Measuring shocks to exchange rate under floating regime.
Brahmasrene, Tantatape ; Jiranyakul, Komain
ABSTRACT
The effect of nominal and real shocks to real exchange rates under
floating exchange rate system was examined. The real exchange rates in
this study were measured in terms of domestic currency relative to the
U.S. dollar. Thailand was used as an event study during the economic
crisis. Ever since the floating exchange rate system was in effect in
the third quarter of 1997, some policymakers have called for policies
designed to keep the exchange rate within the target range. A vector
autoregression (VAR) was employed to investigate the joint behavior of
real and nominal exchange rates in order to identify the nominal and
real shocks that caused fluctuations in the real exchange rate. Based
upon the results of a bivariate VAR model, the impulse response functions showed that real shocks had a thriving impact on changes in
real exchange rates in the twelve- month forecast horizon. Furthermore,
variance decompositions revealed that real shocks were much more robust
than nominal shocks during the period under study.
INTRODUCTION
At the pinnacle of the Southeast Asian economic crisis, nominal and
real shocks that affect real exchange rate have become more prevalent in
macroeconomic policy analysis. Nominal shocks are typically referred to
a shock from monetary policy, while real shocks stem from economic
fundamentals, such as changes in preferences, productivity, and
inflation expectations. If the real shocks to real exchange rate
dominate nominal shocks, monetary policy measures alone cannot be used
to cope with fluctuations in the real exchange rate, especially in the
long run. Nominal exchange rate in Thailand had long been pegged, with
occasional interrupting devaluation until the second quarter of 1997.
The gradual decline in international reserves coupled with the attack on
domestic currency (Thai baht) by speculators forced the Bank of Thailand to float the exchange rate. After entering the floating exchange rate
regime, the nominal exchange rate in terms of baht per U.S. dollars
depreciated sharply until the end of 1997. Consequently, data from Bank
of Thailand (2002) showed that the net flows of portfolio investment,
especially investment in equity securities, substantially decreased in
1998. Furthermore, short-term external debts gradually fell from 1997 to
2001. These events might be attributed to the short-run exchange rate
risk faced by local and foreign economic agents. In early 1998, the baht
began to appreciate and accelerated by the end of the year. In recent
years, the nominal exchange rate has fluctuated to a lesser extent with
an upward trend. This substantially improved the trade balance. Thus,
the country has begun to experience a trade surplus.
According to international finance literature (Gan, 1994),
movements in the real exchange rate can be viewed as a random walk
process during a period of floating nominal exchange rate. Short-term
capital flows can cause exchange rate volatility. This phenomenon is
common in recent developments in Asia and Latin America. Bodnar, Dumas,
and Marston (2002) found that exchange rate changes had a substantial
impact on the pricing behavior of exporting and importing firms. One
approach to alleviate exchange rate volatility is to measure and
investigate the sources of fluctuations in real and nominal exchange
rates.
REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE
The studies of movements in real exchange rates are generally
related to the notion that prices in different countries move towards
equality in common currency term. The empirical works devoted to
purchasing power parity (PPP) are motivated by the presence or absence
of unit roots in real exchange rates and cointegration between nominal
exchange rates and different measures of relative prices, such as
wholesale prices versus consumer prices. If the null hypothesis of
stationarity for the bilateral real exchange rate or real effective
exchange rate is rejected, it is unlikely that PPP will hold.
Bahmani-Oskooee (1993) and Liu (1992) presented contradictory results
regarding the validity of the PPP hypothesis. Detailed PPP puzzle can be
found in Rogoff (1996). Recently, Culver and Papell (1999) investigated
long-run Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) with short-run floating exchange
rate data by using tests where stationarity and cointegration were the
null, rather than the alternative, hypotheses. The results show that the
null hypothesis of stationarity of the real exchange rate or the
cointegration between the nominal exchange rate and the domestic and
foreign prices cannot be rejected in most cases. Therefore, there exists
the evidence of PPP. Another empirical work by Papell (1997) employed 20
observations of quarterly data from 21 countries to test for real
exchange rate stationarity. The results as a whole were consistent with
log-run PPP.
