Incommensurability and the inability of firms to evolve: using science to explain firm failure.
Childers, J. Stephen, Jr. ; Hunt, Judith
INTRODUCTION
Firm survival has been called the ultimate goal of an organization
(Barnard, 1938). While one may assume that survival is a simple target
to reach, it is made more difficult as firms struggle to adapt to
changing market demands (Brown & Eisenhardt, 1995). While numerous
prescriptive offerings are available from academic researchers, for the
business practitioner, translating academic findings into actionable
direction can be daunting.
The purpose of this paper is to more deeply explore one proposed
cause of firm failure: the inability of firms to meet technological
changes in their environment. Firm failure due to environmental change
has been proposed to be a function of the timing of a firm's entry
into technological cycles (Lieberman & Montgomery, 1988), the
inability to escape previous commitments to customers and financial
markets (Christensen & Bower, 1996), or an incapacity to understand
new technology architectures (Henderson & Clark, 1990). While there
is no shortage of conjectures as to how and why technological change
causes firm failure, this paper searches for common ground among these
approaches. Specifically, the authors suggest that the diverse stream of
research into technological failure may be muddying the
practitioner's water. Through a better understanding of the
incommensurable nature of technological progress, as it applies to the
firm, practitioners will be better equipped to survive.
The paper proceeds as follows. First, a review of the technological
change literature is presented, pointing out the key elements of several
research streams as they apply to firm survival. Second, the concept of
incommensurability is introduced and developed. Of key importance to
this research effort is how the concept of incommensurability helps
clarify the technological change-survival connection. Finally, based
upon classic incommensurability theoretical constructs, we provide
practitioners with a prescriptive approach to surviving technological
incommensurability.
This manuscript accomplishes two major goals. For the academic
community, the thoughts outlined in this paper can help to redefine and
refocus the technology change research stream. For the practitioner, the
findings may aid in firm survival.
TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE
According to Schumpeter (1942):
The fundamental impulse, that sets and keeps the capitalist engine
in motion comes from the new consumers' goods, the new methods of
production or transportation, the new markets ... [This process]
incessantly revolutionizes the economic structure from within,
incessantly destroying the old one, incessantly creating a new one.
This process of Creative Destruction is the essential fact about
capitalism. (p. 83)
Schumpeter's writing can be seen as a warning to firms that
changes to their environment will occur and that firm management must be
prepared for them. The danger of these environmental alterations to
firms is the uncertainty created for management in determining when or
how to adequately respond to technological changes as they occur.
Predicting and responding effectively and efficiently to change is vital
to firm survival as firms are capable of making investments in only a
finite spectrum of resources (Barney, 1986). Therefore, firms must
choose carefully which unique behaviors to engage in and when to engage
in them (Dosi, Nelson, & Winter, 2000).
To aid firms in change-related decisions, researchers have
generally investigated technological change as it relates to conditions
within the firm and at the intersection of the firm and its environment.
The theoretical paradigms created in such theories as technology and
innovation management, evolutionary theory, the resource-based view of
the firm, and the learning school analyze change from different
perspectives. As such, a better understanding of each framework helps to
uncover limitations each may possess (Kuhn, 1962).
Investigations into technology and innovation management (TIM)
generally focus on the technological artifact as their unit of study.
This field attempts to show, among other things, the nature of
technological and innovation changes as technologies evolve over time.
Examples of TIM literature include the works of Abernathy and Utterback
(1978) and Gort and Klepper (1982). Due to the researchers' use of
a technology as the unit of analysis, the sociological and political
dimensions that may be present are often ignored. These shortcomings are
often cited by critics who suggest that this perspective is too
simplistic in evaluating the drivers of innovation change. As such,
critics have called for more fine-grained analysis of the causes of
organizational constraints and the impact technological changes have on
industry conditions (McGahan, Argyres, & Baum, 2004).
