Strategic competitive advantages and value net organisation: conceptual considerations and organisational recommendations for two- or multi-sided service markets.
Dietl, Helmut ; Franck, Egon ; Royer, Susanne 等
Introduction: Competition in service markets
Products and services both fulfil human needs. However, a number of
characteristics distinguish services from tangible products. The main
difference is the immaterial character of services. Patenting service
innovations is difficult due to this immaterial nature of service
concepts. Based on ideas, information, and skills, such concepts are
almost impossible to patent and also hard to protect against imitation.
Long-term, sustainable competitive advantage, therefore, is difficult to
achieve. Service firms do not only have to develop unique service
concepts but also protect these with the help of isolating mechanisms.
Rumelt calls such resource characteristics isolating mechanisms that
prevent an imitation by competitors and defines them as 'phenomena
that limit the ex post equilibration of rents among individual
firms' (Rumelt 1984: 567). Mahoney and Pandian (1992: 371) add that
'isolating mechanisms explain (ex post) a stable stream of rents
and provide a rationale for intra-industry differences among
firms'. Establishing isolating mechanisms is a particular challenge
regarding services because of their immaterial nature.
In general it is not possible to store services. It is thus not
possible to decouple supply and demand but a coordination is necessary
which requires a sophisticated supply and demand management. Production
takes place at the same time as consumption. Therefore, the consumer is
virtually integrated into the value-adding process. On the one hand,
this means that consumers, as external factors, introduce additional
variability and instability to the production process. On the other
hand, consumers relieve service firms by placing productive capacity at
its disposal. Due to the integration of the customer into the
value-adding process of service organizations, customers influence value
creation to a high degree. This becomes clear when looking at
self-service. For value creation, the Google search engine, for example,
not only depends on its technical properties, but exceedingly upon the
skill and ability of the user to formulate his or her query.
Integrating the customer into the value-adding process as
co-producer seriously influences service firms (e.g. Royer 2005). This
is even more relevant when customers not only extensively influence
their own transactions' value but also the value-adding process of
other customers. Concerts and sports events are typical examples for
this. The quality of the audience of concerts or sports events is
equally relevant as the quality of the artists or athletes. A pop
concert or soccer game in an empty or half-empty stadium generates
substantially less value than a sold-out event. Many service providers
depend not only on customers but also on complements. For example, eBay
depends on electronic payment transactions, Amazon.com on logistic services and Yahoo! on news and entertainment topics.
It becomes obvious that such so-called two- and multi-sided markets
have certain specificities (e.g. Rochet and Tirole 2001; Amstrong 2006).
Each customer on one market side influences the value creation of
customers on other market sides. For this reason competitive advantages
here are not only based on firm specificities but rather on the
efficient and effective organization of value creation processes and
activities around a certain service. These processes and activities
often transcend far beyond firm boundaries and also include customers
and producers of complements. Therefore, in this paper a new perspective
on value creation and competitive advantage realization is taken that is
neither a market-based (e.g. Porter 1985) nor a resource-based (e.g.
Peteraf 1993) approach. Rather the focus is on the process of value
creation and the underlying value-adding processes and activities.
Around a product or service different value-adding activities undertaken
by various actors lead to a certain form of value net organization (see
Dietl, Royer and Stratmann 2007). In many market environments nets of
various actors transcending firm boundaries are competing. This leads to
a two-level competition on the intra-net level as well as the inter-net
level. Both levels have to be taken into account when analysing
competitive advantage.
This paper aims at elaborating the relationship between value net
organization and competitive advantage in two- and multi-sided service
markets and, based on this, at developing contingent organizational
recommendations for firms competing in such markets. It follows a
description of the characteristics of two- and multi-sided service
markets. This forms the basis for an analysis of the strategic potential
of horizontal, vertical, and lateral forms of value net organization in
two- and multi-sided service markets. In a concluding summary the
findings are summed up and critically reflected.
Two- or multi-sided services
For two-sided services, the integration of customers into the
value-adding process is crucial to success. Those customers on one side
of the market no longer solely contribute to their own value-adding
process and the value-adding process of their co-customers on the same
side, but primarily create value for those customers on the other market
side. Monster.com is a typical example for a two-sided service.