Beyond the PPP hypothesis, there are attempts to investigate the
causes of fluctuations in real exchange rates and to pinpoint the
relative importance between transitory and permanent shocks. Economic
theory does not generally offer a concrete specification of the dynamic
relationship among variables. Furthermore, the case where endogenous
variables may appear on both sides of the equations also makes the
estimation and inference more complicated. A vector autoregression (VAR)
is thus an alternative approach to deal with such problems. The three
varieties of VARs are reduced form, recursive, and structural models.
See Stock and Watson (2001) for further details. Blanchard and Quah
(1989) proposed the long-run restriction on a structural VAR that
nominal shocks have no permanent effects on the real exchange rate. This
restriction is widely used in the literature. Lastrapes (1992)
distinguishes real versus nominal sources of fluctuations in real and
nominal exchange rates under a flexible exchange rate period using the
bivariate vector autoregression (VAR) model. The restriction that
nominal shocks had no permanent effect on real exchange rate was
imposed. Using data from the United States, Germany, United Kingdom,
Japan, Italy, and Canada, the results showed that real shocks dominate
nominal shocks for both exchange rate series over short and long
frequencies. Chen and Wu (1997) used the same restriction to investigate
the relative importance between nominal and real shocks to fluctuations
in real exchange rates. Employing quarterly data from Japan, Korea,
Taiwan, and the Philippines, their findings from the long-run structural
VAR approach indicated that real shocks were more important only in two
cases, Japan and Korea. A recent study by Alexius (2001) showed that the
movements in real exchange rates in the Nordic countries were mainly due
to real supply shocks. In addition, the permanent component dominates
the variances of changes in real exchange rates in most cases.
A bivariate VAR model is applied in this paper to capture the
relationship between nominal and real exchange rates and to assess the
influence of shocks on the fluctuations of real exchange rates in
Thailand under the floating exchange rate system. This reduced form VAR
is widely used as a reliable tool in data description, and forecasting.
The VAR analysis reports results from impulse responses and forecast
error variance decompositions (Stock and Watson, 2001). The next section
deals with methodology, data description and empirical results. The
conclusions, and research and practical implications are presented in
the last section.
MODEL AND METHODOLOGY
To measure fluctuations in exchange rates, the fluctuations
affected by nominal shocks must be isolated from the part affected by
real shocks. In general, these shocks (or disturbances) are not directly
observable, but can be inferred from the joint behavior of the exchange
rate series characterized by a vector autoregression (VAR) as employed
in Lastrapes (1992), and Chen and Wu (1997). A reduced form VAR
framework is formulated with zero restrictions on the coefficients of
the lags of a subset of variables. If some restrictions are imposed,
lack of sufficient observations will not provide sufficient degrees of
freedom to obtain reliable estimates. This unrestricted VAR involves two
equations:
(1) level or first differences of real exchange rates as a function
of past values level or first differences of real and nominal
exchange rates and
(2) level or first differences of nominal exchange rates as a
function of past values of level or first differences of nominal
and real exchange rates.
In essence, a reduced form VAR representation is shown as:
(1) [q.sub.t] = [a.sub.o] + [summation.sup.k.sub.i] [a.sub.i]
[s.sub.t-i] + [summation.sup.k.sub.i] [b.sub.i] [q.sub.t-i] + [u.sub.1t]
(2) [s.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.o] + [summation.sup.k.sub.i]
[[alpha].sub.i] [s.sub.t-i] + [summation.sup.k.sub.i] [[beta].sub.i]
[q.sub.t-i] + [u.sub.2t]
where
q = s + [p.sup.*] - p
q is the level or first differences of the logarithm of the Thai
baht/U.S. dollar real exchange rates.
s is the level or first differences of the logarithm of the Thai
baht/U.S. dollar nominal exchange rates.
[p.sup.*] refers to the logarithm of U.S. wholesale price indices.
p denotes the logarithm of Thai wholesale price level.