Evolutionary economics may fill the gap created by the innovation
and technology studies work regarding how technology impacts firms at an
industry level. Stemming from natural science studies examining
biological competition, evolutionary economics views industry through
the lens of economic competition. The evolutionary economist views firms
as unique in that each is the possessor of heterogeneous resources
(nelson & Winter, 1982). In addition, each firm possesses elements
of continuity and may only change within limits. These resources are
deployed to create innovations which are imitated by competitors.
Because each firm is unique, imitation is never precise and the market
chooses and rewards the version most favored. Lacking in the
evolutionary economist accounts, however, is a clear understanding of
the impact made on change by firm resources.
Firm resources are best understood from the perspective of the
resource-based view of the firm. To the resource-based theorist, it is
firm resources, whether financial, human, or organizational, obtained
through acquisition or nurture, which makes each firm unique
(Wernerfelt, 1984; Barney, 1991). These heterogeneous attributes lead to
above average firm profitability (Wernerfelt, 1984). The resource-based
view complements evolutionary theory as evolutionary theory states that
firms are heterogeneous but never provides details about the factors
that create these differences. The resource-based view of the firm, as
it has evolved from the works of Penrose, explains heterogeneity through
idiosyncratic resource deployments (Penrose, 1959). However, the
resource-based view suffers by not providing explicit instructions to
managers as to what resources to stockpile in order to be successful.
Managers are left wondering how the acquisition of one resource over
another makes a difference?
Technology and innovation management, evolutionary economics, and
the resource-based view all apply an economic-based root discipline
(Baum & Rau, 1998) to the technology firm failure debate. As such,
the paradigms are limited in their approach to the technology/firm
failure problem. The learning school, however, supplements these
frameworks by helping firm management determine how to create and deploy
resources for future successes. Therefore, the learning school, through
its borrowing from psychological literature, provides the prescriptive
power missing in the economic based theories. The learning school of
thought suggests that firms are capable of change. Further, it views the
firm as a collection of individuals, who, in turn, are repositories of
knowledge. It is this collective knowledge that is shared and focused
towards the solving of problems and firm growth (Dosi, Winter, &
Teece, 1992). Quinn (1978) suggests that decisions made by firm members
targeting overall firm improvements create a type of "logical
incrementalism." As such, organizational repositories of knowledge
allow, within a bounded pathway, firm adaptation to change. This logical
incrementalism fits nicely with Nelson and Winter's (1982)
evolutionary account of the ability of firms to evolve routines to meet
challenges created by changes in the environment.
Barnett and Burgelman have called for a synthesizing of theory in
order to gain greater insight into "dynamic, path dependent models
that allow for possibly random variation and selection within and among
organizations" (1996, p.7). In fact, management research has been
described as a fish-scale science, in that multiple perspectives from
various base disciplines such as economics and psychology, have been
employed to seek answers to phenomena under study (Baum & Rao,
1998). As an evolving field, management researchers have blended various
theoretical perspectives in an attempt to come closer to the
"truth" of science of management (Mintzberg, Ahlstrand, &
Lampel, 1998). Many researchers search for this "truth" by
synthesizing the base theoretical paradigms presented above. For
example, Henderson and Clark (1990) posit that knowledge of an
innovation means firms have both an understanding of the pieces of a
technology (the components) and also how those pieces or components fit
together (the architecture). According to the authors, firms can
withstand changes to component concepts; however, any disruption in the
architectural knowledge of the firm can disrupt the embedded processes
and knowledge of the firm and can be extremely difficult to overcome.
Therefore, to Henderson and Clark, the decisive factor of whether or not
a firm survives innovation changes is determined by whether or not the
firm's architectural knowledge is enhanced or compromised with the
new technological trajectories. This perspective ties in well with that
of the technology and management literature, the evolutionary ecology literature, the resource-based view of the firm, and Quinn's view
of logical incrementalism.