Monster.com operates a job exchange platform on the Internet. Employers
can post their vacancies on the Internet portal and job seekers may
search the job portal applying various criteria as well as make an
application. The value-adding process of Monster.com consists mainly of
transaction cost economies, especially saving search costs for both
market sides, i.e. for employers and for job seekers. Compared to
traditional job markets in newspapers, the digitalization of job offers
facilitates searching and, therefore, reduces searching costs for
potential employees. As job seekers are likely to be more successful the
more job offers are launched by the portal, the more are the value
creation for job seekers.
Two forms of cost benefits result for the employer. Firstly, the
costs placing a job offer with Monster.com are much lower than the costs
for corresponding advertisements in newspapers. Secondly, but much more
important: Compared to the costs which result from having a vacancy, the
costs for advertising are negligibly low. Internet recruitment has led
to a reduction of the recruitment period from an average of three months
to one month (Hallowell and Reavis 2002: 5). Monster. com, therefore,
reduces the vacancy period of a position by an average of two months.
The cost advantages associated are the lion's share of (additional)
value creation for the employer. All in all, the extent of cost
reduction by the employer is dependent on the likelihood of finding a
suitable employee. This likelihood grows with the number of job seekers,
i.e. the size of the other market side. Each additional participant on
one market side, therefore, increases the value-adding possibilities for
the participants on the other market side.
The complexity of a value-adding process increases further where
multi-sided services are concerned. Another market side for these
services appears. Such multi-sided service markets are found when a
two-sided market generates attention, which can be sold to advertisers
as a side product. For example, Internet portals, newspapers and
magazines, and sports and cultural events show the characteristics of
multi-sided service markets.
Value net organization and competitiveness
The consideration of value net organization transcends firm
boundaries and, in addition to vertically linked value-adding
activities, integrates further relevant actors on horizontal and lateral
levels into the analysis; yet it does not focus on the industry as a
whole but on a system of value-adding processes and activities around a
product or service that belong together. Value net organization in two-
and multi-sided service markets affects efficiency as well as strategy
of actors participating in a system and is, therefore, a highly relevant
competitive factor within the context of different value adding systems.
The service platform is at the centre of value net organization in
two- and multi-sided service industries. It is understood to be the
(technological) connection between individual market sides. For
telecommunications, for example, this connection is a fibreglass and
copper network. For postal services, the platform is composed of mail
boxes, receiving offices and delivery networks. eBay's platform is
the electronic auctioning portal.
In this context, the so-called network effects play a relevant role
(e.g. Katz and Shapiro 1986). If such network effects are in existence
the average willingness to pay increases with a growing number of
customers. This is, for example, the case for e-mail or telephone
systems or for auction platforms. Only if there is a sufficient number
of users a product can stay in a market characterized by network
effects. At first products with network effects do only have a few users
resulting in a relatively low willingness to pay. If a supplier survives
this phase, for example, by selling at a loss, the willingness to pay
increases as a consequence of the network effects, and the critical mass
of users is reached. Network effects in two- and multi-sided service
markets lead to a value-adding spiral, which spans both market sides.
Therefore, we in these markets call such effects network cross-effects.
Figure 1 exemplarily demonstrates this value-adding spiral for the
electronic auctioning platform eBay as a typical example for a
double-sided market (Dietl and Schieke 2007).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Regarding value net organization, platform operators have to
address issues of horizontal, vertical, and lateral integration
strategically. Moving in a horizontal direction, for example, the
platform operator has to make a decision if to integrate, cooperate
with, or differentiate from rival platforms. For the vertical dimension
the integration or coordination of market sides is in the focus while
the lateral dimension is mainly concerned with the coordination of
complements. It follows an investigation of strategic direction
regarding these three issues.
Horizontal organization
Based on the value-adding spiral between market sides, a platform
operator, in order to remain competitive, has to achieve a critical mass
of customers on all sides of the market as soon as possible. The
respective size of this critical mass depends on the trade-off between
network cross-effects and potential differentiation advantages. In the
extreme case no potentials for differentiation exist. This would apply
to a totally homogeneous service. Due to network cross-effects only one
platform operator can survive in such a market in the long run.
