Economies of scale and the provision of public goods by municipalities.
Couch, Jim F. ; King, Brett A. ; Gossett, Carol H. 等
ABSTRACT
This paper adds to the literature that examines economies of scale
in the provision of municipal services. Private sector economies exist
as average costs decline as output expands. Likewise, economies exist in
the provision of public services as average costs decline as the number
of recipients of the service increases.
A discussion of declining average costs inevitably involves a
discussion of municipal consolidation. Proponents of larger local
government believe bigger government is more efficient government.
Citizens residing in consolidated cities will enjoy quality city
services at a lower cost. In addition, consolidated cities are more
effective at long range, comprehensive planning which spurs regional
economic development.
This study utilizes a sample of municipalities in Alabama to
empirically test for economies (or diseconomies) of scale in the
provision of public services. A brief history of municipal consolidation
is presented in the next section. Section two contains the theoretical
arguments for the creation of mega-municipalities and for numerous,
fragmented local governments. In section three, a review of the existing
literature is presented. Finally, the last section contains the results
of this study and some concluding remarks.
BRIEF HISTORY
Consolidating smaller municipalities into a single metropolitan
government offers the promise of efficiency to many observers. By ending
the duplication of services in nearby cities and taking advantage of
economies of scale, lower-cost public services are possible. Centralized
government will be attractive to industry and will result in increased
economic development.
The notion that bigger local government is better local government
is not new. It traces its origins, according to Andrew Sancton (2000),
to debates surrounding the consolidation of local governments in the
Philadelphia area in 1844. "Eli K. Price, the state senator from
Philadelphia, presented one of the first ever projections of financial
savings. He claimed that the elimination of 168 tax collectors from the
different jurisdictions would save $100,000 per year" (Sancton
2000:28).
New York City is the product of the consolidation of 15 cities in
five separate counties in 1898 (Sancton 2000). Twelve municipalities
were merged with Birmingham by the Alabama legislature in 1910. While a
metropolitan-wide referendum on the merger passed, a majority in the
municipalities being merged were opposed. Sancton (2000:37) points out
that since that time, "no solvent American municipality has been
forced against its will to lose its incorporated status and join
another."
The most recent articulation of the case for consolidation comes
from David Rusk, the former mayor of Albuquerque, New Mexico. His book,
Cities Without Suburbs has successfully placed "the issue of
municipal boundaries back on the American agenda" (Sancton
2000:79).
Nevertheless, the issue is typically unpopular with the voters.
"Only 20 percent of referenda on consolidation are approved by the
electorate (Harrigan and Vogel 2000). To cite a few examples, mergers
were defeated in St. Louis, San Antonio, Sacramento, Portland, Charlotte
and Knoxville. In fact, Knoxville voters have defeated consolidation
plans on four separate occasions (Lyons and Scheb 1998).
A number of notable mergers and consolidations have taken place.
The services provided by Dade County (Miami) were extended in 1957.
Nashville and Davidson County were consolidated in 1962, Jacksonville
and Duvall County were consolidated in 1967 and two years later,
Indianapolis and Marion County were merged (Sancton 2000:71). More
recently, Louisville and Jefferson County were merged in Kentucky.
THEORETICAL ARGUMENTS
"According to the consolidationists, the primary ills of local
government stem from fragmentation and the 85,000 governments and over
500,000 officials that dot America's political landscape. For
consolidationists, the solution lies in eliminating independent
municipalities within a county and replacing them with a single
government" (Savitch and Vogel 2000: 162).
Bigger local government could take advantage of economies of scale
by producing on a larger scale. In addition, the duplication of
supervisors, administrators and local politicians would bring relief to
taxpayers.
Competition between numerous local governments is unproductive as
well. Expressing such an idea is Carl Goldenberg, who in 1963 reported
to the Ontario government the merits of amalgamated metro-government.
"With each municipality seeking to improve its tax base
independently, they compete for development and redevelopment projects,
which are accordingly dealt with on a piecemeal basis and without regard
to sound planning in the overall interests of the area" (Goldenberg
1965: 181-82). By clinging to their own parochial interests, resources
are wasted and the 'big-picture' ignored.
Consolidation supports growth and economic development "by
enhancing the planning capacity of local government. Comprehensive
planning on a metropolitan-wide basis under a single authority is viewed
as a necessary condition for attaining coordinated development"
(Feiock and Carr 1997:166). Firms seeking to locate in an area with a
metropolitan government only have to deal with a single entity rather
than numerous officials from several jurisdictions.
On the other hand, convincing arguments can be made which suggest
that smaller, independent municipalities deliver superior services at
lower costs. Howard Husock, Director of Case Studies at the John F.
Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, argues "that
improvement of ... cities requires not a single, bigger government but
increased numbers of smaller ones". Bigger government, according to
Husock, is not more efficient government. The basis for his assertion
goes back to the work of Charles Tiebout.
Tiebout, in response to those who argued that no mechanism existed
to reveal the preferences of consumers for public goods, showed how
competition among numerous local governments could achieve a market-like
efficiency. When many local governments exist, people can choose to
reside in the one that most closely produces the types of public goods
they desire.
Small communities can offer differing packages of services and
amenities and we can vote with our feet as to which ones we prefer.
Moreover, even when they offer the same sorts of services, they compete
as to which can deliver them more efficiently. The town which offers the
package of services most like that which you want and delivers at the
lowest tax rate will get your vote, in effect. You'll move in. If
things change, you may well move out. We know that competition
disciplines the private marketplace; so, too, does it discipline the
public one (Husock 2001).
Numerous local jurisdictions provide choices for consumers and
citizen mobility promotes efficiency. As Tiebout predicted, differing
policies among jurisdictions has been shown to significantly influence
migration (Reschovsky 1979).
Other local jurisdictions also provide a basis for comparison.
Thus, citizens in one municipality can compare the set of services
offered and the costs of such services with other municipalities and
protest--at the ballot box--if the comparison is unfavorable. Comparison
shopping is more difficult with metropolitan governments.
Large consolidated cities are monopoly providers of services and,
so the argument goes, suffer from all the inefficiencies inherent with
this market structure. "We should no more worry about too many
municipalities than we should worry about too many firms involved in the
retailing of groceries. Just as different grocery stores provide
different levels of selection, quality and price, so too do
municipalities. Having one municipality responsible for providing all
the municipal services in a city-region makes as much sense as having
one monopoly grocery firm" (Sancton 2000:74).
The question of whether economies exist in the provision of
services by municipalities is an empirical one. Before empirical
evidence is presented, however, the existing literature regarding this
subject will be examined.
LITERATURE REVIEW
Researchers have sought to identify the efficiency gains associated
with larger municipalities. Sjoquist (1982) found that numerous small
jurisdictions resulted in lower costs of services. Benton and Gamble
(1984) examined both expenditures and taxation in pre- and post-merger
Jacksonville, Florida and found that both increased after consolidation.
Gustely (1977) showed that expenditures for services provided by Metro
Miami government rose after consolidation. Another study commissioned by
the National Research Council (1999) concluded that rather than a method
of reducing costs, consolidation resulted in increased local
expenditures. Desbiens (1999) found that diseconomies of scale are
present even when jurisdiction with as few as 2000 inhabitants are
merged--a result suggesting that extremely small municipalities are the
most efficient.
Weicher (1970) examines four subcategories of spending; namely
police protection, fire protection, sewers and sanitation and highways.
Evidence of economies of scale is only present with fire protection. In
another study examining Miami-Dade County, Becker and Dluhy (1998) find
no evidence of economies when focusing on aggregate expenditures but
when specific services are examined, they find some, limited evidence
for lower costs with larger jurisdictions. Fire and rescue services,
library services and planning services demonstrated economies of scale
while police protection, waste management, recreation services and
public works showed "either negligible or marginal economies (or
diseconomies) of scale" (1998:85).
A study of the Pittsburg (Allegheny County) area for the U.S.
government's Advisory Council on Intergovernmental Relations (ACIR)
found that, despite the fact that "there were more than 100
separate police departments [in Allegheny County], costs ... were below
the average for other American areas on similar size" (ACIR
1992:78). A separate ACIR study (1988) investigated the St. Louis area.
Researchers found evidence of "slight economies of scale ... in
larger police departments (ACIR 1988: 76). The St. Louis study examined
another issue; are larger areas better able to attract industry and
jobs. The authors found no relationship between the number of
municipalities in a region and the number of jobs created.
The notion that larger local government will eliminate duplication
and result in lower administrative costs was explored by Bish (2000).
The cost associated with 88 elected officials and their staffs in 13
separate jurisdictions were compared with those of 23 elected officials
and their staffs in a merged city of the same population. Bish found
that per capita costs were practically identical.
The quality of services provided by large cities and by numerous
smaller governmental units has also been examined. Ostrom and Parks
(1973) asserted that smaller, unmerged police departments are more
trusted by citizens, know more about their communities and respond to
the citizen needs more quickly. Likewise, Hoxby (1997) found that
students in areas with numerous school districts performed better on
math and reading examinations than did students from areas with large
unified districts. The costs of providing education were significantly
lower with more numerous districts as well.
