Robustness in Regional Development studies. The case of Lithuania.
Brauers, Willem Karel M. ; Ginevicius, Romualdas
1. Definition of robustness
By 1953, which is quite recent for statistics (1), robust became a
statistical term as "strong, healthy, sufficiently tough to
withstand life's adversities" (Stigler 1973: 872).
Nevertheless, already in 1969 the statistician Huber considered
robustness as purely cardinal as a compromise between a normal
distribution and its light deviations (2). More recently the
statisticians Casella and Berger (2002: 509) call a robust alternative
the median absolute deviation for a sample [x.sub.1], ... [x.sub.n].
The error term in a linear equation is the starting point for the
definition of robustness in econometrics (Darnell 1997: 355). In
addition, robustness is not only linked to error terms or random
variables but also to residual terms, slack and dummy variables,
outliers, etc. Darnell (1997: 356) concludes: "given the somewhat
arbitrary ad hoc nature of the robust estimators these approaches have
had limited application in econometrics". Kennedy (1998: 298)
recognizes the existence of robust estimators as "an estimator
whose properties while not quite best", he continues: "the
topic of robustness has become quite popular recently in econometrics,
as researchers have become aware of the extreme sensitivity of some of
their estimation procedures". More specificity is found by authors
who consider robustness in forms of the error distribution (Rhodes and
Fomby 1988), whereas Mills (1992) presents a Bayesian prediction test
which is robust to certain forms of non-normality in the error
distribution. Moreover, from the beginning Bayesian analysis has to be
characterized as cardinal, nevertheless with a high grade of
arbitrariness. This arbitrariness could be softened by considerations on
robustness (3). Anyway, cardinal numbers form also the basis of
robustness in the Poisson distribution, the t statistic and in sampling
(Sarndal et al. 1992).
However, we observe a move to a more vague and qualitative
definition of robustness, namely to the meaning of common language4:
from a cardinal towards a nominal scale: the most robust one, more
robust than ..., as robust as...., robust, weak robust, less robust than
..., not robust, etc.
A debate between Frisch (1933) and Tinbergen (1930) ensued as
whether or not Tinbergen had estimated structural form representations
robust to changes in policy regimes or reduced form representations not
robust to shifting policy regimes (Heckman 1992: 878). Kreps (1990)
maintains that more robustness is more important for bargaining theory
than for auction theory as more information is available in the latter
case than in the former. He esteems that robust predictions are crucial
although the meaning given to robustness may depend on the context
(Vincke 1999). Edin and Ohlson (1991) examine that institutional
arrangements in the political process affect budget deficits.
Sensitivity analysis indicates that the results are robust. Admati and
Pfleiderer (1994) speak of robustness in financial contracting. Another
qualitative approach of robustness is related to subjective probability
by Machina and Schmeidler (1992). Dasgupta and Maskin (2008) maintain
that the simple majority rule is the most robust voting rule.
Concluding remark that significance of robustness depends on the
context can be specified in different ways. First, robustness can be
considered as cardinal or as a nominal scale. Second, if robustness is
indicated as vague or arbitrary is it also not the case with inference statistics (Hoel 1971 versus Hays 1974), probability theory (Hays 1974)
and statistical specification (Intriligator 1978: 2; Matyas and Sevestre
1992 versus Thomas 1985: 71 and Wonnacott, R. J. and Wonnacott, T. H.
1970: 312)? Third, robustness is characterized by completeness being
present in the statistical population, when defined as covering events
and opinions which are present, as well as in the statistical universe
with events and opinions not only present but also possible.