Critical mass size is further dependent on the scalability of the
service range. The most extreme here would be zero marginal costs,
meaning that the service only generates fixed costs and is, therefore,
arbitrarily scaleable. In practice however, the criteria for such a
'natural' monopoly are rarely fulfilled. Especially within the
service sector, there is constant differentiation potential. Any service
business can, on principle, differentiate itself from competitors by
utilizing additional services. Admittedly, effective differentiation
potentials are more limited as most additional services are relatively
easy to imitate. Differentiation efforts in the service sector can,
therefore, quickly lead to a ruinous race with respect to offering
additional services. The higher the extent of genuine differentiation
possibilities, the smaller the critical mass tends to be, since smaller
service platforms can compensate for the disadvantages of network
effects with differentiation advantages.
Customer support as well as physical logistic services largely
represents variable cost elements. Growing importance of these two
components leads to gradually declining scalability degrees. Like
genuine differentiation possibilities, a lower degree of scalability
poses an impediment to growth for service platforms. A low degree of
scalability usually results in a relatively small critical mass, because
utilizing network cross-effects is then limited and will be more than
compensated for by cost disadvantages relatively quickly. Digital
services requiring neither extensive customer support nor physical
logistics attain the highest degree of scalability. Figure 2 summarizes
these considerations and shows a continuum of scalability.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Besides an efficient size of critical mass, the time dimension of
competition regarding horizontal coordination of service platforms is
strategically relevant. Due to network effects, platform competition is
always path-dependent. The larger the critical mass and the longer the
head start of the first mover, the more difficult it becomes for new
competitors to gain market shares. In the best case, a platform operator
has first-mover advantages in a winner-take-all industry, i.e. a sector
with high scalability of service range and no genuine differentiation
possibilities. In such a constellation a first mover can preserve the
horizontal autonomy of a platform. There is no need for acquisition or
cooperation. The danger, however, lies in the fact that the platform
operator gains too much market power and thus provokes state regulation
in the industry. Under such conditions it is better if at least a second
(usually smaller) platform operator can survive in the market.
An example for such a scenario currently can be found in the US
market for digital satellite radio. As the service is digitalized,
scalability is enormously high. Marginal costs are negligibly low and
since a multiplicity of programme contents can be broadcast at the same
time, genuine differentiation possibilities are also limited. In this
winner-take-all industry XM Satellite Radio possesses a clear advantage
compared to its smaller competitor Sirius. Yet, it would be
strategically counterproductive to push the competitor out of business
or acquire it as this would certainly activate the US Anti-Trust
Commission.
Late movers in such constellations due to network cross-effects and
limited differentiation possibilities have a substantial competitive
disadvantage in such situations. The only opportunity to overcome this
lies in cooperating with multiple platforms. This, however, does not
mean that multiple platforms should be operated in direct competition to
the first mover. This would not make sense due to limited
differentiation possibilities. It would be better to combine at least
two types of platform. A typical example for this is the cooperative
project Careerbuilder. com founded by newspaper publishing companies to
be able to survive in competition with Monster.com. In addition to
classic job advertisements in weekend issues of their respective
newspapers, the publishers are able to offer additional Internet ads to
their customers. This means that on one hand the differentiation
possibilities of the newspaper business remain intact while on the
other, Monster.com's first-mover advantages are compensated for by
the Internet platform. This strategy is especially suitable where
several platform technologies with diverse differentiation possibilities
(e.g. press, Internet) compete with each other.
Due to U-shaped cost curves or genuine differentiation
possibilities a 'natural' platform monopoly may not exist. In
such cases it is advantageous for first movers to take market segments
that are most profitable first. Late movers may then gradually take the
next profitable segments. Moreover, this situation offers platform
operators a strong incentive to overcome scalability limits, for
example, by digitalizing services. This strategy, however, is successful
only, when all scalability obstacles can actually be dispelled. A
partial transcending of scalability limits is not sufficient as, for
example, 'sothebys.com' shows. With its Internet platform
Sotheby's was able to design a highly scalable auctioneering
process. However, this did not work for the adherent physical logistics.
As sotheby's.com, unlike eBay, is not able to source out logistics
to transaction partners, the attempt at achieving a profitable platform
monopoly failed.
Figure 3 summarizes the outlined recommendations regarding
horizontal value net organization.
Vertical organization
Operators of multi-sided service platforms face a so-called
Chicken--egg problem with regard to pricing at the time of market launch
(e.g. Caillaud and Jullien 2003). Value is primarily created by the
different market sides. For eBay, for example, the value of platform
usage for sellers grows if as many buyers as possible use the platform.