Christensen and Bower (1996), investigating further the
intersection of environment and firm, suggest that firms competing in a
previous cycle may not have the same economic incentives to explore
innovations. The authors posit, through the blending of economic and
sociological frameworks, that the firm's current customers may not
initially want the successive innovation as it may not fit with their
current product architecture of customer wants and needs. As such, the
established customer base will have little reason to want the existing
producer firm to switch to a new innovation in its early form. This
argument by Christensen and Bower suggests a resource dependence view to
explain why incumbents have a difficult time adjusting to disruptive
innovations. Over time, "disruptive technologies" will match
previous technologies in terms of basic product attributes and excel on
tangent dimensions which will make their use even more attractive to
customers using the previous technology. When this happens, customers
will switch to the new technology, leaving the supplier still
specializing on the previous technology in a diminishing market space.
Furthermore, from an internal political perspective, insecurities and
power plays within the firm can quickly derail development efforts for
the new innovation. As a result, incumbent firms supplying incumbent
technologies ignore or fail to develop new technologies.
Many of these investigations into blended theory support the notion
set forth by DiMaggio and Powell (1983) that firms can be viewed as
operating in an iron cage caused by social arrangement. This iron cage
leaves the firm constrained in terms of both strategy and imagination
(Dobbin & Baum, 2000). As a fish-scale of science, can the
management study of technological change and failure learn from another
existing area of science, or are organizational researchers stuck in our
own "iron cage"? We suggest that an overlooked and important
perspective ignored to this point is the application of
incommensurability to the technology and firm failure debate.
INCOMMENSURABILITY
To the Greeks the term incommensurability meant "no common
measure." For example, when trying to compare the sides of a square
to its diagonal, the lengths of the sides are not the same ratio as the
diagonal of the square. "Two lengths have a common measure if you
can lay m of the first lengths against exactly n of the second"
(Hacking, 1983, p. 67). Care must be made not to confuse
incommensurability with incompatibility. With incompatibility you can
measure two items with the same scale to determine if one is indeed
different from the other; whereas, one cannot do this with
incommensurability because there is no common scale (for example, how
would you compare a liquid measure to minutes?). Kuhn (1962, p. 99)
provides a good example of incommensurability when he compares the
outcomes of newtonian dynamics with that of relativistic dynamics.
According to Kuhn, you cannot directly compare the two. Relativistic theory has allowed scientists to move along much further in knowledge
than we would be if constrained to newtonian physics. However, newtonian
physics is still in use and can arrive at close approximations of
solutions for a number of instances. Why? Because, for example,
Newtonian mass does not apply the same meaning to "mass" as
does relativity theory to "mass." The two are, therefore,
incommensurable. Each theory may be in use by some problem solver, and
may arrive at some unique outcome. However, those outcomes may not be
equal in terms of answer specificity.
The concept of incommensurability is ubiquitous in the philosophy
of science literature, as philosophers and researchers use it to
debate the place and role of paradigms in the search of knowledge
and to compare scientific theories (paradigm in this case is meant
to refer to those definitions used by Kuhn, 1962). Hacking (1983,
p. 67) defines three types of incommensurability:
topic-incommensurability, dissociation, and
meaning-incommensurability. This paper suggests that items, and in
turn the meaning applied to them, are a result of the sense that we
apply to them, and these meanings have consequences in regards to
our actions upon them. We are applying an anti-realism type, what
Hacking defined as meaning incommensurability, in this paper. As
such, we are focusing on the meaning applied to unobservable
constructs, for which terms used to describe paradigms are,
themselves, meaning-laden. While we can all point to a tree and
define it as "tree" because we can sense what the term is referring
to, we cannot do that for unobservable constructs.
Scherer (1998) points out that the concept of incommensurability
always refers to an association or relationship among entities, "A
is incommensurable with B relative to a system of reference C, which
defines the rules of comparison or measurement. A and B can be regarded
as opinions, theses, assertions, paradigms, world views, etc." (p.
149). Scherer (1998) asserts that incommensurability may be present when
three conditions are met.
First, there have to be at least two (radically) different systems
of orientation. Second, these systems of orientation must be
competing with each other concerning a way of acting or using
language, e.g. the definition or solution of a concrete problem so
that coexistence of the different perspectives is not possible.
