首页    期刊浏览 2024年10月07日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:A fuzzy logic enhanced bargaining model for business pricing decision support in joint venture projects/Fuzzy loginio pasikeitimu vertinimo metodo taikymas jungtines veiklos projektu vertei nustatyti.
  • 作者:Yan, Min-Ren
  • 期刊名称:Journal of Business Economics and Management
  • 印刷版ISSN:1611-1699
  • 出版年度:2011
  • 期号:June
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Vilnius Gediminas Technical University
  • 摘要:As a response to the changing business environment and diverse market demands, strategic alliances have been considered as effective business models for creating competitive advantages. In recent decades, project businesses are increasingly emerging and many companies cooperatively participate in various projects by the manner of joint venture (JV). The project-based short-term alliances are especially popular in the construction industry (Norwood and Mansfield 1999). Since construction projects have become larger and more complex, a growing number of projects have exceeded the scope that can be handled by a single company. The desire for and search for collaborators to achieve synergistic competitiveness is the prime motive for companies to collaborate (Xu et al. 2005). Through the manipulation of the appropriate resources, a JV may bring about different kinds of benefits to participating companies, such as risk sharing, resource complementarities, reduced cost, knowledge sharing, and technology transfer (Tam 1999; Munns et al. 2000; Nicolini et al. 2001; Proverbs and Holt 2000; Simchi-Levi et al. 2001). JV has become an important strategy for construction companies in response to the increasing demands in the construction industry. The JV teams can also be significantly competitive for the projects delivered by the qualification-based selection system (Lo and Yan 2009).
  • 关键词:Decision making;Decision-making;Fuzzy algorithms;Fuzzy logic;Fuzzy systems;Game theory;Joint ventures;Paper industry;Pricing;Strategic alliances (Business)

A fuzzy logic enhanced bargaining model for business pricing decision support in joint venture projects/Fuzzy loginio pasikeitimu vertinimo metodo taikymas jungtines veiklos projektu vertei nustatyti.


Yan, Min-Ren


1. Introduction

As a response to the changing business environment and diverse market demands, strategic alliances have been considered as effective business models for creating competitive advantages. In recent decades, project businesses are increasingly emerging and many companies cooperatively participate in various projects by the manner of joint venture (JV). The project-based short-term alliances are especially popular in the construction industry (Norwood and Mansfield 1999). Since construction projects have become larger and more complex, a growing number of projects have exceeded the scope that can be handled by a single company. The desire for and search for collaborators to achieve synergistic competitiveness is the prime motive for companies to collaborate (Xu et al. 2005). Through the manipulation of the appropriate resources, a JV may bring about different kinds of benefits to participating companies, such as risk sharing, resource complementarities, reduced cost, knowledge sharing, and technology transfer (Tam 1999; Munns et al. 2000; Nicolini et al. 2001; Proverbs and Holt 2000; Simchi-Levi et al. 2001). JV has become an important strategy for construction companies in response to the increasing demands in the construction industry. The JV teams can also be significantly competitive for the projects delivered by the qualification-based selection system (Lo and Yan 2009).

To form a JV team, companies have to select partner(s), assign each party's work scope, and especially, negotiate the sharing of rewards, which is usually done by arranging separate amounts of the expected total rewards or by sharing proportionally, depending on the collaborating relationships among the JV teams. However, in a negotiation, two parties may have different objectives and conflicts (Saee 2008). Since each JV party is pursuing its maximum reward, the conflicts of interest make the sharing of rewards always a challenging task. Lai (1989) pointed out that bargaining is needed when a conflict lies between participating parties, and communications and compromises are required to reach an agreement. Raiffa (1982) proposed the concept of "zone of agreement", which can be figured out by deducting the lowest, acceptable price for each party from the total amount. As each party strives for its maximum price, which is also acceptable to the other party, in the "zone", bargaining usually is carried out through numerous repetitions of offer-and-counteroffer until an agreement is reached, or the bargaining is given up.

Bargaining in the construction industry is quite different from other industries. The collaborations between JV parties are usually on a short-term, project-to-project basis and the time allowed for bargaining is strictly limited. Since time factor is crucial in this type of negotiation, the JV parties may be forced to make a concession because of the need to submit a bid on time. Thus, how to evaluate a bargaining situation and offer a price acceptable to both parties in a timely manner is critical for the success of a JV project. However, current practices still lack a systematic tool or model for supporting a company's pricing decisions. The research aim is to fill the gap.

