Which is longer, the short run or the long run?
Holahan, William L. ; Schug, Mark C.
ABSTRACT
This paper focuses on a common oversimplification in the
presentation of one of the most basic concepts that we teach: the
distinction between short run and long run in the theory of production.
This paper illustrates how the terms "long run" and
"short run" do not mean the same thing in demand and supply
analysis they mean in the theory of production. In supply and demand
analysis, short run and long run refer to the length of periods of
chronological time. In the theory of production, the short run and long
run refer to how time is used, not how much time is used. The long run
refers to the planning process while the short run refers to operations.
A survey of commonly available principles of economics textbooks reveals
that this conceptual difference is not being taught.
Albert Einstein instructed us to explain the complex as simply as
possible, but no simpler. Oversimplification will at the very least rob
a subject of richness, and at worst mislead. Economics is based upon
simplifying assumptions, and part of the science is the avoidance of
misleading oversimplification. The purpose of this paper is to point out
a common oversimplification in the principles of economics course,
involving one of the most basic concepts that we teach: the distinction
between short run and long run in the theory of the firm. The common
definitions of these terms are so well accepted that a survey of
available texts shows uniformity in the use of the overly simple
definition. We then offer a simple way to resolve the issue with an
explanation that clears up the potential for confusion, is economically
correct, and is intellectually fun.
HOW THE "LONG RUN" AND "SHORT RUN" DIFFERS IN
SUPPLY AND DEMAND VERSUS THE THEORY OF PRODUCTION
The basic problem is that the terms "long run" and
"short run" do not mean the same in demand and supply analysis
as they mean in the theory of the firm. Unfortunately, none of the
textbooks book we examined points this out. In supply and demand
analysis, short run and long run refer to the length of periods of
chronological time. In the theory of the firm, the short run and long
run refer to how time is used as a resource, not how much time is used.
In the long run firms plan; in the short run they operate the facility
that they decided to install during their planning.
Our examination of widely available principles texts (see Table 1)
reveals that in supply and demand analysis, authors correctly explain
that demand is more elastic in the long run than in the short run
because decision makers have more time to adjust to changes in prices.
Similarly on the supply side, supply is more elastic in the long run
than in the short run, again, because decision makers have more time to
adjust. So, we give the students the clear and correct instruction that
we are referring to the length of periods of chronological time.
Without proper explanation, students naturally think that the terms
"long run" and "short run" in the theory of the firm
are once again referring to chronological time as was the case in supply
and demand analysis. In fact, many texts appear to reinforce
misunderstanding when they explain that the short run is a period so
short that only the variable factors of production can be varied as is
the case in the standard Q = F (K,L) total product function, when only L
can be varied in the short run. The implication is that K cannot be
varied because there isn't enough time.
A FIRM CAN BE SIMULTANEOUSLY IN THE LONG RUN AND THE SHORT RUN
Two Ironies Flow from this Discussion
First, the long run can occupy a much shorter period of
chronological time than the short run. An example that is both familiar
and instructive is McDonalds. All students have been in a McDonalds
restaurant, many of them hundreds of times. They can see the capital and
the labor in a short run setting. They cannot see the long run planning,
but that can be described: To establish a new McDonald's franchise,
the franchisee works with planners from corporate headquarters to
estimate demand, and, in turn, the size, shape and equipment that will
maximize profits for the firm. The planning stage is the long run. Prior
to installation, no hamburgers are being flipped when people are
planning. Only when the best assortment of capital is chosen and
installed can labor be applied to its operation.
The operation of the installed capacity takes place in the short
run. A typical McDonalds can be planned, built, and ready for operation
in a matter of a few months, and operated for many years. That is, the
short run operating period is a much longer period of chronological time
than the long run planning period. In fact, the better the long run
planning decisions, the longer the short run will last.
Second, a firm can be in the long run and the short run at the same
point in time. How can this be? Firms typically have operating divisions
and planning divisions working at the same time. Operating divisions
work in the short run as they produce goods and services. At the same
time, across the hall or across the world, others in the firm are
working in the long run. These are the planners who are deciding what
changes are to be made to capital and how labor is to be deployed in the
future. Not only can the long run and the short run take place at the
same time, the long run can precede or succeed the short run. For
example, the long run must precede the short run in the installation of
a new McDonalds, then after the short run has expired and the restaurant
goes out of the fast food business, the planners must return to
determine how the land and building will be used in future, a long run
exercise that may not take much chronological time.
In the planning mode of the firm, all factors of production are
variable and, because of the nature of the long run, not much
chronological time may be involved. In the long run, planners are
considering different combinations of capital and labor by examining
blueprints and computer-aided design programs. For example, an architect
can now use computer programs to draw up plans for a building, and not
only have computer generated pictures of the building exterior and
interior, but actually move virtual walls right on the screen and
simultaneously have a spreadsheet re-calculate costs. Thus the planner
can see several of the long-run alternatives before committing to the
best short run choice.
LONG RUN AND SHORT RUN AVERAGE COST CURVES
There is no need to alter the traditional diagram that shows the
geometric relationship between the long run average cost curves and the
short run average cost curves. But the proper definition of long run and
short run is essential to understanding what these curves actually
display. It is more a matter of enriching the interpretation of the
graphs to include the fact that real firms can be both planning and
operating at the same time. Moreover, firms may be planning without
operating, or operating without further planning. The long run average
cost curve shows only the envelope of the short run curves, and cannot
therefore include the costs of planning and adjusting capital.
