首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月25日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The impact of dominant religion on international trade.
  • 作者:Lewer, Joshua J.
  • 期刊名称:Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research
  • 印刷版ISSN:1533-3604
  • 出版年度:2005
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:The DreamCatchers Group, LLC
  • 摘要:The destruction of New York's World Trade Center by religious fanatics on September 11, 2001 led many commentators to question whether religion and globalization are compatible. The relationship is complicated by its theoretical ambiguity: religion can both enhance and suppress economic activity in general, and its potential network effect can both create and divert trade. There have been few empirical studies to shed light on the matter, however. This paper fills this void by examining the empirical relationship between religion and international trade.
  • 关键词:Economic conditions;International trade;Religion

The impact of dominant religion on international trade.


Lewer, Joshua J.


ABSTRACT

The destruction of New York's World Trade Center by religious fanatics on September 11, 2001 led many commentators to question whether religion and globalization are compatible. The relationship is complicated by its theoretical ambiguity: religion can both enhance and suppress economic activity in general, and its potential network effect can both create and divert trade. There have been few empirical studies to shed light on the matter, however. This paper fills this void by examining the empirical relationship between religion and international trade.

AN INTRODUCTION TO THE AMBIGUOUS ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF RELIGION

Religion is an institution that guides general economic behavior, and it therefore also affects the important economic activity of international trade. Religions often promote "economically-friendly" behavior, such as honesty, diligence, and the provision of public goods. But, because religions focus on spiritual issues rather than the "pursuit of happiness," they may also suppress people's motivation to engage in welfare-enhancing economic transactions. Religion's overall influence on trade-enhancing institutions is, therefore, ambiguous. (Iannaconne, 1998) observes in his survey of the literature on religion and economic activity that "religion seems to matter, but its impact is far from uniform." Iannaccone's survey also reveals how sparse the research on this issue is. How religion influences the institutions that directly affect international trade has not been systematically examined by economists.

Religion may also have a network effect that facilitates complex economic transactions among people in different countries. Religion's role in creating international trade networks has been investigated by (Greif, 1989; Grief, 1994; Rauch, 1999; Rauch, 2001; Rauch & Trindade, 1999). The sharing of religious beliefs can mitigate problems such as adverse selection, moral hazard, and default. Therefore, religion can facilitate complex economic transactions among people in different countries. These network effects of religion are not necessarily favorable to increased international trade, however. Networks can divert trade as well as create trade. Furthermore, networks may hinder the long-run growth of trade by limiting the entry of new participants and the inclusion of new products. Recent works by (Mokyr, 1990; Holmes & Schmitz, 1995; Parente & Prescott, 2000) showed that vested interests often obstruct competition and economic change, suggesting that networks may serve to protect certain participants from competition from those outside their network.

TESTING THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN RELIGION AND TRADE USING THE GRAVITY MODEL

These ambiguous theoretical results signal the need for an empirical study of religion's effects on international trade. In order to test the institutional and network effects of religion on trade, an augmented gravity model is applied. The gravity model normally explains 70 percent or more of the cross section variation in world trade volumes, and it has proven useful for examining the importance of potential influences on trade. The model is theoretically attractive because it can be derived from a number of traditional trade models; see (Linnemann, 1966; Leamer & Stern, 1970; Anderson, 1979; Deardorff, 1998).

The standard gravity equation specifies trade between a pair of countries to be a negative function of the distance between the countries and a positive function of their combined national products. This equation is usually augmented to account for geographic, ethno-linguistic, and economic conditions. A common form of the gravity model is