In summary, five main procedures are undertaken:
(1) Unit Root Test
(2) Predictive Causality
(3) Variance Decompositions
(4) The Impulse-Response Functions
(5) Integrated Autoregressive Moving Average
Because VAR approach is suitable when each series is stationary,
I(0), or integrated of order one, I(1), it is imperative to test whether
each series contains a unit root in its level or first differences. The
unit root tests such as the ADF (Dickey and Fuller, 1979) and PP
(Phillips and Perron, 1988) are applied at level and first differences
of each series.
However, the most widely used VAR is based upon the condition that
economic variables are known to be integrated of order one, I(1), with
no cointegration. Therefore, unit root test is performed on both level
of and first differenced series of nominal and real exchange rates.
(2) Predictive Causality
After testing for unit root, the standard Granger-causality tests
as employed in Chow (1987) were employed to examine whether lagged
values of one variable help predict the other. If variations of nominal
exchange rates do not help predict variations of real exchange rates,
the coefficients on lags of real exchange rate series will all be zero
in the reduced-form nominal exchange rate series equation, and vice
versa.
(3) Variance Decompositions
The next step is to estimate the reduced form model in two stages:
Stage 1: each variable is regressed on its lags and past values of other
variables and, Stage 2: the Cholesky factorization technique is used to
obtain the residuals from each reduced form equation. The Cholesky
factorization of the reduced form VAR covariance matrix can be computed.
For detail discussion and derivation of this topic, see Hamiliton
(1994).
The reduced form VAR is used to generate the error terms in each
equation. These error terms are the unanticipated movements in the
variables after taking into account past values. The stochastic error
term in the first equation is monetary innovation or impulse in the
language of VAR, while one in the second equation is real innovation.
(4) The Impulse-Response Functions
In practical applications of impulse-response analysis, estimates
replace unknown parameters (Diebold, 2001). This immediately yields
point estimates of the impulse-response functions that can be shown on
graphs to ease interpretation.
(5) Integrated Autoregressive Moving Average
Moreover, the method of fitting real exchange rate changes to the
ARIMA (p, 1, q) based on Beveridge and Nelson (1981) is employed because
changing order of variables in VAR representation can alter the results.
If the real exchange rate series is I(1) process, an ARIMA model of the
first difference of the series is estimated. As a result, the importance
of real shocks using the impulse response from the simple VAR model can
be confirmed.
DATA
Data were collected from International Financial Statistics CD ROM of International Monetary Fund (IMF). They include the monthly nominal
exchange rate, which is the ratio of domestic currency to foreign
currency (Thai baht/U.S. dollar), and Thailand and the US's
wholesale price indexes (WPIs) with the base period of 1995. The
empirical analysis in the present paper is based only on short-term
series since the nominal exchange rate has just been floated in July
1997. So, data under this study ranges from July 1997 through 2002. Data
for computing effective real exchange rate are not available on the
monthly basis. Instead, the real exchange rate is computed as the
product of the nominal exchange rate and the relative price levels
between the US and Thailand, as usually defined in macroeconomic
literature such as Culver and Papell (1999). This is justified by the
fact that transactions in terms of U.S. dollars are dominant in the
global market, as U.S. dollars are widely used in all parts of the
world, including Latin America, the Middle East, and East Asia.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
(1) Unit Root Test
With a critical value of 5 percent, Table 1 shows that both ADF and
PP tests indicate nonstationarity of the log of real exchange rate (q)
at level while yielding contradictory results in the nominal exchange
rate (s) at level. However, with critical value of 10 percent, the ADF
test shows stationarity of log of real exchange rates while the PP test
rejects the null hypothesis of stationarity. The contradictory of these
two tests yields inconclusive results on real exchange rate series.
Furthermore, ADF and PP statistics show that first differences of
nominal and real exchange rate series are stationary. They are I(1), at
1 percent level of significance, according to MacKinnon critical values
(MacKinnon, 1990). In other words, the first differences of nominal and
real exchange rate series are not affected by seasonality and structural
breaks. Both series at level and first differences do not exhibit a
deterministic trend as coefficient of the trend term is insignificant.
(2) Predictive Causality
The standard Granger-causality tests were implemented in this step.