MODEL AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
The present study tests for economies of scale from a sample of
Alabama cities prepared by the Public Affairs Research Council of
Alabama (PARCA), a nonprofit research organization housed at Samford
University. The sample includes Alabama's 25 largest cities ranging
in population from 18,497 in Mountain Brook to 252,997 in Birmingham.
The data in the report are derived from city financial reports for
fiscal year 1998 (October 1998 through September 1999), and have been
adjusted so that the data are comparable from city to city. For example,
solid waste collection is included but sewage treatment facility
expenditures and the expenditures associated with operating a landfill
are omitted.
Municipal expenditures have been divided into a number of
categories; namely, public safety, public works and community
development, general governmental and social and cultural activities.
Public safety expenditures include police, fire, emergency-911, and
civil defense; public works and community development expenditures
include streets, sanitation, engineering, parking, transit and community
development block grants unless allocated to some other function;
general government expenditures encompass the mayor and council, courts,
finance and economic development; and social and cultural activities
include parks, museums, cemeteries, civic auditoriums, libraries,
welfare, senior citizen and youth activities, animal shelters and health
services.
Public safety expenditures were the largest of the spending
categories in 23 of the 25 cities ranging as a percentage of total
operating expenditures from a low of 28% to a high of 46% (PARCA Report
2000:5). In the remaining cities, public works and community development
was the largest category.
In addition to the spending data, the PARCA Report also includes
information that serves as an explanatory variable in this study,
TAXBASE. TAXBASE is the amount of per capita money generated by a 1%
sales tax. It captures the ability of cities to raise revenue. Sales
taxes accounted for the majority of revenue raised in 1998 in 23 of the
25 cities comprising the sample (PARCA Report 2000:2).
Other independent variables entered into the equation are the 1999
median age of the city's residents, the percentage of the
city's population in 1999 with college degrees, 1999 per capita
income of the city, 1997 property crime (burglary, larceny-theft, motor
vehicle theft, arson) per 100,000 residents, 1997 violent crime (murder,
non-negligent manslaughter, forcible rape and assault) per 100,000
residents and the percentage of the city's population that is
black, in 1999.
Models utilizing total aggregate expenditures, public safety
spending, public works spending, cultural expenditures and general
government expenditures as the dependent variables are estimated. The
results are presented in Table 1. Seventy seven percent of the variation
in aggregate expenditures is accounted for in the first model. The size
of the tax base is significantly related to all of the spending
categories (including aggregate spending) with the exception of general
government and public works expenditures.
Higher per capita income and the amount of property crime are
significantly related with public safety expenditures. As the number of
college graduates increases, public safety expenditures decrease
significantly.
The behavior of the variables of chief interest, population and
population squared, indicate that economies of scale are not present in
any of the specifications. No evidence for the proposition that big
government is efficient government is found. Instead, the results
indicate that diseconomies are present in the provision of public safety
services and in aggregate expenditures.
CONCLUSION
This study yields no support for the hypothesis that large
government takes advantage of economies of scale and avoids wasteful
duplication. In fact, diseconomies exist when examining aggregate
spending and in the provision of public safety services. Given the
overwhelming evidence supporting numerous jurisdictions, Sancton (2000:
75) asserts, "to be intellectually convincing, consolidationists
must now specify exactly what it is they expect consolidation to
accomplish and why this objective cannot be achieved by following some
other course of action."
REFERENCES
Benton, J. E. & Gamble, D. (1984). City/County Consolidation
and Economies of Scale: Evidence from a Time-Series Analysis in
Jacksonville, Florida, Social Science Quarterly, 65, 190-98.
Bish, R. L. (2000). Local Government Amalgamations: Discredited
Nineteenth-Century Ideals Alive in the Twenty-First. C. D. Howe
Institute Commentary 150, March.
Consolidation Versus Fragmentation of Government Services: Evidence
From Metropolitan Miami, (1998) in Becker & Dluhy, (Eds.), Solving
Urban Problems in Urban Areas Characterized by Fragmentation and
Divisiveness, Stamford CT: JAI Press.
Desbiens, J. (1999). Fusions Municipales et economies
d'echelle: Mythes et realities.
Feiock, R. C. & Carr, J. B. (1997). A Reassessment of
City/County Consolidation: Economic Development Impacts. State and Local
Government Review, 29(3), 166-71.
Goldenberg, C. (1965). Ontario: Report of the Royal Commission on
Metropolitan Toronto.
Gustely, R.D..(1977). The Allocation and Distributional Impacts of
Governmental Consolidation: The Dade County Experience, Urban Affairs
Quarterly, 12(3), March.