(1) [tot.sub.ij] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1](gd[p.sub.i]gd[p.sub.j]) + [a.sub.2](po[p.sub.i] po[p.sub.j]) + [a.sub.3][dist.sub.ij] + [a.sub.4][CONT.sub.ij] + [a.sub.5][LANG.sub.ij] + [a.sub.6][FTA.sub.ij] + [u.sub.ij],

in which [tot.sub.ij] is the log of bilateral trade between countries i and j, gd[p.sub.i]gd[p.sub.j] is the log of GDP for i and j, [dist.sub.ij] is the log of geographic distance between i and j, [pop.sub.i] [pop.sub.j] is the log of the product of the populations in country i and j, and CONT, LANG, and FTA are dummy variables for pairs of countries that have a contiguous border, a common language, and are members of the same active free trade area, respectively. For recent gravity studies see, for example, (Frankel, Stein & Wei, 1995; McCallum, 1995; Eichengreen & Irwin, 1996; Deardorff, 1998; Frankel & Romer, 1999; Freund, 2000; Freund & Weinhold, 2000; Frankel & Rose, 2002).

ADDING RELIGION VARIABLES TO THE GRAVITY EQUATION

For religion to substantially influence a country's institutions, it must be a dominant religion. Minor religions adhered to by a few people are unlikely to have much effect on a country's overall economic institutions and, hence, its aggregate level of international trade. A dominant religion can be defined as one that is followed by at least 75 percent of the country's population. Religion's network effect depends on whether people in different countries share the same religion. Therefore, to distinguish between religion's influence on trade through the institutional channel and the network channel, three dummy variables are introduced into the augmented gravity equation: DOM for each pair of countries in which one trade partner has a dominant religion, DIFDOM when trade partners both have dominant, but different, religions, and SAMEDOM for country pairs in which both countries have the same dominant religion. If a dominant religion's influence on a country's institutions has a general effect on its ability to engage in international trade, then the DOM and DIFDOM dummies should be significantly positive, with the latter being greater in magnitude than DOM. If the sharing of the same dominant religion has a positive network effect, then SAMEDOM dummy should be significantly positive.

In recognition of potential omitted variable bias, several institutional and network variables are added to equation (1): a dummy (LAWij) to capture the network effect of having a common legal structure using data from (Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silane & Shleifer, 2002), the bi-lateral average of (Kaufmann, Kraay & Zoido Lobaton's, 1999) government regulation variable ([burden.sub.ij]) to capture other institutional effects, and two communications channels, [cyber.sub.i][cyber.sub.j] and [phone.sub.i][phone.sub.j], the log of the bilateral product of top domain web hosts and telephones per thousand in countries i and j, respectively [See data sources in the Appendix]. This leaves the extended gravity model:

(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

REGRESSION RESULTS

Most studies estimate the gravity equation (2) in double logarithmic form so that the estimated coefficients can be interpreted as elasticities. This technique omits country pairs whose bilateral trade is zero, or about twenty percent of the observations in this study. Omitting these observations biases the results. Therefore, the scaled OLS (SOLS) technique first used by (Eichengreen & Irwin, 1995), in which the dependent variable is expressed as log(1 + [TRADE.sub.ij]). (Greene, 2003) shows that the transformed variable approximates a "semi-log Tobit relationship;" for small values of [TRADE.sub.ij] the logarithm is close to zero, and for large values of [TRADE.sub.ij] the logarithm of the transformed variable is close to the logarithm of [TRADE.sub.ij]. This approach yields results that are similar to those for a Tobit regression, and the double log form is maintained.

To check for estimation robustness, equation (2) is also estimated using nonlinear least squares technique similar to that applied by (Coe & Hoffmaister, 1999; Coe, Subramanian & Tamarisa, 2002). This method essentially changes the equation into an exponential form, and by not actually putting the data in logarithmic form we can include the observations for which trade is zero.

Column 2 in Table 1 presents the SOLS results for the baseline gravity model using data on the bilateral trade volumes between 84 countries during the year 1998. As is common for gravity models, nearly 80 percent of the variation in bilateral trade is explained. All signs are as expected and significant at the 95 percent level. Nonlinear estimates converted to be compatible with the logarithmic results of the SOLS regressions are given in Column 5; the similarity between columns 2 and 5 adds robustness to the results.