Since the series of real exchange rates is I(1), and the series of
nominal exchange rates is I(0) resulting from unit root tests with the
level of significance of 5 percent, a reduced form bivariate VAR was
performed by using first differences of real exchange rates and nominal
exchange rates at level. If variations of the nominal exchange rate at
level do not help predict variations of first differences of the real
exchange rate, the coefficients on lags of first difference real
exchange rate series will all be zeros in the reduced-form level nominal
exchange rate series equation, and vice versa.
These equations were estimated using lag lengths of 2, 4, and 6
months. However, the lag length of 6 provided the best estimates of
coefficient from causality test under Akaike Information criterion (AIC,
see Pindyck and Rubinfeld, 1997). The results of the standard Granger
causality tests showed bi-directional causation between the two series.
This implied that level of nominal exchange rates caused changes in real
exchange rates at 1 percent level of significance, and changes in real
exchange rates caused level of nominal exchange rates at 5 percent level
of significance. In other words, the series of level nominal exchange
rates help predict the series of changes in real exchange rates, and the
series of changes in real exchange rates also help predict the series of
level nominal exchange rates.
(3) Variance Decompositions
Variance decompositions and impulse response function using the lag
length of four according to AIC criterion are described below.
Table 2 presents the variance decompositions of changes in real
exchange rates and the level of nominal exchange rates. The results give
the fraction of the forecast error variance for each variable that is
attributable to its own innovations and to innovations in another
variable. The forecast error variances are reported for forecast
horizons over twelve months. Two columns under (a) of Table 2 shows
within the first two months, 96.168 percent of the error in the forecast
of changes in the real exchange rate is due to real shocks ( q). When
compared with six and twelve months, the percentages of forecast error
increase to 95.479 and 95.327 percent, respectively. In Table 2, the
last two columns under (b) also reports the variance decompositions of
level nominal exchange rate due to real ( q) and nominal shocks (s). The
forecast error variances for level nominal exchange rate are similar to
shocks to real exchange rate changes, but with a somewhat higher
percentage point. For example, within the first two months, 96.861
percent of the error in the forecast of level nominal exchange rates is
due to real shocks. The percentages of forecast error increase to 97.066
and 96.423 percent in 6 and 12 months, respectively. The salient feature
of the variance decomposition results is that the predominant source of
fluctuations in real exchange rate changes and level nominal exchange
rates is due to real shock.
(4) The Impulse-Response Functions
The impulse-response function is another device of interest to
forecasters that verifies the dynamic properties of VAR. Hence, they are
reported in Figures 1 and 2.
[FIGURES 1-2 OMITTED]
Figure 1 shows impulse responses that trace out the responses of
current and future values of real exchange rate changes to a one-unit
increase in the current value of real and nominal shocks. In view of the
fact that the reduced form VAR model is estimated in first differences
of real exchange rates but at level of nominal exchange rates, a
one-time shock to its first differences is a permanent shock to its
level. A nominal shock to the real exchange rates seems to dissipate within 12 month forecast horizon while a real shock still causes
fluctuations in changes in the real exchange rate. The finding indicates
that even though initial responses of changes in the real exchange rate
to real shocks have a strong positive effect, a negative effect can be
observed within two months and thereafter. Figure 2 confirms that real
shocks as compared with nominal shocks clearly cause more variations in
the nominal exchange rate.
(5) Integrated Autoregressive Moving Average
The result of fitted and actual first differences of real exchange
rates is shown in Figure 3. Figure 3 shows that the fitted and actual
first differences of the real exchange rate move closely in concert. The
maximum variations vary from about 0.08 to -0.14.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In addition, using Beveridge and Nelson's (1981) technique,
the ARIMA (6, 1, 0) is found to be the most suitable model for the first
differences of the exchange rate series. Figure 4 shows the
impulse-responses from the ARIMA (6, 1, 0) model. The response of
changes in the real exchange rates to real shocks is quite similar to
what depicted in Figure 1.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
CONCLUSIONS
In retrospect, it has long been recognized in the international
finance literature that the domestic currency should be pegged to the
U.S. dollar or to a basket of hard foreign currencies so as to avoid
excessive instability and to attract foreign capital into the country.
However, if the banking sector is poorly supervised, capital inflows for
bank lending to business under the pegged exchange rate regime can be
large and over-investment or over-consumption can be the consequences.