Third, an accepted system of reference to objectively evaluate the
competing perspectives must be lacking. (p. 150)
Arrow viewed the firm as a collection of individuals creating
learned activities and behaviors (1962). Pitt (1998) writes, "A
technological infrastructure is a complex set of mutually supporting
individuals, artifacts, networks, and structures, physical and social,
which enable human activity and which foster inquiry and action"
(p. 37). As such, the firm can be seen as a type of technology in and of
itself. Kogut and Zander (1992) posit, "the capabilities of the
firm in general are argued to rest in the organizing principles by which
relationships among individuals, within and between groups, and among
organizations are structured" (p. 384). These capabilities stem
from the past knowledge collected and how it is arranged and assimilated
into the organization (Cohen & Levinthall, 1990). Therefore, the
structure of the firm does impact the way it creates and responds to
technological changes. Further, when a situation arises where two firms
are creating two competing technologies, based upon different
technological underpinnings, competing against each other in a
marketplace for dominance, incommensurability may be present. This point
is acknowledged by Scherer (1998), "one can imagine a situation in
which managers do not agree about the interpretation of an organization
problem or strategic issue.... creating a situation of
incommensurability" (p. 150).
INCOMMENSURABILITY AND TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE
The findings presented in this paper suggest incommensurability may
be a significant cause of firm failure in response to technological
change. Just as "a successor theory may attack different problems,
use new concepts and have implications different from old theories"
(Hacking, 1983, p.68), new technological trajectories can do the same
(Dosi, 1982). According to Kuhn (1962), the following conditions may
lead competing firms into an incommensurable morass:
* Proponents of competing paradigms will often disagree about the
list of problems of competing paradigms any candidate for paradigm must
resolve;
* New paradigms "borrow" the language of the old, but
mean different things;
* Proponents practice their trade in different world-- one fast,
one slow. (pp 148-150)
An example of this can be seen in the computer memory storage
devices (an example employed by Burgleman, 1994). Firm A currently
manufactures 5.25 inch floppy discs. These discs have the ability to
store a certain amount of information. By changing the way the disc
stores this information, firm A is able to increase the storage capacity
of the 5.25 inch floppy by 25%. The manufacture of the floppy and the
basic architecture utilized in its manufacture is essentially the same
in both processes. No new internal technologies are thus required for
the production of this improved disc. This would be an example of a firm
creating a sustaining technology. These technologies are predominantly
created by industry incumbents (those firms already operating in an
existing market) and are generally well accepted by consumers, as there
is little need to change their preferences or methods of usage for the
new technology (Bower & Christensen, 1995). In this situation the
firm's current "gestalt," including the language and
knowledge of both the technology as artifact and technology as system,
remains intact. no disruption to the firm is predicted.
However, a second type of technological change is described by
Christensen (1992). Using our floppy storage devices again as an
example, if firm B were to create a new storage device that uses a
fundamentally different type of architecture in its creation (Henderson
& Clark, 1990), and required a change in the way consumers use this
technology (e.g. the need for a new disc drive and technological
system); then, firm B would have created a potentially disruptive
technology if it grows in market share and surpasses the market share of
the previous technology produced by firm A (Bower & Christensen,
1995). When this event happens, firm A will be in a situation of playing
catch-up to firm B. This may not be an easy task, however, as firm B
will be viewed by customers and investors as more innovative than A.
This leads us to our first assertion. Specifically, we suggest:
Proposition 1: Firms will find it difficult to make architectural
technological changes to their existing technological knowledge base.
Why is it that industry incumbents usually create sustaining
technologies while the disruptive technologies are left to new entrants?