Harrigan, J. J. & Vogel R. K. (2000). Political Change in the
Metropolis. 6th edition. New York: Longman.
Husock, H. (1998). The Case for Breaking Up Cities The Taubman
Center Report, Harvard University.
Husock, H. (2001). Why Bigger Local Government Isn't More
Efficient: The Case for Breaking Up Cities Speech given at
Montreal's Omni Hotel. May 18, www.iedm.org/library/discourshusock.
Lyons, W. & Scheb, J. (1998). Saying No One More Time: The
Rejection of Consolidated Government in Knox County, Tennessee, State
and Local Government Review, 30(2), Spring.
www.bestplaces.net/html/cities.html
Morgan, D. & Mareschal. (1996). Central City/Cuburban
Inequality and Metropolitan Political Fragmentation, American Political
Science Association, San Francisco, California, August 27-30.
National Research Council, (1999). The Committee on Improving the
Future of U.S. Cities, Governance and Opportunity in the U. S. Cities.
National Academy Press, Washington, D.C.
Ostrom, E. & Parks, R. (1973). Suburban Police Departments: Too
Many and Too Small? in L. Masotti & J. Hadden, (Eds.), The
Urbanization of the Suburbs, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.
Reschovsky, A. (1979). Residential Choice and the Local Public
Sector: An Alternative Test of the Tiebout Hypothesis, Journal of Urban
Economics. October 6(4) 501-20. Rusk, D. (1995). Cities Without Suburbs
2nd edition, Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson Centre Press.
Sancton, A. (2000). Merger Mania: The Assault on Local Government,
Westmount, Quebec, Canada: Price Patterson Ltd.
Savitch, H. V. & Vogel, R. K. (2000). Paths to New Regionalism,
State and Local Government Review, 32(3), 158-68.
Sjoquist, D.L. (1982). The Effect of the Number of Local
Governments on Central City Expenditures, National Tax Journal.
The PARCA Report, (2000). Financial Comparisons for Alabama's
Largest Cities. Number 39, Summer, Samford University: Birmingham.
Tiebout, C.M. (1956). A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures, Journal
of Political Economy. October, 64(3), 416-24.
United States Advisory Council on Intergovernmental Relations
(ACIR), 1988. Metropolitan Organization: The St. Louis Case, Report
M-181.
United States Advisory Council on Intergovernmental Relations
(ACIR), 1992. Metropolitan Organization: The Allegheny County Case,
Report M-181.
Weicher, J.. C. (1970). Determinants of Central City Expenditures:
Some Overlooked Factors and Problems, National Tax Journal, 23(4),
379-396.
Jim F. Couch, University of North Alabama
Brett A. King, University of North Alabama
Carol H. Gossett, University of North Alabama
Joan B. Parris, University of North Alabama
Table 1
Total Expenditures
Public
Model 1 Mode1 2 Safety
Intercept -172.2 -292.6 153.7
(-0.3) (-0.58) (1.07)
Population -0.0065 -0.0065 -0.002
(-1.96) * (-2.37) *** (-2.78) ***
Pop Squared 0.00000003 0.000000028 0.000000008
(2.14) ** (2.58) *** (2.84) ***
Tax Base 3.5 3.6 0.87
(3.54) *** (4.2) *** (3.64) ***
Median Age 10.13 11.42 -2.83
(0.66) (0.79) (-0.7)
College Grad 13.82 15.46 -7.04
(1.18) (1.43) (-2.32) ***
Per Capita 0.002 0.002 0.011
Income (0.195) (0.184) (3.72) ***
Property Crime 0.04 0.041 0.02
(1.53) (3.16) *** (4.33) ***
Violent Crime 0.036
(0.42)
Percent Black (2.48)
(-0.52)
[R.sup.2] 0.77 0.76 0.79
Public Cultural General
Works Expenditures Government
Intercept 124.0 -81.1 95.01
(0.77) (-0.75) (0.89)
Population -0.001 -0.0004 0.000038
(-1.15) (-0.77) (0.77)
Pop Squared 0.000000004 0.000000003 0.0000000008
(1.27) -1.11 (0.34)
Tax Base 0.39 0.414 0.186
(1.53) (2.42) *** (1.09)
Median Age 1.37 3.69 -0.31
(0.3) (1.19) (-0.1)
College Grad -5.1 1.15 -1.74
(-1.5) (0.5) (-0.77)
Per Capita 0.004 -0.0008 0.001
Income (1.14) (-0.35) (0.64)
Property Crime
Violent Crime
Percent Black
[R.sup.2] 0.37 0.42 0.27
t-statistics in parentheses
* 10% level of confidence
** 5% level of confidence
*** 1% level of confidence