Careless short term bank lending can essentially be problematic. When
there are large outflows of capital, this can harm the country by
depleting its international reserves, especially, the amount of U.S.
dollars at the Bank of Thailand. Control on inflows can be fruitful in
that it protects the country from the vulnerability to sudden reversals
of capital flows and diminish vulnerability to speculative attack.
As one of the hardest hit countries from the Asian crisis, the real
exchange rate had sharply depreciated during the last two quarters of
1997. This drastic depreciation of baht against U.S. dollar caused
uncertainty in both exports and imports. Moreover, there is a large
discrepancy between estimated and actual values of the balance of trade
at that time. Exchange rate instability typically occurs as nation
enters into the floating exchange rate regime as Thailand experienced in
mid-1997. Therefore, the sources of exchange rate fluctuations should be
identified and monitored.
Contributions
(1) The importance of identifying the sources of exchange rate
fluctuations is that the validity of PPP can be established (Chen and
Wu, 1997). The most appropriate approach to the estimation of exchange
rate determination relies on the validity of the PPP theory. The PPP
theory is valid when the real exchange rate series is stationary.
Otherwise, cointegration between nominal exchange rate and the relative
prices should be obtained. According to these tests performed, the level
nominal exchange rate and the first difference of real exchange rate
series yielded the best fit for VAR under this event study.
(2) Most research on sources of real exchange rate fluctuations
finds mixed results of the role of nominal shocks compared to that of
real shocks. This study confirms the crucial role of real shocks to real
exchange rate. According to the Purchasing Power Parity (PPP), real
shocks have permanent effects on the observed real exchange rate in the
long run. However, nominal shocks might be able to explain real exchange
rate fluctuations in the short and intermediate terms. The crucial role
of real shocks to changes in real exchange rate movement was observed.
(3) Moreover, this study represented a model of short-run
exploration of the issue concerning shocks to real exchange rates
because only data from mid-1997 to 2002 are available as a
representation of floating regime.
(4) VAR model was used to investigate nominal and real shocks to
changes in real and level nominal exchange rates measured in terms of
U.S. dollar. The results concluded that changes in real exchange rate
movements and the level nominal exchange rate were mainly caused by real
shocks during the period under investigation.
Research Implications
Given these findings, yet there is room for future research to
identify key sources and treatment of real shocks. There should also be
more studies across national markets for generalization of these
results. Such research will contribute significantly toward our
understanding of how policy makers deal with a phenomenon of unstable
exchange rates that comes with increased globalization.
Practical Implications
The results in this study also provide a clear policy implication.
Like other developing countries, authorities in Thailand should not be
complacent with exchange rate movements. The government in concert with
the central bank should take certain measures to minimize the real
exchange rate fluctuations that can disrupt economic decision-making,
especially those in the foreign sector of the economy. Nevertheless,
extra bank reserve could be accumulated by the central bank. In view of
the fact that exercising monetary measures alone may not be adequate to
maintain real exchange rate stability, attention to economic
fundamentals such as changes in productivity, inflation expectations and
preference should also be included as part of the stabilization package.
ACKNOWLEDGMENT
The authors gratefully acknowledge the helpful suggestions received
when an earlier version of this paper was presented at the Allied
Academies International Conference, October 2002; Northeast Business
& Economics Association 29th Annual Conference, September 2002; and
Hong Kong Economics Association Conference, December 2002.
REFERENCES
Alexius, A. (2001). Sources of Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations in
the Nordic Countries. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103, 317-331.
Bahmanee-Oskooee, M. (1993). Purchasing Power Parity Based on
Effective Change Rate and Cointegration: 25 LDCs' Experience with
Its Absolute Formulation. World Development, 21, 1023-1031.
Bank of Thailand (2002). Economic and Financial Statistics, 42.
Beveridge, S. & C. R. Nelson (1981). A New Approach to
Decomposition of Economic Time Series into Permanent and Transitory
Components with Particular attention to Measurement of the
'Business Cycle'. Journal of Monetary Economics, 7, 151-174.