Columns 3 and 6 in Table 1 present the results for regression equation (2). All coefficients except DOM are significant and compatible with the baseline gravity model regression. The coefficient for DOM is positive but small and not statistically significant; the coefficient for DIFDOM is significant using SOLS and equal to !0.314, which implies that, all other things equal, two countries with different dominant religions trade 31 percent less. Finally, the SAMEDOM coefficient tells us that when two countries share the same dominant religion, then all other things equal they trade 38 percent less. These results suggest that the presence of a dominant religion has no institutional effect, or possibly a negative institutional effect, on trade. The negative SAMEDOM coefficient suggests that the network effects related to countries' sharing of religious institutions cause more trade diversion than trade creation.

THE TRADE IMPACT OF SPECIFIC RELIGIONS

The gravity model can be extended further to distinguish the impact of specific dominant religions on trade flows. By adding dummies for specific dominant religions (DOM) and shared dominant religions (SAME), the regression model becomes:

(3) [tot.sub.ij] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1]([gdp.sub.i][gdp.sub.j]) + [a.sub.2]([pop.sub.i] [pop.sub.j]) + [a.sub.3][dist.sub.ij] + [a.sub.4][CONT.sub.ij] + [a.sub.5][LANG.sub.ij] + [a.sub.6][FTA.sub.ij] + [a.sub.7][LAW.sub.ij] + [a.sub.8]([burden.sub.ij]) + [a.sub.9]([cyber.sub.i][cyber.sub.j]) + [a.sub.10]([phone.sub.i][phone.sub.j]) + [a.sub.11](DOMBuddhist) + [a.sub.12](DOMCatholic) + [a.sub.13](DOMHindu) + [a.sub.14](DOMJudaism) + [a.sub.15](DOMMuslim) + [a.sub.16](DOMProtestant) + [a.sub.17](SAMEBuddhist) + [a.sub.18](SAMECatholic) + [a.sub.19](SAMEHindu) + [a.sub.20](SAMEMuslim) + [a.sub.21](SAMEOrthodox) + [a.sub.22](SAMEProtestant) + [u.sub.ij].

Estimation results for equation (3) are found in columns 4 and 7 in Table 1. The results indicate that when Catholic, Hindu, Judaism, Muslim, or Protestant religions are dominant, trade is reduced. The dominance of the Orthodox religion has an insignificantly positive institutional effect, and only Buddhism has a significantly positive institutional effect on trade. The network effects of individual religions are mostly insignificant. However, when countries share the Orthodox and Buddhist religions, trade is enhanced. Catholicism has a negative network effect.

CONCLUSIONS

Is religion compatible with globalization? The evidence from the regressions relating dominant religions and international trade suggests that dominant religion seems to have negative effect on trade. Focusing on individual religions reveals that most religions discourage trade. An exception is Buddhism, whose institutional and network effects both seem to encourage trade.

DATA APPENDIX

Bilateral trade data are from the International Monetary Fund's Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook, 2000 (IMF, Washington, D.C.). Gross Domestic Product in millions of U.S. dollars, population, telephone lines per 1,000 people, free trade areas, and number of top domain internet hosts per 1,000 people are from the World Bank's 2001 World Development Indicators (World Bank, Washington D.C.). Distance (kilometers between capital cities) is from the U.S. Geological Survey (ftp://kai.er.usgs.gov/pub/). Common borders, common languages, and fraction of population claiming adherence to religions are from the CIA World Factbook 2000, (http://www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook/).

REFERENCES

Anderson, J.E. (1979). A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. American Economic Review, 69(1), 106-116.

Coe, D.T. & A.W. Hoffmaister (1999). North-south trade: Is Africa unusual? Journal of African Economics, 8(2), 228-256.

Coe, D.T., A. Subramanian & N.T. Tamirisa (2002). The missing globalization puzzle. IMF Working Paper, No. 171.