There are many factors that could affect a company's pricing on a specific project. However, previous research has pointed the outcome of bargaining is highly influenced by the stakes of the bargainers, the bargainer's level of dependence on the outcome of bargining (Bacharach and Edward 1981). Accordingly, this research focused on the variable, need for the revenue from the project, which is used to represent company's level of dependence on the profit from a JV project. A sequential bargaining model is developed, based upon game theory, which is used to estimate acceptable prices in accordance with each party's costs and needs. The game theory perspective helps decision makers to take into account not only the current strategy of the competitor, but his forthcoming responsive actions as well (Ginevicius and Krivka 2008). Furthermore, fuzzy logic is used to quantify a company's need for the revenue from the project, which always features a certain degree of uncertainty. The applications of fuzzy logic enhance the bargaining model to support quantitative analysis and operational research of bargaining strategies.

2. The sequential bargaining model

Game theory has been defined as "the study of mathematical models of conflict and cooperation between intelligent rational decision-makers" and successfully applied to many important issues, such as negotiations, finance, and imperfect markets. It allows researchers to find mathematical solutions of conflict situations (Peldschus 2008). Based on the concept of dynamic games, the bargaining between two parties of a JV team is modeled as a sequential bargaining process. In this model, the JV parties are termed as "players".

2.1. Basic symbols and definitions

In the game theoretical analysis, the rationale of players' behavior is to maximize their payoffs calculated based on quantified considerations and both players are assumed risk neutral, while the utility function can be used to modify this model in cases where the players have other risk attitudes. Definitions of each basic symbol and assumption in the model are as follows:

* k represents players in the bargaining, while a refers to player A and b refers to player B.

* n represents round of bargaining. Each player's offer accounts for a round.

* E represents total contract amount estimated based on announced budget information and market price. The total contract amount is assumed the award price. As agreement is reached, the total contract amount is the sum of the payment obtained by player A (a*) and the payment obtained by player B (b*).

* [a.sub.n] represents player A's quotation for its work scope in the nth round. In this model, player A makes the first offer, [a.sub.1], in the 1st round for its work scope. Further, since both parties take turns to offer a price, only when the number of round is odd (n = 1, 3, 5, ...) player A can offer its price.

* [b.sub.n] represents player B's quotation for its work scope in the nth round. As assumed above, first player A offers [a.sub.1] in the 1st round for its work scope, and then player B may make a counteroffer, [b.sub.2], for its work scope. Since both parties take turns to offer, only when the number of round is even (n = 2, 4, 6, ...) player B can offer its price.

* [C.sub.k] represents cost estimated by the player k according to individual work scopes. [C.sub.a] indicates player A's cost; [C.sub.b] indicates player B's cost. Since information associated with market prices of materials and labor is quite open, it is assumed in this research that both parties in the bargaining can obtain clear awareness of each other's cost.

* F represents total profit of the project (total profit plus total cost of the project equals the total contract amount).

* P represents probability of failure in the bargaining.

* [L.sub.k(n)] represents the loss of potential profits when agreement is not settled.

2.2. Sequential bargaining process

In this model, it is assumed that bargaining begins with the offer proposed by player A in round 1 (n = 1), and there are three possible reponses from player B: (a) accepts the offer, (b)rejects the offer and closes the bargaining, and (c) makes a counteroffer. If player B makes a counteroffer, then similarly, player A may accept, reject, or make a counteroffer to player B. Usually the bargaining is an offer-counteroffer process till the nth round, when an agreement is reached, or the bargaining is given up. Accordingly, different rewards or losses in each round are expected (as shown in Fig. 1). At the nth round, it could be player A's or player B's turn to make the offer. Nevertheless, in the bargaining model shown in Fig. 1, it is assumed that it is player A's turn to propose the offer.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

2.3. Equilibrium of sequential bargaining

In order to understand how players behave in the sequential bargaining process, this research introduced the concept of "Nash equilibrium", one of the most important concepts in game theory. Nash equilibrium refers to a situation in which individuals participating in a game pursue the best possible strategy while possessing the knowledge of the strategies of other players. In Nash equilibrium, each player's strategy should respond to the other player's strategy, and no player wants to deviate from the equilibrium solution (Myerson 1991). Thus, the equilibrium price of sequential bargaining process is a best price for both parties under the sets of information and bargaining situation.