2. Conditions of robustness in multi-objective methods
The most robust multi-objective method has to satisfy the following
conditions:
1) the method of multiple objectives in which all stakeholders are
involved is more robust than this one in which only one decision maker
or different decision makers defending only a limited number of
objectives are involved. All stakeholders mean everybody interested in a
certain issue. Consequently, the method of multiple objectives has to
take into consideration consumer sovereignty too. The method taking into
consideration consumer sovereignty is more robust than this one which
does not respect consumer sovereignty;
2) the method of multiple objectives in which all non-correlated
objectives are considered is more robust than this one in which only a
limited number of objectives is considered;
3) the method of multiple objectives in which all interrelations
between objectives and alternatives are taken into consideration at the
same time is more robust than this one in which the interrelations are
only examined two by two;
4) the method of multiple objectives which doesn't need
external normalization is more robust than this one which needs a
subjective external normalization. Consequently, the method of multiple
objectives with inside normalization through the non-subjective
dimensionless measures is more robust than this one which uses
subjective weights (already introduced by Churchman et al. in 1957;
Churchman and Ackoff 1954) or subjective non-additive scores like in the
traditional reference point theory (Brauers and Zavadskas 2008: 168-170;
Brauers 2004: 158-159);
5) the method of multiple objectives based on cardinal numbers is
more robust than this one based on ordinal numbers: "an ordinal
number is one that indicates order or position in a series, like first,
second, etc." (Kendall and Gibbons 1990). The robustness of
cardinality is based first on the saying of Arrow (1974):
"Obviously, a cardinal utility implies an ordinal preference but
not vice versa", and second on the fact that the four essential
operations of arithmetic: adding, subtracting multiplication and
division are only reserved for cardinal numbers (see Annex B);
6) the method of multiple objectives which uses the last recent
available data as a base in the response matrix is more robust than this
one based on earlier data;
7) once the previous six conditions are fulfilled, the use of two
different methods of multi-objective optimization is more robust than
the use of a single method; the use of three methods is more robust than
the use of two, etc.
The Multi-Objective Optimization by Ratio Analysis Method (MOORA)
satisfies the first six conditions. In addition, MOORA satisfies
partially the seventh condition by using two different methods of
multi-objective optimization. MOORA is the most robust method as no
other method satisfies the seven conditions better.
3. The MOORA method
The method starts with a matrix of responses of all alternative
solutions to all objectives:
[x.sub.ij] (1)
with: [x.sub.ij] as the response of alternative j on objective or
attribute i, i = 1, 2, n as the objective or the attributes j = 1, 2,
..., m as the alternatives.
In order to define objectives better we have to focus on the notion
of attribute. Keeney and Raiffa (1993: 32) present the example of the
objective "reduce sulfur dioxide emissions" to be measured by
the attribute "tons of sulfur dioxide emitted per year". An
objective and a correspondent attribute always go together.
Consequently, when the text mentions "objective" the
correspondent attribute is meant as well.
The MOORA method consists of two parts: the ratio system and the
reference point approach.
3.1. The ratio system as a part of MOORA
We go for a ratio system in which each response of an alternative
on an objective is compared to a denominator, which is representative
for all alternatives concerning that objective (5):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
with: [x.sub.ij] = response of alternative j on objective i, j = 1,
2, ..., m; m the number of alternatives, i = 1, 2, ... n; n the number
of objectives, [x.sup.*.sub.ij] = a dimensionless number representing
the normalized response of alternative j on objective i.
Dimensionless Numbers, having no specific unit of measurement, are
obtained, for instance, by multiplication or division. The normalized
responses of the alternatives on the objectives belong to the interval
[0; 1]. However, sometimes the interval could be [-1; 1]. Indeed, for
instance in the case of productivity growth some sectors, regions or
countries may show a decrease instead of an increase in productivity,
i.e. a negative dimensionless number (6).
For optimization, these responses are added in case of maximization
and subtracted in case of minimization:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
with: i = 1, 2, ..., g as the objectives to be maximized, i = g +
1, g + 2, ..., n as the objectives to be minimized, [y.sup.*.sub.j] =
the normalized assessment of alternative j with respect to all
objectives, [y.sup.*.sub.j] can be positive or negative depending on the
totals of its maxima and minima.
An ordinal ranking of the [y.sup.*.sub.j] shows the final
preference. Indeed, cardinal scales can be compared in an ordinal
ranking after Arrow (1974): "Obviously, a cardinal utility implies
an ordinal preference but not vice versa".