We argue that the theorized reasons of firm inertia or architectural
incompetence are all symptoms of the firm's inability to change its
gestalt. Following Kuhn's account, firm A does not understand the
new standards during a paradigm shift, in this case a disruptive
technological change. Further, the incumbent may not even understand
what they do not know. Lindsay and Norman (1977) have suggested that in
organization settings it is not enough for the firm to simply be exposed
to new ideas because firm memory may not be in place through which
understanding is possible. To fully integrate new knowledge the firm
will need to screen the new knowledge through previous assimilated
knowledge (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). The firm, in essence, is unable
to change the internal technologies, the way work is done, and its
learned behaviors and activities it has come accustomed to employing
(Arrow, 1962). These inabilities can be seen at all levels of
technologies: the firm will find it difficult to change fundamental
production processes, the firm will find it difficult to serve new
product innovations, and the firm will have difficulty adjusting
structural dimensions. The very rigidities that ensured controls and
thus success in the old paradigm have become dysfunctional. The
architectural means employed for such a long period of time become its
"iron cage" (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). In the end, the
incumbent firm will be on the outside looking in as others find favor of
key constituencies, such as consumers and investor markets. Therefore,
we suggest:
Proposition 2: The reason for the inability to change stems from
the application or development of incommensurable theories of
innovation.
At this point, firm A may have become aware of firm B's
advances and firm A will search for ways to adjust to its environment.
If firm B's newly created cycle is incommensurable to the cycle in
which Firm A was competing, firm A would need a gestalt change in order
to survive. At times, firm A may believe it understands the new cycle
and management feels confident of succeeding. But, can it? Firm
knowledge consists of different dimensions of knowledge: tacit versus
explicit; observable versus unobservable; complex versus simple; and
system bound versus independent (Winter, 1987). Much of the knowledge
needed for new technological cycles is difficult to transfer as these
knowledge structures play at the intersection of the explicit and the
tacit (nonaka, 1991, 1994). As a result, firms may not understand or be
able to properly interpret what they are observing as one cycle is
incommensurable to the other. The language employed by firm A is not the
language and understanding held by the current environment (customers
and investors).
Proposition 3: Even though a firm may become aware of technological
changes, the tacit nature of knowledge, and the incommensurable meanings
associated with them, may make it impossible for the firm to properly
integrate the new knowledge.
Lauden contends that theories can be compared and discussed if one
goes back to some "joint problem" from which both pathways
were derived (1977, p. 144). Perhaps the same can be said for the firm:
go back to the basics of the technological system and rethink the value
added proposition. As stated by Kuhn (1962, p. 112) "At times of
revolution, when the normal-scientific tradition changes, the
scientist's perception of his environment must be re-educated--in
some familiar situations he must learn to see a new gestalt." This
brings us to the fourth proposition:
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Proposition 4: During architectural changes incumbents may lag as
they strive to understand evolving competitive priorities.
Incumbents can be in a situation where the new technology exists
beyond their realm of understanding. That is, the incumbents are
technologically so far behind they cannot catch up with this new round
of technology. According to Spender and Scherer, "we cannot
recognize uncertainty as knowledge-absence from a context we know enough
about to notice the absence, which is then an aspect of situated
experience of puzzling sense-data or unresolved questions. We cannot
discover a knowledge absence in a knowledge vacuum" (2007, p. 16).
Kuhn (1962) suggests that when new paradigms, or technological
cycles, are encountered, firms should apply new theories, or gestalts,
as they will fit the facts of the new environment better than the old
gestalt. This situation is detailed in Figure 1. The figure shows that a
firm in current technological cycle X uses language X. When encountering
a new technological cycle, X+1, a new language, X+1, must also be used.
If a firm does not "learn" a new language, it will be
attempting to compete with an old gestalt, X-1. This language may not be
appropriate in the new technological cycle. As a result, firms will lose
ground relative to competitors. To combat this, a firm may be able to
use its antiquated gestalt to make advances at a component level of a
technology.
These observations lead us to the following proposition:
Proposition 5: During architectural changes incumbents will need to
"learn" a new language or drop to component level.
Finally, firm A, left behind in the gestalt switch, may need help
understanding the language of the new technological cycle. Absent the
ability to understand what it is the firm needs to learn and understand,
the firm will need to seek the help of others, perhaps best accomplished
through networking. According to von Hippel (1988), "trading of
know-how often requires the establishment of long-term relationships in
which the exchange occurs within a learned and shared code" (p.