In order for a buyer to use the platform, however, various sellers and
their offers must in turn already exist. In short, no sellers will come
if buyers do not exist and without sellers the platform cannot attract
buyers. It is, however, not possible to integrate the market side inside
a business. Other coordination mechanisms thus have to be found.
The chicken--egg problem is often intensified by the so-called
penguin effect (Farrell and Saloner 1987). The first customers on each
market side contribute most to value creation. They virtually get the
ball rolling. However, these first customers also bear the highest risk
as they do not yet know which platform will prevail in competition.
Jumping on the wrong platform leads to sunk cost, i.e. their investment
is lost. This risk increases with the specificity of the investments.
This situation can be compared to the decision problem hungry penguins
face. Freezing and standing on an ice floe, they would very much like
feeding on the many fish swimming by, but they hesitate to jump in and
hunt because predators are lurking in the cold water. These in turn
would very much like to feed on the penguins. As the first penguins to
jump are at the highest risk of being eaten, each penguin waits for the
other to jump. As soon as a number of penguins have jumped into the
water the danger of one individual being eaten by a predator is
negligibly low and each penguin is able to calmly hunt the substantially
available fish. It is this penguin phase that platform operators must
overcome in order to be successful. One possibility is to subsidize or
at least to grant price advantages to first platform users. In the
beginning, it is often advisable to offer the platform free of charge. A
further strategy is winning attractive reference customers as first
customers.
After the penguin starting phase, i.e. during the swimming and
feeding phase, the selection of price structure remains an important
success factor. An orientation based on marginal costs and price
sensibility of customers is insufficient. In addition, the value-adding
contributions of each market side to respective other market sides have
to be considered. If one market side accomplishes very high value
creation for the other market side(s), this must be considered with
regard to pricing. In this case it is beneficial to subsidize this
market side and to price only the other market side(s). Adobe, for
example, prices only the Adobe Creator while offering the Reader free of
charge. This way Adobe tries to ensure that an adequately large
installed basis of potential readers exists. By selling the Adobe
Reader, additional income would be possible on this market side, but, as
a consequence of the high price sensibility on this market side, a
substantial cutback of demand would have to be expected at the same
time. This decrease of demand would again lessen the Adobe
Creator's value creation. All in all, more income would be lost on
the author's market side than would be gained on the reader's
side. In some cases it can even be rational to request a negative price
on one market side. However, this is often associated with serious
free-rider problems. A possible solution is subsidization by means of
personal additional services which cannot be sold to third parties.
Mobile telephone services, for example, often offer free minutes.
Value creation in many multi-sided service industries is not only
related to the quantity of platform users. Often their quality plays a
relevant role for competitive advantage realization. For a participant
on one market side it may be important which types of customers use the
platform, so that customer selection plays a strategically relevant
role. Value here again is created by other customers. Within a chat room
for example, value creation is primarily achieved by the quality of the
communicating partners. In such a case, platform operators must mainly
focus on the characteristics of the platform user. In doing so,
self-selection mechanisms are most suitable besides signalling and other
selection strategies. Self-selection mechanisms should be designed in
such a way that each platform attracts only those users actually
possessing the desired qualities.
Looking again at those cases for which value creation is mainly
determined by the quantity of platform users, self-service plays a
crucial role. Platform operators in this context usually face the
following dilemma: Due to network cross-effects a fast-growing number of
customers on all market sides is advantageous, yet each additional
customer not only increases value creation. Since customers of service
industries are co-producers at the same time, they also inevitably bring
additional variability into the production process (e.g. Larrson and
Bowen 1989). This variability, which manifests itself in differing
needs, abilities, and attitudes, as well as individual motivation,
willingness, and acceptance of customers, influences production
efficiency. In principle, this problem can be evaded in two ways. Either
the platform operator caters to this variability and allows for the
individual characteristics of each platform user, which, as a general
rule, deteriorates cost structure and in turn endangers scalability of
the service concept. Or, the platform operator ignores the individual
characteristics of each platform user in order to guarantee cost
efficiency and scalability. This, however, impairs the service
experience of platform users.