3.2. The reference point approach as a part of MOORA
Reference Point Theory will go out from the ratios found in formula
(2), whereby, a Maximal Objective Reference Point is also deduced. The
Maximal Objective Reference Point approach is called realistic and
non-subjective as the coordinates ([r.sub.i]), which are selected for
the reference point, are realized in one of the candidate alternatives.
In the example, A (10;100), B (100;20) and C (50;50), the maximal
objective reference point [R.sub.m] results in: (100;100). The Maximal
Objective Vector is self-evident, if the alternatives are well defined,
as for projects in Project Analysis and Project Planning.
Given the dimensionless number representing the normalized response
of alternative j on objective j, namely [x.sub.ij.sup.*] of formula (2)
and in this way arriving to:
([r.sub.i] - [x.sub.ij.sup.*]), (4)
with: i = 1, 2, ..., n as the attributes, j = 1, 2, ..., m as the
alternatives, [r.sub.i] = the ith coordinate of the reference point,
[x.sub.ij.sup.*] = the normalized attribute i of alternative j, then
this matrix is subject to the Min-Max Metric of Tchebycheff (Karlin and
Studden 1966) (7):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
/[r.sub.i] - [x.sub.ij.sup.*]/ means the absolute value if
[x.sub.ij] is larger than [r.sub.i], for instance by minimization.
Concerning the use of the maximal objective reference point
approach as a part of MOORA some reserves can be made in connection with
consumer sovereignty. Consumer sovereignty is measured with the
community indifference locus map of the consumers (Brauers 2008b:
92-94). Given its definition the maximal objective reference point can
be pushed in the non-allowed non-convex zone of the highest community
indifference locus and will try to pull the highest ranked alternatives
in the non-allowed non-convex zone too (Brauers and Zavadskas 2006:
460-461). Therefore an aspiration objective vector can be preferred,
which moderates the aspirations by choosing smaller coordinates than in
the maximal objective vector, and consequently can be situated in the
convex zone of the highest community indifference locus. Indeed,
stakeholders may be more moderate in their expectations. The coordinates
[q.sub.i] of an aspiration objective vector are formed as:
([r.sub.i - [q.sub.i]) being a subjective element we don't
like to introduce subjectivity in that way again. Instead, a test shows
that the min-max metric of Tchebycheff delivers points inside the convex
zone of the highest community indifference locus (Brauers 2008b:
98-103).
3.3. The importance given to an objective
The normalized responses of the alternatives on the objectives
belong to the interval [0; 1] (see formula 2). Nevertheless, it may turn
out to be necessary to stress that some objectives are more important
than the other ones. In order to give more importance to an objective,
its normalized responses on an alternative could be multiplied by a
Significance Coefficient:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
with: i = 1, 2, ..., g as the objectives to be maximized, i = g +
1, g + 2, ..., n as the objectives to be minimized, [s.sub.i] = the
significance coefficient of objective i, [[??].sup.*.sub.j] = the
normalized assessment of alternative j with respect to all objectives
with significance coefficients.
The Attribution of Sub-Objectives represents another solution. Take
the example of the purchase of fighter planes (Brauers 2002). For
economics, the objectives concerning the fighter planes are threefold:
price, employment and balance of payments, but there is also military
effectiveness. In order to give more importance to military defence,
effectiveness is broken down in, for instance, the maximum speed, the
power of the engines and the maximum range of the plane. Anyway, the
Attribution Method is more refined than a significance coefficient
method could be, as the attribution method succeeds in characterizing an
objective better. For instance, for employment two sub-objectives
replace a significance coefficient of two and in this way characterize
the direct and indirect side of employment.
Of course, at that moment the problem is raised of the subjective
choice of objectives in general, or could we call it robustness of a
choice? The Ameliorated Nominal Group Technique, as explained in Brauers
(2004: 44-60), will gather all stakeholders interested in the issue to
determine the objectives in a non-subjective and anonymous way. The
original Nominal Group Technique of Van De Ven and Delbecq (1971) was
less robust as the ameliorated version, as this one excludes subjective
wishes of the experts. Indeed, in the Ameliorated Nominal Group
Technique the group is questioned about the probability of occurrence of
an event. In this way the experts become more critical even about their
own ideas. The probability of the group is found as the median of the
individual probabilities. Finally, the group rating (R) is multiplied by
the group probability (P) in order to obtain the effectiveness rate of
the event (E). The events are translated into objectives and selected in
a robust way by the Delphi Technique (examples are given in Brauers
(2008a; 2004: 40-44)).