Figure 1 displays the standard depiction in which three SAC curves
are drawn. For a firm that has three scales of plant from which to
choose, SAC0 and SAC1 intersect at point A, and SAC1 and SAC2 intersect
at point B. Therefore, if the firm is planning on an output range
between zero and Q1, the planner will install the scale of plant
associated with SAC0. Similarly if the output range is expected to be
between Q1 and Q2, the planner will install SAC1; and for an output
range above Q2, SAC2.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
But what if things change and the original output expectation is
not what actually happens? Suppose that SAC0 is selected and installed
but output averages Q3 rather than the expected zero to Q1 range. Then
average costs will be at the height of point C, whereas the same output
could be produced at lower cost at the larger scale of plant shown by
SAC1 at point D. The planner in the firm now has to evaluate whether the
reduction in cost that will be available at the larger scale of plant
outweighs the cost of making the additional capital investment. The cost
of making the investment is sunk once capital is installed, and the only
costs that are reflected in the cost curves are the opportunity costs of
capital and labor in the short run.
This new way of looking at the short run and long run distinction
is not inconsistent with the treatment in the standard texts, but rather
enriches it. For example, the short run is a period in which some
factors, usually called capital, are fixed. But they are not fixed
because the short run is a short period of chronological time, as the
texts state. Rather the fixed factors are fixed either because the
cost-minimizing scale of the plant has been chosen or because the cost
of adjusting capital from one scale of plant to another is greater than
the present value of expected savings to be derived from changing to the
cost-minimizing scale of plant. The better the choices made in the
long-run planning phase, the smaller will be the incentives to change
the scale of the plant. Therefore, the short run may last a long period
of chronological time, much longer than the long run.
This distinction works outside the theory of the firm as well.
Consider marriage. Many of your college students are unmarried people
seeking spouses. Spouse-seeking unmarried people are selecting potential
mates from alternatives found on campus and elsewhere. This process of
sorting is long run planning. But, marriage changes everything because
it requires a choice of a scale of plant. The married state is actually
the short run since once married, people find it financially and
emotionally expensive to change their spouse, i.e., their fixed factor
of production. Married spouses who engage in long run activity are bound
to shorten the marriage's short run. In marriage, it is fine to be
in it for the long haul, but not the long run.
SUMMARY
The purpose of this paper is to caution teachers of the principles
of economics course that the terms "long run" and "short
run" do not mean the same thing in demand and supply analysis as
they mean in the theory of production. In supply and demand analysis,
short run and long run refer to the length of periods of chronological
time. In the theory of the firm, the short run and long run refer to how
time is used, not how much time is used: the long run refers to the
planning process while the short run refers to operations.
REFERENCES
Case, K. E. & Fair, R. C. (1996). Principles of economics. (4th
Ed.) Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall Inc.
Colander, D. C. (2001). Economics. (4th Ed.) Boston, MA: Irwin
McGraw-Hill.
Hyman, D. N. (1997). Economics. (4th Ed.) Boston, MA: Irwin
McGraw-Hill.
Mankiw, N. G. (1998). Principles of economics. Fort Worth, TX: The
Dryden Press.
Nordhaus, S. (1998). Economics. (16th Ed.) Boston, MA: Irwin
McGraw-Hill.
Schiller, B. R. (1997). The economy today. (7th Ed.) Boston, MA:
Irwin McGraw-Hill.
Slavin, S. L. (1999). Economics. (5th Ed.) Boston, MA: Irwin
McGraw-Hill.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1997). Economics. (2nd Ed.) New York, NY: W. W.
Norton & Company, Inc.
Tucker, I. B. (2000). Economics for today. (2nd Ed.) Cincinnati,
OH: South Western College Publishing.
William L. Holahan, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee
Mark C. Schug, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee
Table 1 Short Run and Long Run Analysis
Author Publisher and Year The concepts of
long and/or
short run are
explained
properly with
reference to
chronological
time in the
supply and
demand analysis
Karl E. Case & Prentice Hall, Yes
Ray C. Fair 1996
David C. Irwin McGraw Yes
Colander Hill, 2001
David N. Irwin, 1997 Yes
Hyman
N. Gregory Dryden, 1999 Yes
Mankiw
Campbell R. McGraw Hill, Yes
McConnell & 1999
Stanley L. Brue
Paul A. Irwin McGraw Yes
Samuelson Hill, 1998
& William D.
Nordhaus
Bradley R. Irwin McGraw Yes
Schiller Hill, 1997
Stephen L. Irwin McGraw Yes
Slavin Hill, 1999
Joseph Stiglitz Norton, 1997 Yes
Irvin B. Tucker South-Western, Yes
2000
Author The concepts of Explicit
long and/or vocabulary of
short run are long range
explicitly planning and
explained as not short range
necessarily operations is
involving used
chronological
time in the
analysis of the
theory of the
firm
Karl E. Case & No No
Ray C. Fair
David C. No No
Colander
David N. No Yes
Hyman
N. Gregory No No
Mankiw
Campbell R. No No
McConnell &
Stanley L. Brue
Paul A. No No
Samuelson
& William D.
Nordhaus
Bradley R. No No
Schiller
Stephen L. No No
Slavin
Joseph Stiglitz No No
Irvin B. Tucker No No