118). The exchange of this code may aid firm A in changing its gestalt
to match the new environment in which it operates. The networking in
this instance may come in the form of attending conferences and shows,
collaborating with "knowledgeable" firms in new product
development, or through the acquisition of skills through purchase.
Through these techniques, firm A will be able to better understand the
new gestalt, and signal to outside investors and customers its growth
and development as a firm. This brings us to the final proposition:
Proposition 6: During architectural changes incumbents will need to
network in order to assimilate to different constituency perceptions.
DISCUSSION
Based upon the findings of this research, Figure 2 presents
prescriptive offerings to firm management as to how to adjust to changes
in technological cycles.
The 3x2 matrix in figure 2 is a function of the current firm
language or gestalt (found on the vertical axis) and the technological
language or gestalt embraced by the environment (found on the horizontal
axis). Three scenarios for firm language are suggested, ranging from
language that languishes behind that currently accepted by the
environment (X-1), one in which the firm's language matches that
currently in favor (X), and a final situation in which the firm is ahead
of the language currently accepted (X+1). In terms of change
experienced, a change may be incremental in nature (Y) or disruptive in
nature (Y+1).
When a firm's language is behind that currently in favor and
it faces an incremental change (X-1, Y), our findings suggest that the
firm in question may be experiencing rigidities in its organization
stemming from past inabilities to evolve. In this case, the firm will
need to partner and learn new language. If, however, the firm is facing
a disruptive change (X-1, Y+1), the firm is two cycles behind and may
find it extremely difficult to catch up to its new environment. Its best
option may be to harvest its current operations.
A firm current in its language (X) is expected to have little
trouble from incommensurability should it face incremental changes (X,
Y). However, should it face a disruptive change (X, Y+1), the
firm's current gestalt may be incommensurable and it will need to
partner and learn the new embraced language.
A third set of scenarios is uncovered from firms possessing a
mindset ahead of its environment (X+1). Little researched by management
theorists to this point, this stage is predicted to face similar perils
as that of the language laggards (X-1). Specifically, the firm in this
situation (X+1, Y), has a choice: it can wait for the environment to
catch up with its mindset, or it can attempt to educate those to its new
worldview or gestalt. Either proposition requires resources and it is
expected that this drain may be equivalent to that of the laggard. The
final scenario is when the advanced firm finds itself in a situation
where its gestalt is being favored in a disruptive change (X+1, Y+1).
This is an ideal situation and the firm can be expected to reap the
rewards from it investments.
CONCLUSIONS
The inability of some firms to adapt to new technological demands
has been well documented in the strategic management literature. Some
have argued that this inability to meet competitive pressures stems from
the development of core rigidities leading to the failure to identify
and make strategic changes as needed (Leonard-Barton, 1992). Other
researchers have focused on the inability to accurately understand what
customers want; or even the fact that the firm listens too closely to
its customers (Christensen & Bower, 1996).
This paper does not counter these arguments; instead, our purpose
is to provide order to the various explanations. We argue that the above
mentioned explanations are merely symptoms of a much larger issue for
the failing firm. The technologies utilized by a firm, in terms of its
processes, products, and structure, are its theories of the world: its
gestalt. We suggest that the main reason for the inability of firms to
adjust as needed during disruptive technological changes is due to
technological incommensurability. Put simply, the laggard firm does not
understand the language of the new environment. Its gestalt is
inappropriate to the new gestalt and language embraced by investors and
customers. The two are incommensurable.
For the management researcher, the findings presented here provide
new avenues to aid in understanding firm failure during architectural
changes, along with new ideas for firm prescriptions. Further, this
research presents several propositions for testing. Through the
confirmation or refutation of our conjectures, gains in knowledge of the
firm and how it responds to changes are possible (Popper, 1963). In
addition, this research may create a common ground among the diversity
of technological failure literature. In this way, this work may serve as
an integrationist, unifying isolationist paradigms (Burrell &
Morgan, 1979). Integrating academic works will aid organizational
researchers in better serving practitioner needs. Failure to do so may
place academics "in danger of becoming irrelevant" (Scherer,
1998, p. 151).