The equilibrium of sequential bargaining can be solved through "backward induction" (Gibsons 1992). According to the method, whether a player accepts the counterpart's offer depends on his expectation of rewards in the next round. Only when the reward offered by the counterpart exceeds or equals what is expected would a player accept the offer and settle the agreement. So, if player A offers the highest price of [a.sub.n] at the nth round (n [greater than or equal to] 3), a potential loss, [PL.sub.a(n)], may be incurred, thus the expected payoff of player A in the nth round is as Eqn. (1):

[a.sub.n] - [PL.sub.a(n)]. (1)

Furthermore, since player B knows that, in the (n-1)th round, any price higher than Eqn. (1) would be accepted by player A, player B's best offer in the (n-1)th round is as Eqn. (2):

E - [a.sub.n] + [PL.sub.a(n)]. (2)

Similarly, for player B, in the (n-1)th round, the expected payoff in the (n-1)th round is as Eqn. (3):

E - [a.sub.n] + [PL.sub.a(n)] - [PL.sub.b(n-1)]. (3)

In addition, since player A understands that, in the (n-2)th round, any price higher than Eqn. (3) would be accepted by player B, and player A's offer in the (n-2)th round is as Eqn. (4):

[a.sub.n] - [PL.sub.a(n)] + [PL.sub.b(n-1)]. (4)

As a summary of the aforementioned description, Table 1 shows the prices acceptable to player A and player B in the last three rounds as induced by backward induction.

Based on the concept of equilibrium, the player cannot produce a price better than [a.sub.n]. Therefore, the equilibrium price can only be solved when player A's offer in the nth and (n-2)th round is the same as Eqn. (5):

[a.sub.n] = [a.sub.n] - [PL.sub.a(n)] + [PL.sub.b(n-1)]. (5)

Since bargaining between players is a repetitive process of offer-counteroffer, when the round of bargaining n [right arrow] [infinity], the P in each round will be very close. Thus, in this model, the probabilities of failure in any bargaining round are assumed the same and Eqn. (5) can be simplified as Eqn. (6):

[L.sub.a(n)] = [L.sub.b(n-1)]. (6)

2.4. Equilibrium price function

In this research, [L.sub.k(n)] is the loss of potential profits in the JV project. However, bargaining theory (Bacharach and Edward 1981) suggests that potential profits considered by a player in the bargaining should be additional profit which can not be gained from other projects. If a player has other opportunities that may earn the same amount of profit, there is no potential profit for this project. Therefore, this research developed a variable, need for the project ([S.sub.k]), to encompass the above concept. Losses expected by player A and player B are as Eqn. (7) and Eqn. (8) respectively.

[L.sub.a(n)] = (E - [b.sub.n-1] - [C.sub.a]/[C.sub.a])[S.sub.a], (7)

[L.sub.b(n)] = (E - [a.sub.n-1] - [C.sub.b]/[C.sub.b])[S.sub.b]. (8)

It is common that player A and player B of the JV team may invest on different scales. Thus, the [L.sub.k(n)] is evaluated on the unit basis for the sake of fairness. Value of [S.sub.k] is assumed to fall between 0 and 1; the higher the value, the higher the need for the project, and vice versa. The value 1 indicates that the player has no other opportunities, which can earn the same amount of profit as this project. 0 indicates that the player can earn the same profit from other opportunities and does not need the profit at all.

Since bargaining between players is a process of offer-counteroffer, both players tend to gradually lower their offers to reach an agreement. When the bargaining reaches n [right arrow] [infinity], it can be inferred that the players' offers will converge and players' offers in the last three rounds tend to be the same. Thus, [a.sub.n-2], [a.sub.n], and a* can be considered equal and the same principle applies to [b.sub.n-3], [b.sup.n-1], and b*. Eqn. (9) can be derived by substituting Eqn. (7) and (8) given for [L.sup.a(n)] and [L.sub.b(n)] in Eqn. (6):

[a.sub.n] = E - [C.sub.b] - (E - [b.sub.n-1] - [C.sub.a])[C.sub.b][S.sub.a]/[C.sub.a][S.sub.b]. (9)