Deardorff, A. (1998). Determinants of bilateral trade: Does gravity work in a classical world? in: J.A. Frankel, (Ed.) Regionalization of the world economy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 7-22.

Djankov, S., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silane & Andrei Shleifer (2002). Courts: The lex mundi project. NBER Working Paper, No. 8890.

Eichengreen, B. & D.A. Irwin (1995). Trade blocs, currency blocs and the reorientation of world trade in the 1930s. Journal of International Economics, 38(1), 1-24.

Eichengreen, B. & D.A. Irwin (1996). The role of history in bilateral trade flows. NBER Working Paper, No. w5565.

Frankel, J.A. & D. Romer (1999). Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review, 89(3), 379-399.

Frankel, J.A. & A. Rose (2002). An estimate of the effect of common currencies on trade and income. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2), 437-466.

Frankel, J.A., E. Stein & Shang-Jin Wei (1995). Trading blocs and the Americas. Journal of Development Economics, 47(1), 61-95.

Freund, C. (2000). Different paths to free trade: The gains from regionalism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4), 1317-1341.

Freund, C. & D. Weinhold (2000). On the effects of the internet on international trade. International Finance Discussion Paper 693, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Greene, W.H. (2003). Econometric analysis (Fifth edition). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders. Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 857-882.

Greif, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies. Journal of Political Economy, 102(5), 912-950.

Holmes, T. & J. Schmitz Jr. (1995). Resistance to new technology and trade between areas. Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Iannaccone, L.R. (1998). Introduction to the economics of religion. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(3), 1465-1495.

Kaufmann, D.,A. Kraay & P. Zoido Lobaton (1999). Aggregating governance indicators. World Bank Working Paper, No. 2195.

Leamer E.E. & R.M. Stern (1970). Quantitative international economics. Boston, MA: Allyn and Bacon Publishers.

Linnemann, H. (1966). An econometric study of international trade flows. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

McCallum, J. (1995). National borders matter: Canada-US regional trade patterns. American Economic Review, 85(3), 615-623.

Mokyr, J. (1990). The lever of riches. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Parente, S.L. & E.C. Prescott (2000). Barriers to riches. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Rauch, J.E. (1999). Networks versus markets in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 48(1), 7-35.

Rauch, J.E. (2001). Business and social networks. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), 1177-1203.

Rauch, J.E. & V. Trindade (1999). Ethnic Chinese networks in international trade. Review of Economics and Statistics, 48(1), 7-35.

Joshua J. Lewer, West Texas A&M University
Table 1: The Gravity Model and Dominant Religions

 Equation Equation Equation
 (1) SOLS (2) SOLS (3) SOLS

Constant -6.695 -4.883 -4.714
 (-24.62) ** (-14.99) ** (-14.10) **
[gdp.sub.i][gdp.sub.j] 0.687 0.666 0.668
 (75.78) ** (30.87) ** (29.34) **
[pop.sub.i] [pop.sub.j] -0.072 -0.101 -0.111
 (-5.81) ** (-4.09) ** (-4.26) **
[dist.sub.ij] -0.594 -0.689 -0.696
 (-24.61) ** (-28.02) ** (-27.73) **
CON[T.sub.ij] 0.759 0.59 0.575
 (6.83) ** (5.49) ** (5.32) **
LAN[G.sub.ij] 0.521 0.243 0.305
 (7.72) ** (3.24) ** (4.02) **
FT[A.sub.ij] 0.475 0.293 0.282
 (8.47) ** (5.29) ** (5.03) **
DO[M.sub.ij] 0.049
 (1.02)
SAME -0.372
DO[M.sub.ij] (-5.26) **
DIFDO[M.sub.ij] -0.314
 (-5.78) **
LA[W.sub.ij] 0.365 0.354
 (7.96) ** (7.61) **
[burden.sub.ij] 0.282 0.366
 (4.34) ** (5.54) **
[cyber.sub.i]- 0.081 0.087
 [cyber.sub.j] (8.28) ** (8.23) **
[phone.sub.i] -0.188 -0.215
 [phone.sub.j] (-7.59) ** (-8.23) **
DOM 0.356
Buddhist (3.47) **
DOM -0.157
Catholic (-3.04) **
DOM -0.386
Hindu (-3.17) **
DOM -0.331
Judaism (-1.86) *
DOM -0.119
Muslim (-1.72) *
DOM 0.024
Orthodox (0.26)
DOM -0.019
Protestant (-2.56) **
SAME 0.660
Buddhist (2.11) **
SAME -0.265
Catholic (-3.33) **
SAME 0.802
Hindu (0.78)
SAME -0.042
Muslim (-0.21)
SAME 0.878
Orthodox (2.62) **
SAME 0.005
Protestant (0.02)
[R.sup.2] 0.783 0.800 0.800