For practitioners this research serves as a guide to survival
during technological changes. Scherer suggests that incommensurability
arises in the practice of businesses when "managers do not agree
about the interpretation about an organization problem or strategic
issue" (Scherer, 1998, p. 150). Because of many different potential
factors such as personal experiences, orientations (such as finance or
marketing), values or even potential personal outcomes, one set of
managers may not be able to comprehend the need for radical change while
another set of managers is certain the lack of change will result either
in an inferior competitive position or death of the firm. Architectural
changes in technology require a major new commitment in both capital and
knowledge to the firm. Those managers associated with the old technology
will see the potential for their power diminishing. This denigrates the
value of their experience and their usefulness to the organization.
While rationality is believed to prevail in for-profit firms, the
reality is human beings will often sub-optimize the goals of the
organization to optimize their own personal outcomes. By better
understanding the way through which technological incommensurability
hinders firms from making strategic adjustments as needed, firm
management can take steps to counter the problem. Making the proper
changes will help achieve main goal of the firm: survival (Barnard,
1938).
REFERENCES
Abernathy, W.J., & Utterback, J.M. (1978). Patterns of
industrial innovation. Technology Review, 80(7), 40-47.
Arrow, K.J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing.
Review of Economic Studies, 29(3), 155-173.
Barnard, C.I. (1938). Functions of the executive. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Barnett, W.P., & Burgelman, R.A. (1996). Evolutionary
perspectives on strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 17 (Special
Issue: Evolutionary Perspectives on Strategy), 5-19.
Barney, J.B. (1986). Strategic factor markets--expectations, luck,
and business strategy. Management Science, 32(10), 1230-1241.
Barney, J.B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive
advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120.
Baum, J.A.C., & Rao, H. (1998). Strategic management as a
fish-scale multiscience. In J.A.C. Baum (Ed.), Disciplinary roots of
strategic management: Vol. 15. Advances in strategic management (pp.
1-16). Stamford: JAI Press Inc.
Bower, J.L., & Christensen, C.M. (1995). Disruptive
technologies--catching the wave. Harvard Business Review, 73(1), 43-53.
Brown, S., & Eisenhardt, K. (1995). Product development: Past
research, present findings, and future directions. Academy of Management
Review, 20 (2), 343-378.
Burgelman, R.A. (1994). Fading memories: A process theory of
strategic business exit in dynamic environments. Administrative Science
Quarterly, 39(1), 24-45.
Burrell, G., & Morgan, G. (1979). Sociological paradigms and
organisational analysis. London: Heinemann Educational Books.
Christensen, C.M. (1992). Exploring the limits of the technology
s-curve. Part i: Component technologies; part ii: Architectural
technologies. Production and Operations Management, 1(4), 334-366.
Christensen, C.M., & Bower, J.L. (1996). Customer power,
strategic investment, and the failure of leading firms. Strategic
Management Journal, 17(3), 197-218.
Cohen, W.M., & Levinthal, D.A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A
new perspective in learning and innovation. Administrative Science
Quarterly, 35(1), 178-184.
DiMaggio, P.J., & Powell, W.W. (1983). The iron cage revisited:
Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational
fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2), 147-160.
Dobbin, F., & Baum, J.A.C. (2000). Introduction: Economics
meets sociology in strategic management. In J.A.C. Baum & F. Dobbin
(Eds.), Economics meets sociology in strategic management: Vol. 17.
Advances in Strategic Management (pp. 1-26). Stamford: JAI Press Inc.
Dosi, G. (1982). Technological paradigms and technological
trajectories--a suggested interpretation of the determinants and
directions of technical change. Research Policy, 11(3), 147-162.