Based on the definitions of this research, the total contract amount, E, is the sum of a* and b*, while total profit plus total cost of the project equals the total contract amount. Thus, an equilibrium price function can be derived from Eqn. (9) as Eqn. (10):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (10)

Eqn. (10) can be promptly used to suggest player A's offer as an acceptable price for both parties. In most cases, the required parameters of the equation, [C.sub.a], [C.sub.b], and F are already established before bargaining, while [S.sub.a] and [S.sub.b] are not. Thus, [S.sub.a] and [S.sub.b] are two key variables for determining the price. Through Eqn. (10), the impacts of [S.sub.k] on company's offers can be analyzed by using a fixed [S.sub.b] with different values of [S.sub.a]. It is found that player A's suggested offer decreases as the [S.sub.a] increases (see Fig. 2).

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

This scenario is more significant as the [S.sub.b] decreases. Similarly, this research tests the suggested offers based on a fixed [S.sub.a] with different values of [S.sub.b], and finds that the suggested offer increases as the [S.sub.b] increases (see Fig. 3). This scenario is more significant as the [S.sub.a] decreases. To summarize these results, a company with relatively high need for the project is likely to lose more of the profit of the JV project.

3. Fuzzy rule-based estimation of company's demand for the project

Based on the aforementioned equilibrium price function, individual company's demand for the project would have an impact on the equilibrium price. Thus, quantitative analysis of the need for the project is essential and it can be enabled by using fuzzy logic. In a JV team, each party can obtain business information and speculate on its partner's "need for the project" (S) through public or private information channels. For example, the awareness that the counterpart has not taken any construction project in the past six months and opportunities for construction projects will be rare in the following six months suggests that the counterpart's "S" must be high. However, it is difficult to transform the above information and linguistic variables into a specific value to facilitate the decision-making. To the imprecise data or linguistic variables, fuzzy logic is a widely used approach in helping decision making (Arslan and Aydin 2009). Therefore, this research incorporates fuzzy logic to quantify the "S" of each party and enable further quantitative analysis.

3.1. Measure of need for the project

Carr (1987) proposed that a company's pricing should be consistent with its status of business operation. If a company's returns gained from business operations cannot cover its general and administrative expenditures, this company will suffer loss. Thus, if a company's total revenue is expected to fall behind its scheduled revenue target, the company is in an urgent "S" and thus forced to lower its offer for better opportunities. On the contrary, if its scheduled revenue target has been reached, this company's "S" is relatively low. In this research, the degree of "S" is regarded in terms of the company's fulfillment of scheduled revenue target. The lower the degree of scheduled revenue target attainment, the higher the company's "S." The degree of fulfillment of scheduled revenue target is closely related to received revenues and potential business prospects in the future. Moreover, future revenue is associated with future business opportunities and the level of competition. Thus, this research assumes that a company's "S" is influenced by three factors, "received revenues"(R), "future business opportunities"(O), and "level of competition"(L).

3.2. Fuzzy sets and membership functions

Both "R" and "O" are evaluated against the company's degree of attainment of its scheduled revenue target. For example, if "R"/scheduled revenue target yields a value of 0.95 (covering 95% of its scheduled revenue target), it is suggested that this company's "R" is rather high. Both "R" and "O" may exceed scheduled revenue target, so values of these two items range between 0~2 and are further divided into three degrees of "High", "Moderate", and "Low". As for the variable of "L", the value is represented by "number of competitors", which has been the most frequently used criterion for measurement of competition level in previous research. Note that the number of competitors is an adaptive parameter, which is adjustable for specific cases in different industries. Lo et al. (2007) have conducted a nation-wide study on the traffic construction projects in Taiwan and proposes an estimation of the number of competitors ranging from 3 to 13. In this research, we took the estimation for the demonstration of the fuzzy membership function. Therefore, this research ranges the value of "L" from 3 to 15 so as to include some extremely competitive cases (3 competitors is the minimum requirement for open bids); higher values indicate higher level of competition, which is also divided into three levels of "High", "Moderate", and "Low". "S" is defined in the range between 0 and 1, and further divided into three levels of "High", "Moderate", and "Low".

