
earlier, an officer in the German Reserve Army. Stauffenberg (Cruise) is
urged to meet the original conspirators by Olbricht, and after being
received at the meeting by von Tresckow, and he is impressed by what he
learns about the lofty positions the conspirators hold (or once held) in
various branches of the larger Nazi (German) bureaucracy. The positions
fall under the military/intelligence, diplomatic, political and civil
corps of the Nazi (German) bureaucracy, as pointed in Mixon et al.
(2004b) and in Table 2.8 After hearing how the original conspirators
appear to have all of the bases covered for building a new, post-Hitler
Germany, Stauffenberg questions his presence in the room to von Tresckow
and the others, and attempts to exit. Though sympathetic to the cause,
by military rank Stauffenberg does not necessarily fit into the
horizontal trust network that he is being introduced to in this scene.
However, he is convinced that the act of tyrannicide has to be carried
out, and that, given his inclinations and position in the Reserve Army,
he might have the means and opportunity to assist.
In giving his assistance to the plot, Mixon et al. (2004b: 377)
explain that Stauffenberg, and others at his level, or a lower level in
the larger Nazi bureaucracy, contributed "vertical loyalty"
(i.e., they formed a vertical trust network) to assist those in the
horizontal trust network presented in Table 2. Though not as rich in the
quantity of scenes and dialogue with pedagogical value as Conspiracy,
the particular scenes from Valkyrie described above really hit a mark
with regard to capturing part of the Breton and Wintrobe (1982 and 1986)
concept of horizontal trust networks in bureaucracy.
CONCLUDING COMMENTS
The recent wave of using movies and television to teach
undergraduate economics, emphasized in Mateer (2004 and 2009), Dixit
(2006), Sexton (2006) and Mateer and Li (2008), is potentially most
beneficial in those economics courses for which the publishing industry
has yet to produce a specialized textbook. That is the case with an
undergraduate course in public choice economics. Here, some instructors
adopt books of readings, supplemented by a reading list containing
published journal articles, while other instructors simply opt for the
latter.
This article provides some guidelines for integrating
"economics in the movies" into a part of a public choice
economics course. Various scenes from the HBO Films (2001) production of
Conspiracy, and at least one key scene from the United Artists (2008)
production of Valkyrie, offer avenues for using movie scenes to explain
critical aspects of the modern theory of bureaucracy (Breton and
Wintrobe, 1982). Given the benefits of an "economics in the
movies" approach like those described in this essay, its use to
cover some of the bureaucracy theory portions of an undergraduate course
in public choice economics might make for a successful pedagogical
enterprise.
AUTHOR'S NOTE
The author thanks two anonymous referees of this journal for
helpful comments on an earlier version of this article. The usual caveat
applies.
REFERENCES
Breton, A. & R. Wintrobe (1982). The logic of bureaucratic
conduct: An economic analysis of competition, exchange, and efficiency
in private and public organizations, Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge
University Press.
Breton, A. & R. Wintrobe (1986). The bureaucracy of murder
revisited. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 905-926.
Dixit, A. (2006). "Restoring fun to game theory," In W.E.
Becker, M. Watts and S.R. Becker (Eds.), Teaching economics: More
alternatives to chalk and talk (pp. 1-19). Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward
Elgar.
Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy, New York, NY:
Harper.
Mateer, G.D. (2004). Economics in the movies, Mason, OH:
Thomson-Southwestern.
Mateer, G.D. (2009). Recent film scenes for teaching introductory
economics. In F.G. Mixon, Jr. & R.J. Cebula (Eds.), Expanding
teaching and learning horizons in economic education (pp. 165-172). New
York, NY: Nova Science Publishers,.
Mateer, G.D. & H. Li (2008). Movie scenes for economics.
Journal of Economic Education, 39(3), 303.
