The emergence of commodity money alongside a functioning fiat money.
White, John B.
INTRODUCTION
Do you ever wonder how your pharmacy always (or nearly always) has
the prescription medication you need when you need it? Grocery stores
often find themselves short of bread, or milk, or some item that is on
your shopping list. Everyone has experienced the frustration of going to
the shoe store and finding the perfect shoe, only to discover that they
do not have it in your size. How is it that pharmacies, with hundreds of
drugs behind the counter, successfully manage to maintain an inventory
that supports a nearly perfect on time delivery record, when other
businesses frequently find themselves short of a particular item?
Pharmacies in a small community in southeast Georgia (USA) enhance
their chances of delivering the requested prescription drug by
cooperating with one another in an exceptional manner. If one pharmacy
finds itself short of a particular medicine, it calls a local competitor
and asks if they have that particular item. If the requested pharmacy
finds itself short of another drug, a barter exchange is negotiated,
enabling both pharmacies deliver the product to their customers with
unerring efficiency. Given the size of the community, all of the
pharmacists know one another. They may have previously worked together
in the local location of a national chain, such as CVS, but now may work
for different pharmacies, or may have even opened their own pharmacy.
Speaking with local pharmacists, none could recall a time when they did
not exchange pharmaceutical products with each other.
However, the most common inter-pharmacy exchange involves neither
cash nor a direct barter exchange. Rather, a system has evolved where
drugs that are commonly exchanged are priced in terms of one specific
drug, Prevacid[TM]. Prevacid[TM] (generic name: Lansoprazole) is
manufactured by TAP Pharmaceuticals to treat gastrointestinal disorders.
It is commonly prescribed for those who have acid reflux disorder. Its
sales make this drug one of the top 20 pharmaceutical products, with
revenues in excess of $3 billion per year.
PREVACID[TM] AS A MEDIUM OF EXCHANGE
The exchange of a particular drug for Prevacid[TM] is an exchange
of equivalent dollar values of the drugs. For instance, if Lipitor[TM]
(a cholesterol medication from Pfizer) costs $10 per tablet and TAP
Pharmaceuticals charges $2 per Prevacid tablet, then 100 Lipitor[TM]
(worth $1000) would cost 500 Prevacid[TM] (also worth $1000). Likewise,
if Singulair[TM] (asthma medication from Merck) is $6 per tablet, then
100 Singulair[TM] would cost 300 Prevacid[TM] in this $600 transaction.
Since these exchanges are for equivalent dollar amounts, Prevacid[TM]
can be used to "buy" liquid medications as well.
Prices from the major drug manufacturers are relatively stable.
There are no "seasons" associated with hypertension medication
as there would be with "back to school" supplies in the fall
or jewelry at Christmas and Valentine's Day. However, on those rare
occasions when a drug price does change, then the pharmacies continue to
exchange an equivalent dollar amount of Prevacid[TM] for the other drug.
Thus, Prevacid[TM] serves as money in these transactions, much like
gold, salt or cigarettes have done in the past. Money is generally
acknowledged as having three functions: the medium of exchange; the unit
of account; and a store of value. (See any introductory economics text,
such as Mankiw (2009), Baumol and Blinder (2009) or Bade and Parkin (2007).) For this particular inter-pharmacy market, Prevacid[TM] takes
on the medium of exchange function of money. While the specific drug
that serves as the medium of exchange has changed over time, the primary
requirement, that the drug is a fast mover, has remained constant. The
dollar continues to be the unit of account, as the dollar establishes
equivalent values, and also a store of value.
While most of our purchases use the dollar as the medium of
exchange and unit of account, it is not a requirement that these two
functions be performed by the same asset. Indeed, while the medium of
exchange needs to exist, the unit of account need not exist. For
instance, in 19th century England, many services were priced in guineas.
A guinea was a pound and a shilling, or twenty-one shillings (since
twenty shillings equaled a pound sterling). There was no single note or
coin that equaled a guinea. In the United States, the well-known saying,
"shave and a haircut, two bits" implied the shave and a
haircut would cost 250 cents. While a two bit, or 250 cents, coin
existed, there was never a 12 1/2 cents coin that equaled a single bit.
However, the absence of a coin equal to a guinea or a bit did not make
those measures any less effective or less efficient as the unit of
account.
The efficiencies that result from this "monied" exchange
over barter are many. The "buying" pharmacy is able to acquire
a product needed to fill a prescription locally much faster and less
expensively than from the manufacturer. Acquiring the product locally
merely means driving to the competing pharmacy and swapping the
Prevacid[TM] for the desired product. This transaction need not be
completed by a registered pharmacist, but can be handled by a less
expensive employee, such as a pharmacy technician. While Prevacid[TM] is
dispensed only by prescription, it is not a controlled substance, such
as Ritalin[TM] or Oxycontin[TM]. With little or no street value, there
is little threat the pharmacy technician would be tempted to steal the
Prevacid[TM] in order to sell it illegally on the street. In addition,
with little or no street value, there is no need to provide the
significant security (at a significant cost) that would be required if
controlled substances or cash were being transported. The
"buying" pharmacy may find itself temporarily with an excess
inventory of Prevacid[TM]. However, this excess supply is easily
ameliorated by reducing the amount of Prevacid[TM] on the next order.
OTHER EXAMPLES OF COMMODITY MONEY
The classic example of a commodity evolving into a medium of
exchange is the use of cigarettes in prisoner of war (POW) camps in
Germany during World War II, as described by Radford (1945). Prisoners
traded items from Red Cross packages, such as canned milk, chocolate,
canned meat and cigarettes. Rather than engage in barter to exchange
unwanted items for those items they preferred, POWs began accepting
cigarettes in exchange. Cigarettes, once accepted, met the minimal
criteria for a medium of exchange. They were of small enough value
individually that further divisibility was not required. Cigarettes also
"maintained their value," which is to say, they did not spoil.