4. A target for regional economic policy in Lithuania
4.1. Which regional economic policy?
In a country economic development can differ from region to region.
Changes are possible in the following ways.
Firstly, no actions or not to a sufficient extent are taken to
weaken the differences. For example, in 2002 five Lithuanian districts
counted an emigration quota against five districts with an immigration quota (Ginevicius and Podvezko 2004: 11). In 2005, only the district of
the capital Vilnius remained with an immigration quota (Statistics of
Lithuania 2006). The capital of a country or another main city as the
only attraction pole is a general world phenomenon, but has to be
corrected.
Secondly, a policy of smoothing out the differences in economic
development would try to equalize the average income in all regions by
the way of transfer payments. The richer regions will see their average
individual income decrease in favour of the average individual income in
the poorer regions in order to come to the same average individual
income at the national level. Even worse, in Belgium an income paradox
took place. The average individual income in the richer region became
smaller than the average individual income in the poorer region (Brauers
2004: 247-259; 1999). Consequently, the most dynamic region is punished.
Its growth effort will go down, less transfer payments will be possible
and everybody will be worse off. Therefore, a limitation of the
redistribution would be better.
Thirdly, some past experiences may help in order to limit the
redistribution of income. The debate is centralized around the aid to
Western Europe by the Marshall Plan (1948-1950) and an eventual aid to
Eastern Europe and China at that time. The last item concerned a
proposition by Senator Mc Mahon of February 1950: "what the United
States can afford". The yearly aid of the Marshall Plan could be
estimated to 2% of Gross National Product, but inclusive of the other
proposition would have been 3 1/3% of GNP (Mendershausen 1949; Polak
1954). However, the inflation in the US finished in 1948 and, in
addition, there was a slight deflation tendency and zero economic growth
in 1949 (U.S. Department of Commerce 1951). One may say, as a
conclusion, that the figure of 3 1/3 % of GNP is acceptable with zero
growth and without inflation. Transfer payments may amount to 10 1/3% in
case of the important economic growth of 5% and inflation of 2%. On the
contrary, in time of recession with a minus one percent of economic
growth and inflation of 2%, transfer payments are limited to 4 1/3%. The
redistribution of income, even when restricted, can ameliorate the
interregional trade, resulting in a win-win situation for all regions.
A note on terminology is needed to clarify the issue. Gross
Domestic Product (GDP) in a certain year is the value added created on
the national territory, being a territorial concept. On the contrary,
Gross National Product (GNP) is related to the civilians and the
permanent residents of a nation. Interpolated for a region, the Gross
Regional Domestic Product (GRDP) signifies the value added created on a
regional territory during a given year, and the Regional Income (RI)
means the value added created by the permanent residents of a region
during that year. Consequently, for the computation of the transfer
payments of a region the Regional Income has to be considered instead of
the Gross National Product.
However, for the measurement of the well-being of the regional
population the computation of the Regional Income is not sufficient. The
RI per capita can be biased by the presence of individuals with a very
high income and a large group of small income earners. Furthermore, RI
is expressed in money units, being a typical exponent of the economics
of welfare. The Economics of Welfare (the term was invented by professor
Pigou (1920)) tries to bring material wealth for everybody (Beveridge
1944; 1942). However, the well-being economy goes further. In the
well-being economy each individual would have to feel good concerning
material wealth, health, education, all kind of security and concerning
the environment. In other words, multiple objectives have to be
fulfilled. Even more, multiple objectives, realized simultaneously, will
measure well-being.
All the objectives are translated into money terms in the well
known Cost-Benefit Analysis. In this analysis even benefits are
expressed in the chosen monetary unit, either in a direct or in an
indirect way. Ipso facto the net-benefit is either positive or negative.