One possible way out of this dilemma is to outsource production
steps to the customer. Self-service allows customers to match a service
to their respective individual specifics. Self-service, therefore,
resolves the original dilemma and cost efficiency and scalability are
preserved without diminishing the service experience of the customer.
Figure 4 recapitulates the fundamental organization recommendations
in respect of vertical value net organization.
Lateral organization
Often operators of two- or multi-sided service platforms are
dependent on complements in order to activate the value-adding spiral.
E-commerce suppliers need payment systems, credit card portals need
banks, Internet portals need DSL connections, etc. As previously
discussed, the question if complements possess market power or not comes
up only in those cases in which complements are available in sufficient
numbers. If they do possess market power, the complement providers are
able to appropriate a large amount of value creation at the expense of
the platform operator. When, on the other hand, complements are not yet
available, a further chicken-egg problem emerges: Companies will only be
willing to invest in supplying necessary complements, if the platform
already offers a large amount of users. The platform will be utilized
intensely, however, only if the necessary complements are already
available in adequate numbers.
In both cases, it seems to make sense to advise the platform
operator to integrate the production of complements. Such a lateral
integration would, at first sight, solve both value acquisition as well
as the coordination and provision problem. On closer inspection,
however, the dangers of lateral integration become apparent. If the
platform market is a winner-take-all market, meaning it is characterized
by high scalability and missing differentiation possibilities, the
platform operator is dependent on fast-growing market sides. Precisely
this would be prevented, however, if the consumers had to undertake
specific investments and if the platform operator also monopolizes the
complement market in addition to the platform market (e.g. Dietl and
Royer 2003). Consumers would then have to fear being themselves
exploited even in the case of utilizing the platform free of charge. In
this case the platform operator would not be able to solve the
chicken--egg problem or overcome the penguin phase.
In the case where a platform operator strives for platform monopoly
and customers do not have to undertake specific investments, lateral
integration is possible but not necessary (Figure 5). When platform
users have to undertake specific investments, the value-adding spiral
will only get under way if there is competition on the complement market
(Figure 5). To platform users, competition amongst the complements
signalizes that their consumer's rent cannot be taken away by
monopoly prices for complement purchases. Finally, if platform
competition exists in a situation in which platform users must not
transact specific investments, a lateral integration is beneficial since
large profits are not attainable on platform markets anyway (Figure 5).
Lateral integration allows platform operators to monopolize the
complement market and thus clearly improve their value acquisition
possibilities. Figure 5 recapitulates the lateral organization
recommendations.
Summary and Conclusion
In this paper we analyse the relationship between value net
organization and strategic competitive advantage in two-sided and
multi-sided service markets. Therefore, the interplay of actors who
contribute in a value-adding process is taken into consideration with
regard to the strategic analysis instead of focusing on firm internal
resources or a particular industry structure. The analysis extends over
organizational boundaries and takes not only vertically linked
value-adding activities into consideration but integrates other actors
on the horizontal and lateral level. In two-sided and multi-sided
service markets each customer on one market side influences the
value-adding possibilities of the customers on other market sides.
Competitive advantages in such markets strongly rely on the ability to
organize effectively the complete value creation process stretching over
firm boundaries. The paper gives answers to relevant strategic questions
of service platform providers with regard to horizontal (integrate
competing platforms, cooperate with them, or differentiate from them?),
vertical (integration or coordination of the market sides?), and lateral
(how does the coordination of complements function?) value net
organization. The aim of the paper is to give a conceptual overview of
strategic possibilities of platform providers in two-sided and
multi-sided service markets. These considerations could be a valuable
basis for following in-depth case study research of the suggested types
of value net organization.
References
Armstrong, M., 'Competition in Two-Sided Markets', RAND
Journal of Economics, Vol. 37, 2006, pp. 668-91.
Cailland, B., and B. Jullien, 'Chicken and Egg: Competition
among Intermediation Service Providers', RAND Journal of Economics,
Vol. 34, No. 2, 2003, pp. 309-28.
Dietl, H. M., and T. Schieke, 'Wertschopfung in mehrseitigen
Dienstleistungsmarkten', in M. Bruhn und B. Stauss (Hrsg.), Forum
Dienstleistungsmanagement, Wiesbaden: Gabler, 2007, pp. 121-40.