While the multiple exchanges from buyer to seller would certainly have
reduced the value of a traded cigarette as a smoke, Gresham's Law
insured that only the cigarettes that were least desirable as a smoke
were used as a medium of exchange. Since the lower quality cigarettes
were used as money, the cigarettes' loss of value as an intrinsic
commodity was minimized.
Senn (1951) describes how cigarettes also served as money in
post-war Germany, specifically from 1946 through 1948. Currency
conversion between the dollar and Reichmarks (as well as between the
English pound and the Reichmark) was arbitrarily established at a
non-equilibrium exchange rate. The occupation army, mainly American and
British soldiers, had no incentive to lose purchasing power by
converting their pay into local currency. They used their cigarette
ration to acquire cigarettes, which they then traded with locals.
Because of the small value of cigarettes, cognac also emerged as money,
but with a much higher denomination than cigarettes (Friedman, 1992).
COMPARISON OF PREVACID AND OTHER COMMODITY MONIES
Gresham's Law states that bad money drives out good money. For
instance, the introduction of the silver-copper sandwich dimes and
quarters in the United States caused the pure silver coins to be pulled
from circulation. The pure silver coins were worth more than their face
value. Likewise, as POWs received cigarettes of various quality, with
the cigarettes that were used in exchange (acted as money) were those
cigarettes least desirable to enjoy as a smoke. Thus, you had two
classes of cigarettes, those that were smoked and those that were used
as money in exchange. However, the value of cigarettes in exchange was
all the same. The Prevacid[TM] tablets are all of equal quality, having
all been manufactured under strict controls, so there is no quality
difference between those dispensed in a prescription and those that are
used as money. Thus, there is no display of Gresham's Law in action
with this commodity money.
CONCLUSION
In the situations described above, a commodity emerged as money to
facilitate transactions. Barter was always an option, but a medium of
exchange removed the requirement of simultaneous reciprocal wants. The
use of "money" (either dollars, cigarettes or Prevacid[TM])
increased the efficiency of the transaction.
There are numerous examples of barter in today's economy. The
internet makes it easier to find a partner to complete a trade. They are
particularly helpful in facilitating transactions among multiple
participants. Assume seller 1 wants to exchange product A for product B,
and seller 2 wants to exchange product B for product C. The internet
barter sites can find seller 3 that wants product A in exchange for
product C. If necessary, the sites will find the fourth, or fifth, or
sixth, etc., trader required to complete the transaction. The more
convoluted the barter arrangement, the more you appreciate some item (or
commodity) serving as money.
For a single good to evolve into money, as Prevacid[TM] has done
among the pharmacists, the market must have several characteristics.
First, the more generic the goods are that are bought and sold, the more
likely a single item will emerge as money. The generic nature of the
traded goods makes pricing more straight forward. The money good itself
must also be commonly used by the market members. For instance, big-box
building supply companies (such as Home Depot and Lowes) could use 2x4s
as the medium of exchange, since the boards are commonly sold by both
companies and are indistinguishable. Shirts, on the other hand, would
not serve well as money for clothing stores because the different sizes
and styles. Other desired characteristics of a medium of exchange
include value and portability, which is why a currency based on 2x4s
probably will not emerge. If Lowes needed a particular refrigerator from
Home Depot, it would require a considerable quantity of 2x4s to have an
equivalent value. The exchange would be quite labor intensive, and thus,
quite expensive with regard to transaction costs. Diamonds are a high
value to weight item that could serve as money for jewelers. However,
the value of individual diamonds depends on cut, color, clarity and
carat weight, which makes them less generic. Also, the item sold in
jewelry stores vary greatly, with many necklaces or rings being quite
unique. In addition, the high street value of diamonds suggests the
courier could be tempted to steal the diamonds and/or risk being robbed.
The pharmacy setting seems to be rather unique in that it seems to
satisfy all of these criteria, which would explain why an alternative
money has evolved in this market and not others.
Another factor that makes the emergence of Prevacid[TM] money note
worthy is that it emerged in a market that had a functioning fiat money.
(Post-war Germany's Reichmark was a fiat money, but the non-market
mandated exchange rate between the Reichmark and the dollar or pound
prevented the Reichmark from functioning efficiently.) In addition,
while cigarettes in the POW camp or post-war Germany were accepted in
numerous markets for many items, Prevacid[TM] is exchanged only for
other prescription pharmaceuticals and only in a specific geographic
market. However, in this specific market, Prevacid[TM] is more efficient
than fiat money in funding these interpharmacy exchanges, and as such,
replaces the dollar as money for these transactions.
ACKNOWLEDGMENT
The author would like to acknowledge the invaluable assistance
provided by Bryan Pinckney White, a student at the University of Georgia
College of Pharmacy. His technical knowledge of the pharmaceutical
industry and retail pharmacy made this paper possible.
REFERENCES
Bade, Robin & Michael Parkin (2007) Foundations of
Macroeconomics, Boston: Addison Wesley Publishers.
Baumol, William J. & Alan S. Blinder (2009) Economics:
Principles and Policy, 11th Edition, Mason, OH: SouthWestern Cengage
Learning.
Friedman, Milton (1994) Money Mischief, Harvest Book, San Diego,
CA: Harcourt Brace and Company.
Mankiw, N. Gregory (2009) Principles of Economics, 5th Edition,
Mason, OH: SouthWestern Cengage Learning.
Radford, R.A. (1945) "The Economic Organisation of a P.O.W.
Camp," Economica, 12(48), 189-201.
Senn, Peter (1951) "Cigarettes as Money," The Journal of
Finance, 6(3), 329-332
John B. White, United States Coast Guard Academy