Mixon, F.G., Jr. & E.W. King (2009). Coercion, vertical trust
and entrepreneurism in bureaucracies: Statistical evidence from the Nazi
Holocaust. Economics Bulletin, 29(2), 681-687.
Mixon, F.G., Jr., W.C. Sawyer & L.T. Trevino (2004a). The
bureaucracy of murder: Empirical evidence. International Journal of
Social Economics, 31(9), 855-867.
Mixon, F.G., Jr., W. Charles Sawyer & L.T. Trevino (2004b).
Vertical and horizontal trust networks in bureaucracy: Evidence from the
Third Reich. Constitutional Political Economy, 15(4), 371-381.
Mixon, F.G., Jr. & L.J. Trevino (2009). The modern economic
theory of bureaucracy as a precursor to New Public Management.
Humanomics, in press.
Niskanen, W.A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government,
Chicago, IL: Aldine- Atherton.
Olson, M.L. (2008). Bureaucracy. In S.N. Durlauf & L.E. Blume
(Eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. New York, NY: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Sexton, R. (2006). Using short movie and television clips in the
economics principles class. Journal of Economic Education, 37(4),
406-417.
Shughart, W.F, II (2008). Public choice. In The Concise
Encyclopedia of Economics, New York, NY: Liberty Fund.
ENDNOTES
(1) In Niskanen's (1971) formal model, the bureaucrat's
power, influence, job-related perquisites are an increasing function of
the bureaucracy's size or budget (Olson, 2008).
(2) As Breton and Wintrobe (1986) indicate, it is more difficult to
establish the guilt of subordinates using earlier theories of
bureaucracy.
(3) As many public choice scholars are aware, there is no
specialized textbook for undergraduate courses in public choice
economics. As a result, instructors often choose to assign (require)
books of readings that generally contain published journal articles.
Given the limited use of original source materials (e.g., Niskanen,
1971; Breton and Wintrobe, 1982) in any one portion of a semester-long
public choice economics course, particularly those in book form,
instructors may find it difficult to justify having students purchase
those materials.
(4) Given the lack of public choice economics textbook options
noted earlier, instructors often use reading lists containing various
journal article publications from the genre. Though which articles to
require (or recommend), if any, in each portion of the course is often a
matter of personal preference, I have found that students show interest
in the Breton and Wintrobe (1986) application of the modern theory of
bureaucracy.
(5) Conspiracy consists almost entirely of the dialogue from the
Conference, which is generally recognized as the origin of earlier-used
terms such as "Final Solution" and "Jewish
Question."
(6) Conspiracy contains other examples of imprecise language regarding the "Final Solution" that are not included in Mixon
et al. (2004a). At the beginning of the Conference, Heydrich is shown
stating that "We have a storage problem in Germany with these
Jews," and that "I have been asked to direct the release of
Germany and all of Europe from the Jewish stranglehold, and I believe
that together we will." Emphasis has been added to the quotes above
to highlight the other uses by Heydrich of imprecise terms that are
hoped by him to motivate competitive behavior on the part of the
Conference attendees and the branches or divisions of Nazi Germany that
they represent. Heydrich's last line above, that he believes the
group can together accomplish something with regard to the evacuation of
the European Jews supports the Breton and Wintrobe (1982 and 1986)
notion that a new or modern kind of bureaucracy was motivated to action
in this case. Finally, it is interesting that in the movie Heydrich is
pressed by the Conference attendees to judge some of their
interpretations of "evacuation" and the other imprecise terms.
At one point the movie portrayal of events even has Heydrich specifying
his own preference for interpreting the term(s).
(7) At points in the movie Eichmann relays to attendees the
preliminary results of various applications of "concepts" and
"initiatives," such as mobile gassing vehicles and the
infamous furnace systems that would ultimately used in the death camps.
It is also worth noting here that Conspiracy portrays some of the
perquisites that Nazi Holocaust participants might expect as a result of
their successful "concepts" and "initiatives."