Dietl, H. M., S. Royer, and U. Stratmann,
'Wertschopfungsorganisation und Differenzierungsdilemma in der
Automobilindustrie', Working Paper No. 64, Institute for Strategy
and Business Economics, University of Zurich, Working Paper Series, ISSN 1660-1157, May 2007.
Dietl, H. M., and S. Royer, 'Intra-System Competition and
Innovation in the International Videogame Industry', Innovation:
Management, Policy & Practice, Vol. 5, No. 2/3, 2003, pp. 158-169.
Farrell, J., and G. Saloner, 'Competition, Compatibility and
Standards: The Economics of Horses, Penguins and Lemmings', in H.L.
Gabel (Hrsg.), Product Standardization and Competitive Startegy,
Amsterdam, 1987, pp. 1-21.
Hallowell, R., and C. Reavis, 'Monster.com: Success Beyond the
Bubble', Harvard Business School Case Study, 9-802-024, 2002.
Katz, M. L., and C. Shapiro, 'Technology Adoption in the
Presence of Network Externalities', Journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 94, No. 4, 1986, pp. 822-841.
Larrson, R., and D. Bowen, 'Organization and Customer:
Managing Design and Coordination of Services', Academy of
Management Review, Vol. 14, No. 2, 1989, pp. 213-233.
Mahoney, J. T. and J. R. Pandian, 'The Resource-Based View Within the Conversation of Strategic Management', Strategic
Management Journal, Vol. 13, No. 5, 1992, pp. 363-80.
Peteraf, M. A., 'The Cornerstones of Competitive Advantage: A
Resource-Based View', Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 14, No. 3,
1993, pp. 179-91.
Porter, M. E., 'Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining
Superior Performance', New York: The Free Press, 1985.
Rochet, J.C. and J. Tirole, 'Platform Competition in Two-sided
Markets', Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 1, No.
4, 2001, pp. 990-1029.
Royer, S., 'Strategic Management and Online-Selling: Creating
Competitive Advantage with Intangible Web Goods', Routledge
Advances in Management and Business Studies, London and New York:
Routledge, 2005.
Rumelt, R. P., 'Towards a Strategic Theory of the Firm',
R. B. Lamb, (ed.) Competitive Strategic Management, Englewood Cliffs,
New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1984, 556-70.
Helmut Dietl, Institut fur Strategie und Unternehmensokonomik,
Lehrstuhl fur Services- und Operationsmanagement, Universitat Zurich,
Winterthurer Strasse 92, CH-8006 Zurich
Egon Franck, Institut fur Strategie und Unternehmensokonomik,
Lehrstuhl fur Unternehmensfuhrung und -politik, Universitat Zurich,
Plattenstrasse 14, CH8032 Zurich
Susanne Royer, Internationales Institut fur Management, Professur
fur Allgemeine Betriebswirtschaftslehre, insbes. strategisches und
internationales Management, Universitat Flensburg, Munketoft 3, D- 24937
Flensburg
Figure 3: Horizontal Value Net Organization
No genuine possibilities Genuene possibilities
of differnetation and of differentation and/or
high scalability low scalability
First Autonomy Taking the most
Mover profitable market
segment, possibily
overcoming borders of
scalability
Late Platform cooperation Successive taking of
Mover next profitable market
segments
Figure 4: Vertical Value Net Organization
Penguin Phase Swimming and
Feeding Phase
Design Establishing a critical Taking the value
of Price mass by product creation of other
Structure subsidies and/or market side(s) into
by winning relevant account regarding
reference customers. the distribution of
revenues.
Customer Establishing If necessary,
Selection adequate signalling signalling
and selection and selection
strategies for the requirements have
actors that contribute to be increased to
to value creation improve customer
combined with a quality continuously if
high relevance of of strategic relevacne.
customer quality Outsourcing
Outsourcing Implement self-service concept if possible.
of Value- Otherwise: Trade-off between scalability
adding (no consideration of individual customer
Activities to characteristics from most reasons) and
Customers differentation (development of mechanisms
to take individual customer specificities into
account to be different to competitors in the
eyes of the customers).
Figure 5: Lateral Value Net Organization
No specific Specific investment
investment of of customers
customers
Platform Lateral integration Competition in
monopoly possible but not the market for
necessary complements
No Lateral integration Competition in
platform advantageous the market for
monopoly complements