Blanchard, O. J. & D. Quah (1989). The Dynamic Effect of
Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturbances. American Economic Review, 79,
655-673.
Bodnar, G. M, B. Dumas & R. C. Marston (2002). Pass-through and
Exposure. Journal of Finance, 57, 199-231.
Chen, S. & J. Wu (1997). Sources of Real Exchange-Rate
Fluctuations: Empirical Evidence from Four Pacific Basin Countries.
Southern Economic Journal, 63, 776-787.
Chow, G. C. Y. (1987). Causality between Export Growth and
Industrial Development: Empirical Evidence From NICs. Journal of
Development Economics, 26, 55-63.
Culver, S. E. & D. H. Papell (1999). Long-run Purchasing Power
Parity with Short-Run Data: Evidence with a Null Hypothesis of
Stationarity. Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 751-768.
Dickey, D. A. & A. W. Fuller (1979). Distribution of Estimators
for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Journal of American
Statistical Association, 74, 427-431.
Diebold, F. X. (2001). Elements of Forecasting (Second Edition).
Cincinnati, OH: South Western.
Gan, W.B. (1994). Characterizing Real Exchange Rate Behavior of
Selected East Asian Economies. Journal of Economic Development, 19,
67-92.
Hamilton, J.D. (1994). Time Series Analysis. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Lastrapes, W. D. (1992). Sources of Fluctuations in Real and
Nominal Exchange Rates. Review of Economics and Statistics, 530-539.
Liu, P. C. (1992). Purchasing Power Parity in Latin America: A
Co-integration Analysis. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 128, 662-680.
MacKinnon, J. G. (1990). Critical Values for Cointegration Tests.
In by R. F. Engle, and C. W. J. Granger (Eds.), Long-Run Economic
Relationship: Readings in Cointegration (pp. 267-276). Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Papell, D. H. (1997). Searching for Stationarity: Purchasing Power
Parity Under the Current Float. Journal of International Economics, 43,
313-332.
Phillips, P.C. B. & P. Perron (1988). Testing for a Unit Root
in Time Series Regression. Biometrika, 335-346.
Pindyck, R.S. & Rubinfeld, D.L. (1997). Econometric Model and
Economic Forecasts. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Rogoff, K. (1996). The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle. Journal of
Economic Literature, 34, 647-668.
Stocks, J.H. & M. W. Watson (2001). Vector Autoregressions.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 101-115.
Tantatape Brahmasrene, Purdue University North Central Komain
Jiranyakul, National Institute of Development
Table 1: Unit Root Tests for Nominal and Real Exchange Rates
ADF Test PP Test
Variables No Trend Trend No Trend Trend
Log of s -3.223 * -3.434 -3.266 * -3.277
Log of q -2.611 -2.851 -2.485 -2.633
Log of s -5.635 * -5.614 * -6.407 * -6.377 *
Log of q -5.952 * -5.917 * -6.847 * -6.805 *
Critical Value at 5% -2.912 -3.486 -2.911 -3.486
Note: * significance at 5 percent level.
Table 2: Variance Decomposition
a. Changes in Real Exchange Rate () q)
Forecast Standard % from
Horizon Error [DELTA] q % from s
1 0.0388 100.000 0.000
2 0.0397 96.168 3.832
3 0.0422 95.715 4.285
4 0.0429 95.190 4.810
5 0.0443 95.474 4.526
6 0.0444 95.479 4.521
7 0.0444 95.479 4.521
8 0.0445 95.364 4.636
9 0.0445 95.330 4.670
10 0.0445 95.329 4.671
11 0.0446 95.326 4.674
12 0.0446 95.327 4.673
b. Level of Nominal Exchange Rate (s)
Forecast Standard % from
Horizon Error [DELTA] q % from s
1 0.0423 94.273 5.727
2 0.8320 96.861 3.139
3 0.2850 97.567 2.433
4 0.8100 97.566 2.434
5 0.5260 97.318 2.681
6 0.5210 97.066 2.934
7 0.5210 96.742 3.258
8 0.6350 96.597 3.403
9 0.6700 96.534 3.466
10 0.6700 96.484 3.516
11 0.6740 96.452 3.548
12 0.6720 96.423 3.577