Membership functions commonly used include triangular functions and bell-shaped functions (Yu and Skibniewski 1999). To demonstrate the concept more efficiently, triangular functions are used in this research (see Fig. 4). In a triangular membership function, each triangular fuzzy number has linear representations on its left and right side such that its membership function can be defined as Eqn. (11):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (11)

where s and l represent the smallest and the largest possible values and m represents the most promising value that describes a fuzzy event.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

3.3. Fuzzy if-then rules

To effectuate the composition of the variables considered for estimating a company's demand for the project, fuzzy inference rules can be developed (Costantino and Gravio 2009). The company's perceptions about the counterpart's need for the project can be grouped into three rule categories as follows:

* If a company's "R" is high, and: (a) "O" is high, then expected "S" will be low; (b) in other cases, the expected "S" will be moderate.

* If a company's "R" is moderate, and : (a) "O" is high while "L" is low, then the "S" will be low; (b)"O" is not high, then a high "S" is expected; (c) in other cases, the expected "S" will be moderate.

* If a company's "R" is low, and : (a) "O" is high while "L" is low, then the "S" will be moderate; (b) in other cases, the expected "S" will be high.

* Twenty-seven If-Then rules are developed based on the conbinations of the aforementioned three rule categories (see Table 2).

4. Illustrative case study

Two companies intend to form a JV, so as to bid for a project which consists of 5.5 km of tunneling work and a substation. The assumed amount of the winning bid is 3,229 million dollars. It is agreed that company A handles the station portion and company B handles the tunnel portion. Information for the JV project is summarized in Table 3.

For the company A, the highest price is cost ([C.sub.a]) + estimated total profit (F) = 1,180 million dollars + 279 million dollars = 1,459 million dollars. On the other hand, the highest price of company B is [C.sub.b] + F = 1,770 million dollars + 279 million dollars = 2,049 million dollars. Since the total budget is limited, these prices are hardly acceptable to both parties. Therefore, to expedite the bargaining and make a rational bargaining strategy, both parties need to collect information about each party's need for the project and estimate the values of [S.sub.a] and [S.sub.b]. Based on the information implied in each party's "received revenues", "future business opportunities", and "level of competition", [S.sub.a] and [S.sub.b] estimated by company A are 0.72 and 0.41, respectively. Then the company A that used the equilibrium price function may infer that it may earn 1, 256.77 million dollars while the company B may receive 1, 972.23 million dollars.

If company B's recognition of each party's demand for the project is similar to that of company A, the agreement can be reached immediately. If both party's perceptions about their own and the other part's need for the project differ, conflicts in the bargaining may be incurred. In this situation, the accuracy of the information received should be confirmed by both parties and as more information is exchanged between both parties, the equilibrium price function can be very helpful for both parties to adjust their pricing policy in a timely and rational manner.

Considering a case that the company A can make sure that [S.sub.a] is 0.72, while [S.sub.b] is not definite. By implementing a scenario analysis, the acceptable rewards in different bargaining positions can be estimated by the proposed model. Note that the estimation of high [S.sub.b] represents that company A takes an optimistic bargaining position and low [S.sub.b] for pessimistic bargaining positions. As shown in Fig. 5, the suggested offer based on different sets of [S.sub.b] can be easily obtained. Similarly, company B can lock [S.sub.b] (suppose it is 0.41) and infer the company A's possible offers based on different sets of [S.sub.a] (the rewards willing to share by company B in Fig. 5). In this case, once the reward willing to share by company B is more than the acceptable reward for company A, the agreement can be made.

In addition to figure out the possible individual rewards in various bargaining positions, the scenario analysis can turn to project level by evaluating the total rewards needed with different bargaining positions. As shown in Fig. 6, since the contract amount is fixed, the possibility of agreement can be evaluated by comparing the contract amount and the acceptable total reward. If both parties take too optimistic bargaining positions, then the acceptable total reward might over the contract amount to lower the possibility of agreement. Thus, these objective evaluations give each company a clear guideline for pricing. Irrational alternatives can be detected and eliminated with the support of the proposed model and the functions can help making rational decisions (Sarka et al. 2008).