 Equation (1) Equation (2) Equation (3)
 Nonlinear Nonlinear Nonlinear

Constant -7.674 -6.777 -6.703
 (-18.17)** (-10.39)** (-10.56)**
[gdp.sub.i][gdp.sub.j] 0.851 0.861 0.895
 (43.09) ** (13.19) ** (11.94) **
[pop.sub.i] [pop.sub.j] -0.061 -0.137 -0.178
 (-1.43) (-1.49) (-1.82) *
[dist.sub.ij] -0.526 -0.596 -0.501
 (-21.06) ** (-19.79) ** (-13.76) **
CON[T.sub.ij] 1.207 1.042 1.069
 (6.69) ** (5.46) ** (5.48) **
LAN[G.sub.ij] 0.457 0.348 0.420
 (3.92) ** (2.50) ** (2.83) **
FT[A.sub.ij] 0.473 0.362 0.344
 (4.17) ** (3.17) ** (2.48) **
DO[M.sub.ij] -0.140
 (-1.08)
SAME -0.126
DO[M.sub.ij] (-2.75) **
DIFDO[M.sub.ij] -0.043
 (-0.22)
LA[W.sub.ij] 0.467 0.451
 (6.13) ** (5.08) **
[burden.sub.ij] 0.347 0.592
 -1.32 (2.11) **
[cyber.sub.i]- 0.105 0.107
 [cyber.sub.j] (3.14) ** (2.28) **
[phone.sub.i] -0.259 -0.328
 [phone.sub.j] (-3.55) ** (-2.95) **
DOM 0.421
Buddhist (2.39) **
DOM -0.327
Catholic (-2.57) **
DOM -0.476
Hindu (-2.56) **
DOM -0.294
Judaism (-0.58)
DOM -0.174
Muslim (-0.94)
DOM 0.155
Orthodox (0.61)
DOM -0.310
Protestant (-2.14) **
SAME 0.625
Buddhist (0.62)
SAME -0.101
Catholic (-0.37)
SAME 0.825
Hindu (1.44)
SAME -0.039
Muslim (-0.07)
SAME 1.111
Orthodox (2.34) **
SAME 0.280
Protestant (0.52)
[R.sup.2] 0.816 0.823 0.834

** indicates significant at the 95% level, and * at the 90% level.
With 84 countries, there are 3486 data points (=84*(83/2)). Dominant
Buddist countries are Japan and Thailand, dominant Catholic countries
are Argentina, Austria, Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia,
Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, France,
Guatemala, Honduras, Ireland, Italy, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama,
Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Portugal, Spain, and Venezuela,
dominant Hindu countries are India and Nepal, the dominant Judaic
country is Israel, dominant Muslim countries are Algeria, Bangladesh,
Indonesia, Iran, Mauritania, Saudi Arabia, Tunisia, and Turkey,
dominant Orthodox countries are Belarus, Georgia, Greece, Moldova, and
Ukraine, dominant Protestant countries are Denmark, Estonia, Finland,
Norway, Sweden, and the United Kingdom..

Notes: Figures in parentheses are heteroskedasticity-consistent
t-statistics.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有