Dosi, G., Nelson, R.R., & Winter, S.G. (2000). The nature and
dynamics of organizational capabilities. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Dosi, G., Winter, S.G., & Teece, D.J. (1992). Towards a theory
of corporate coherence: Preliminary remarks, in G. Dosi, R. Giannetti,
& P.A. Toninelli, (Eds.), Technology and Enterprise in a Historical
Perspective (pp. 185-211). Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Gort, M., & Klepper, S. (1982). Time paths in the diffusion of
product innovations. The Economic Journal, 92(367), 630-653.
Hacking, I. (1983). Representing and intervening: Introductory
topics in the philosophy of natural science. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
Henderson, R.M., & Clark, K.B. (1990). Architectural
innovation--the reconfiguration of existing product technologies and the
failure of established firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1),
9-30.
Kogut, B., & Zander, U. (1992). Knowledge of the firm,
combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology.
Organization Science, 3(3), 383-397.
Kuhn, T. (1962). The structure of scientific revolutions. Chicago:
The University of Chicago Press.
Lauden, L. (1977). Progress and its problems. Berkeley: University
of California Press.
Leonard-Barton, D. (1992). Core capabilities and core rigidities: A
paradox in managing new product development. Strategic Management
Journal, 13 (Special Issue: Strategy Process: Managing Corporate
Self-Renewal), 111-125.
Lieberman, M.B., & Montgomery, D.B. (1988). First-mover
advantages. Strategic Management Journal, 9 (Special Issue: Strategy
Content Research), 41-58.
Lindsay, P.H., & Norman, D.A. (1977). Human information
processing. Orlando, FL: Academic Press.
McGahan, A.M., Argyres, N.S., & Baum, J.A.C. (2004). Context,
technology and strategy: Forging new perspectives on the industry life
cycle. In J.A.C. Baum & A.M. McGahan (Eds.), Business strategy over
the industry lifecycle: Vol. 21. Advances in strategic management (pp.
1-21). Stamford: JAI Press, Inc.
Mintzberg, H., Ahlstrand, B., & Lampel, J. (1998). Strategy
safari: A guided tour through the wilds of strategic management. New
York: Free Press.
Nelson, R.R., & Winter, s.G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of
economic change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.
Nonaka, I. (1991, November-December). The knowledge-creating
company. Harvard Business Review, 96-104.
Nonaka, I. (1994). A dynamic theory of organizational knowledge
creation. Organization Science, 5(1), 14-37.
Penrose, E.T. (1959). The theory of the growth of the firm. New
York: John Wiley.
Pitt, J.C. (1998). Explaining change in science. Techne: Journal of
the Society for Philosophy and Technology, 3(3), 36-45.
Popper, K. (1963). Conjectures and refutations: The growth of
scientific knowledge. New York: Harper Torchbooks.
Quinn, J.B. (1978). Strategic change: Logical incrementalism. Sloan
Management Review, 20(1), 7-21.
Scherer, A.G. (1998). Pluralism and incommensurability in strategic
management: A problem in search of a solution. Organization, 5(2),
147-168.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New
York: Harper.
Spender, J.C., & Scherer, A.G. (2007). The philosophical
foundation of knowledge management: Editor's introduction.
Organization, 14(1), 5-28.
von Hippel, E. (1988). The sources of innovation. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic
Management Journal, 5(2), 171-180.
Winter, S.G. (1987). Knowledge and competence as strategic assets.
In D. Teece (Ed.) The competitive challenge-strategies for industrial
innovation and renewal (pp. 159-184). Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
J. Stephen Childers, Jr.
Assistant Professor
Department of Management
Radford University
jchilders2@radford.edu
Judith Hunt
Associate Professor
Department of Management
East Carolina University
Figure 2: Prescriptive Accounts of Technological Incommensurability
Technological Language Accepted by Environment
Firm Y (Incremental) Y+1 (Disruptor)
Language
Poor Innovation Results
X-1 from Rigidities. Need Harvesting strategy: firm
internal learning decay
dissemination
Gap in understanding
Possible Positive Results- technological futures.
X Incremental improvements External learning needed
or drop to component
level.
X+1 Ahead of the curve. Do we Strong results possible
wait or teach our as the firm is industry
language? trendsetter.