Heydrich is shown stating to some Conference attendees how he is fond of
the Wannsee mansion where the Conference was held, and that he expects
it to become his post-war home.
(8) One lesson from Mixon et al. (2004a and 2004b) is that the
"solutions" implemented by Einsatzkommando 3 in Lithuania in
1941 were inadequate for achieving the Nazi bureaucracy's ultimate
goal of the "cleansing" of Europe's Jews (Mixon et al.
2004b: 375). For that the Nazi bureaucracy turned to another initiative
developed in 1941, the construction of death camps like those at Belzec,
Sobibor, and Treblinka (Mixon et al. 2004a: 861).
Franklin G. Mixon, Jr., Columbus State University
Table 1: Wannsee Conference Particpants as Portrayed in Conspiracy
Conference Bureau Portrayed in
Participant Conspiracy by
Reinhard Heydrich Chairman, Reich Central Kenneth Branagh
Security Office (RHSA)
Dr. Alfred Meyer Reich Ministry for Occupied Brian Pettifer
EasternTerritories
Dr. Georg Liebbrandt Reich Ministry for Occupied Ewan Stewart
Eastern Territories
Erich Neumann Secretary of State, Reich Jonathan Coy
Ministry for the Interior
Dr. Roland Freisler Secretary of State, Reich Owen Teale
Ministry of Justice
Dr. Josef Buhler Secretary of State, Office of Ben Daniels
the Government General of
Poland
Dr. Martin Luther Under-Secretary of State, Kevin McNally
Foreign Office Office
Gerhard Klopfer Party Chancellery Ian McNeice
Friedrich Kritzinger Reich Chancellery David Threlfall
Otto Hofmann Race and Settlement Main Nicholas
Office (RuSHA) Woodeson
Heinrich Muller Reich Main Security, Gestapo Brenden Coyle
Chief
Adolf Eichmann Reich Central Security Office Stanley Tucci
(RHSA,Subs. IV-B-4)
Dr. Karl Schongarth SD Chief of the General Peter Sullivan
Government of Poland
Dr. Rudolf Lange SD Chief of Latvia Barnabay Kay
Sources: Mixon, Sawyer and Trevino (2004a) and HBO Films (2001).
Table 2: Conspirators in July 1944 Plot to Kill Hitler as Portrayed in
Valkyrie
Conspirator Position in Nazi Hierarchy Portrayed in
Valkyrie by
Claus Schenk Graff Colonel, Reserve Army Tom Cruise
von Stauffenberg
Military/Intelligence Conspirators
Ludwig Beck Colonel General, Chief of Terence Stamp
General Staff (retired, 1939)
Wilhelm Canaris Admiral, Head of
Counterintelligence
Friedrich Fromm General, Commander of Reserve Tom Wilkinson
Army
Adolf Heusinger Colonel General, Operations Matthew Burton
Chief of the Army High Command
Erich Hopner Colonel General (dismissed,
1941)
Gunther Hans von Field Marshall
Kluge
Friedrich Olbricht Colonel General, Reserve Army Bill Nighy
Hans Oster Major General,
Counterintelligence
Erwin Rommel Field Marshall
Karl Heinrich von Colonel General, Military
Stulpnagel Government of France
Henning von Kenneth Branagh
Tresckow Major
General
Erwin von Field Marshall (retired, 1942) David Schofield
Witzleben
Diplomatic Corps Conspirators
Hans Bernd Diplomatic Office, Switzerland
Gisevius
Christian von German Ambassador to Italy
Hassell (retired)
Adam von Trott zu German Foreign Ministry
Solz
Political/Civil Conspirators
Carl Goerdeler Lord Mayor of Leipzig (former) Kevin McNally
Wolf Heinrich von Chief of Berlin Police Waldemar Kobus
Helldorf
Julius Leber Member of Reichstag (former)
Johannes Popitz Prussian Finance Minister
Sources: Mixon, Sawyer and Trevino (2004b) and United Artists (2008).