The proposed solution is then, either the acceptance of the project or
the status quo ante. Anyhow, cost-benefit presents a materialistic approach, whereby for instance unemployment and health care are degraded to monetary items. Consequently, to keep the original units of the
objectives is better. However, at that moment the problem is posed to
make the different units comparable, which is the problem of
Normalization. Therefore, sometimes weights are given to the different
units. The choice of weights means the introduction of subjectivity even
with expert evaluation. For instance, past research on Lithuanian
regionalization was less conclusive due to the fact that weights had to
be chosen (Ginevicius and Podvezko 2004: 12-13; Ginevicius et al. 2004:
8-11).
4.2. The data on the Lithuanian regions
Not only the method to handle the different objectives expressed in
different units has to be non-subjective but also the choice of the
objectives, starting with the data underlying the objectives. What is
meant by 'non-subjective'?
In physical sciences, a natural law dictates non-subjectivity
without deviations. In human sciences, for instance in economics, an
economic law will state the attitude of men in general with very
exceptionally individual deviations. Outside these human laws in the
human sciences unanimity or at least a certain form of convergence of
opinion between all stakeholders, which means everybody concerned in a
certain issue, will lead to non-subjectivity (8). Consequently, the
choice of the data concerning the Lithuanian regions, leading to the
objectives, would mean bringing together the representatives of the
national government, of the districts, of the inhabitants, of the
workers and entrepreneurs and of the specialists from the academic
world. Instead of this considerable undertaking the authors themselves
made a broad choice of data in the different fields of interests. For
instance, for migrations of population the emigration is taken as
negative and the immigration as positive. Further the issues are
considered:
--the unemployment rate;
--for income and expenditure: the municipal budget and the monthly
earnings;
--for housing and other floor space: useful floor space and
completed dwellings;
--for education: number of pre-schools and of schools;
--for production and commerce: animal production, investments,
construction and retail trade;
--for justice: criminal offences.
The number of physicians is considered for health care. On the
national level mostly the number of hospital beds is counted, which has
no sense on the regional level as many patients prefer treatment in
large towns sometimes outside their own district.
For pollution the following average emissions in kg and per
[km.sup.2] are taken into account: solid emissions, S[O.sub.2],
N[O.sub.x], CO, volatile organic compounds (VOC) and some others.
We do not mention the greenhouse gas emission ([CO.sub.2]) as
Lithuania has still a reserve for 2020 of 15% above the 2005 figure (9).
Consequently, we suppose that the Lithuanian regions also have no
problem with the greenhouse effect.
On the other side, Lithuania has to foresee energy from renewable
sources for 2020 of 23% of its final energy demand (Commission of the
European Communities 2008a). Table 1 shows all the data.
As mentioned above, in order to determine the transfer payments
between the regions, the size of the Regional Income (RI) of each region
has to be taken into account. The RI means the value added created by
the permanent residents of a region during a year. The average gross
monthly earnings for 2005 as mentioned in Table 1, sub 5 approaches more
or less the notion of Regional Income. Table 2 classifies the regions by
this notion.
However, the computation of the Regional Income is not sufficient.
The RI per capita could be biased. Furthermore, regional income is a
typical exponent of the welfare economy. The well-being economy goes
further. In the well-being economy each individual would have to feel
good concerning material wealth, health, education, all kind of security
and concerning the environment. Therefore, multiple objectives have to
be fulfilled. Multiple objectives, realized simultaneously, will measure
well-being. The 16 data of Table 1 become attributes and when optimized,
either as maxima or minima, objectives. At that moment, the MOORA method
will be operational.
5. Application of the MOORA method on the data of the Lithuanian
regions
5.1. The part of the Ratio System in MOORA
In order to apply the MOORA program the data of Table 1 are
rearranged in Subtable 3a as objectives under the form of a matrix.
Next, in Subtables 3b and 3c starts from the matrix as in formula
(2).
In addition, after formula (3) the objectives are then added in
case of maximization and subtracted in case of minimization (Subtable
3c).
The last column of Subtable 3 c gives the final ranking for the
ratio system in MOORA.
5.2. The part of the reference point theory in MOORA (Subtables 3d
and 3e)
Reference Point Theory starting from the dimensionless numbers of
Table 3c is non-subjective, also by using the Maximal Objective
Reference Point, as expressed in formula (5).