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

5. Conclusions

During a business bargaining process, many interaction effects might occur due to different levels of presentational and negotiation skills or social psychological phenomena. A proper pricing strategy in the dynamic bargaining process is important for an enterprise because it can ensure right businesses when cooperating with other partners. However, due to the lack of decision support models, business managers tend to adopt a more intuitive and subjective approach to the bargaining problem. Thus, a quantitative decision support model would help decision makers to maintain their bargaining positions and contract price lines. Irrational offers and alternatives can thus be detected and eliminated during the bargaining process.

To solve bargaining problems, many researchers have theoretically focused on the unique equilibrium price by assuming the information for pricing is perfect. However, perfect information situation is not common in real bargaining cases and companies inevitably continuously collect information, evaluate bargaining situations, and repetitively make pricing decisions in the bargaining process. Instead of finding a unique equilibrium price, the approach of this paper is to propose a bargaining decision support model, which can be used to assess the bargaining situation and select a pricing strategy in a scientific and rational manner. With the complementary use of game theory and fuzzy logic, the research results are useful for JV parties to determine the best price based on each party's cost and the estimated degree of need for the JV project, thus can improve the possibility to reach an agreement. In addition, this research provides a quantitative analytic framework for objective business pricing and the framework enables further developments of rational and quantitative bargaining models. With this pilot study, the modeling assumptions can be improved for solving specific bargaining problems and broader applications.

doi: 10.3846/16111699.2011.573281

Acknowledgement

Parts of the research were financially supported by the National Science Council in Taiwan (NSC 99-2628-E-034-001).

References

Arslan, G.; Aydin, O. 2009. A new software development for fuzzy multicriteria decision-making, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(2): 197-212. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.197-212

Bacharach, S. B.; Edward, J. L. 1981. Bargaining Power, Tactics and Outcome. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

Carr, R. I. 1987. Competitive bidding and opportunity costs, Journal of Construction Engineering and Management 113(1): 151-165. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)0733-9364(1987)113:1(151)

Costantino, F.; Gravio, G. D. 2009. Multistage bilateral bargaining model with incomplete information --a fuzzy approach, International Journal of Production Economics 117(2): 235-243. doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2008.09.013

Gibsons, R. 1992. Game Theory for Applied Economist. Princeton University Press: Princeton, N. J.

Ginevicius, R.; Krivka, A. 2008. Application of game theory for duopoly market analysis, Journal of Business Economics and Management 9(3): 207-217. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2008.9.207-217

Lai, H. 1989. A Theoretical Basis for Negotiation Support Systems. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. University of Purdue.

Lo, W.; Lin, C. L.; Yan, M. R. 2007. Contractor's opportunistic bidding behaviour and equilibrium price level in the construction market, Journal of Construction Engineering and Management 133(6): 409-416. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)0733-9364(2007)133:6(409)

Lo, W.; Yan, M. R. 2009. Evaluating qualification-based selection system: a simulation approach, Journal of Construction Engineering and Management 135(6): 458-465. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862.0000013

Munns, A. K.; Aloquil, O., Ramsay, B. 2000. Joint Venture negotiation and managerial practices in the new countries of the former Soviet Union, International Journal of Project Management 18: 403-413. doi:10.1016/S0263-7863(99)00071-X

Myerson, B. R. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Nicolini, D.; Holti, R., Smalley, M. 2001. Integrating project activities: the theory and practice of managing the supply chain through clusters, Construction Management and Economics 19(1): 37-47. doi:10.1080/014461901452067

Norwood, S. R.; Mansfield, N. R. 1999. Joint venture issues concerning European and Asian construction markets of the 1990's, International Journal of Project Management 17(2): 89-93. doi:10.1016/S0263-7863(98)00016-7

Proverbs, D. G.; Holt, G. D. 2000. Reducing construction costs: European best practice supply chain implications, Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management 6(3): 149-158. doi: 10.1016/S0969-7012(00)00011-3

Peldschus F. 2008. Experience of the game theory application in construction management, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(4): 531-545. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.531-545

Raiffa, H. 1982. The Art and Science of Negotiation. Mass: the Belknap press of Harvard University press.

Saee, J. 2008. Best practice in global negotiation strategies for leaders and managers in the 21st century, Journal of Business Economics and Management 9(4): 309-318. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2008.9.309-318

Sarka, V.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Ustinovicius, L.; Sarkiene, E.; Ignatavicius, C. 2008. System of project multicriteria decision synthesis in construction, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(4): 546-565. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.546-565

Simchi-Levi, D.; Kaminsky, P.; Simchi-Levi, E. 2001. Designing and Managing the Supply Chain. The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., New York.

Tam, C. M. 1999. Build-operate-transfer model for infrastructure developments in Asia: reasons for success and failures, International Journal of Project Management 17(6): 377-382. doi:10.1016/S0263-7863(98)00061-1

Yu, W. D.; Skibniewski, M. J. 1999. A neuro-fuzzy computational approach to constructability knowledge acquisition for construction technology evaluation, Automation in Construction 8(5): 539-552. doi:10.1016/S0926-5805(98)00104-6

Xu, T.; Bower, D. A.; Smith, N. J. 2005. Types of collaboration between foreign contractors and their Chinese partners, International Journal of Project Management 23: 45-53. doi:10.1016/j.ijproman.2004.05.012

Min-Ren Yan

Department of International Business Administration, Chinese Culture University (SCE), No. 231, Sec. 2, Jian-guo S. Rd., Da-an Dist., Taipei City 106, Taiwan E-mail: mjyen@sce.pccu.edu.tw

Received 29 September 2010; accepted 05 February 2011

Min-Ren YAN. PhD, Assistant Professor of the Department of International Business Administration at Chinese Culture University (SCE), Taipei, Taiwan. Dr Yan is concurrently the leader of the research lab in Project Business Economics and Decision Models, the director of Quality Centre for Business Excellence, and business consultant in web technology, marketing, and services industries. His research interests focus on strategic alliances, game theoretical analysis, project business economics, and decision models.
Table 1. The acceptable prices in the last three rounds

Round   Acceptable price for player A   Acceptable price for player B

n-2     [a.sub.n] - [PL.sub.a(n)]       E - [a.sub.n] + [PL.sub.a(n)]
        + [PL.sub.b(n-1)]               + [PL.sub.b(n-1)]

n-1     [a.sub.n] - [PL.sub.a(n)]       E - [a.sub.n] + [PL.sub.a(n)]

n       [a.sub.n]

Table 2. The fuzzy if-then rules

Rule
code       "R" is           "O" is           "L" is            "S" is

1     IF   High       and   High       and   High       THEN   Low
2     IF   High       and   High       and   Moderate   THEN   Low
3     IF   High       and   High       and   Low        THEN   Low
4     IF   High       and   Moderate   and   High       THEN   Moderate
5     IF   High       and   Moderate   and   Moderate   THEN   Moderate
6     IF   High       and   Moderate   and   Low        THEN   Moderate
7     IF   High       and   Low        and   High       THEN   Moderate
8     IF   High       and   Low        and   Moderate   THEN   Moderate
9     IF   High       and   Low        and   Low        THEN   Moderate
10    IF   Moderate   and   High       and   High       THEN   Moderate
11    IF   Moderate   and   High       and   Moderate   THEN   Moderate
12    IF   Moderate   and   High       and   Low        THEN   Low
13    IF   Moderate   and   Moderate   and   High       THEN   High
14    IF   Moderate   and   Moderate   and   Moderate   THEN   High
15    IF   Moderate   and   Moderate   and   Low        THEN   High
16    IF   Moderate   and   Low        and   High       THEN   High
17    IF   Moderate   and   Low        and   Moderate   THEN   High
18    IF   Moderate   and   Low        and   Low        THEN   High
19    IF   Low        and   High       and   High       THEN   High
20    IF   Low        and   High       and   Moderate   THEN   High
21    IF   Low        and   High       and   Low        THEN   Moderate
22    IF   Low        and   Moderate   and   High       THEN   High
23    IF   Low        and   Moderate   and   Moderate   THEN   High
24    IF   Low        and   Moderate   and   Low        THEN   High
25    IF   Low        and   Low        and   High       THEN   High
26    IF   Low        and   Low        and   Moderate   THEN   High
27    IF   Low        and   Low        and   Low        THEN   High

Table 3. Information of the JV project

Information                     Company A               Company B

Estimated total amount                3,229 million dollars
of the project (E)

Work scope                   Station portion         Tunnel portion

Estimated cost            1,180 million dollars   1,770 million dollars
([C.sub.a] and
[C.sub.b])

Estimated total profit                  279 million dollars
of the project (F)
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有