The last column of Subtable 3e gives the final rank for the
Reference Point Theory in MOORA.
Comparing Subtables 3c and 3e the ranking is quite similar for the
head and tail of the last column. However, the remark could be made that
only the data for one year are observed. Therefore, having the figures
for 2002 (Ginevicius and Podvezko 2004), a comparison is possible with
that year (data are given in Annex A). In that manner the 2002
pre-European Union year is compared to a European Union year, namely
2005.
In Table 4 the income approach represents the measurement of the
welfare of a region but not of the wellbeing of the inhabitants. The
well-being is rather effectively measured by MOORA using the multiple
objectives concerning these inhabitants. MOORA shows some differences
between the ratio system and the reference point versions. Nevertheless,
a general tendency is present, even compared with a pre-European Union
year. Three well-being regions, Vilnius, Klaipeda and Kaunas, are in
sharp contrast with Taurage and Siauliai, regions with rather poor
well-being.
Telsiai is very poor concerning general well-being, but has
sufficient income to ameliorate this anomaly. The anomaly is mainly
brought about by pollution, emigration and shortage of dwellings. The
pollution originates from the nearby town of Mazeikiai (Telsiai county)
where the oil refinery of "Mazeikivj. nafta", the only oil
refinery of the Baltic States, is located. In 2005 the refinery started
with the introduction of an environment management system. The
completion was scheduled for 2007 (Mazeikhi nafta 2008).
The Reference Point Method shows some other deviations for regions,
which can be self-supporting concerning well-being. For instance, Utena,
shows a shortage of dwellings, for which it is as bad as Taurage and
Siauliai. Since 2002 there has also been a relative amelioration of the
position of Klaipeda and of Panevezys.
The labour drain to the district of Vilnius represents a serious
problem. In 2002 an immigration surplus still existed in the regions of
Alytus, Kaunas, Marijampole, Utena and Vilnius. In 2005 only the
district of Vilnius showed an immigration surplus.
6. Some conclusions on the economic policy of the Lithuanian
regions
The redistribution of income has to take place between the
Lithuanian regions. The well-being regions, Vilnius, Klaipeda and Kaunas
can eventually support the poorer regions, Taurage and Siauliai, inside
the limits mentioned above, namely 3 1/3% of the Regional Income of a
rich region under conditions of zero economic growth and inflation.
However, these transfer payments have to be diminished by the transfers
given directly and indirectly (by the national state) to the European
Union, to the other international institutions and by the aid to
developing countries. Opposite, the transfer payments have to take into
account the subsidies received from the European Union and from the
other international institutions. Anyway, sometimes an overlapping is
possible between the transfer payments from Europe and from the other
regions. In the long run it would be better that all transfer payments
are centralized by the European Union itself.
As already said, the poorer regions concern especially Siauliai and
Taurage. Regional aid to them is best project oriented. These projects
can be inspired by studying the data of Table 4. Also, the international
organizations only allot assistance for a specific project, even with
the privilege to follow up the advancement of the project.
Siauliai needs more employment opportunities and more investments,
which at the same time will decrease the emigration of the inhabitants.
Taurage with the highest emigration quota of the country has to attract
more investments with more construction also for private housing. The
retail trade has to be developed, for instance around an important
highway, when trade with Russia could develop.
However, economic development is necessary over the whole of the
Lithuanian territory with the exception of the district of Vilnius. The
labour drain to Vilnius will still further increase when Vilnius is the
cultural capital of Europe. Development of tourism all over the
Lithuanian territory would be good. Fishing in the many lakes and
fitness centers around the lakes will certainly attract foreign
tourists. The rocket base near Plateliai (Telsiai) can be an attraction
pole for all European and Turkish tourists as they were threatened by
the rockets one day. Even a later closed nuclear power plant of Ignalina
of the type of Chernobyl, if safely protected, can attract disaster
tourists and industrial archeologists, industrial archeology being the
last modern branch of modern history. Nevertheless, not only services
are needed but also a form of industrialization.
As already mentioned, the European Commission foresees a 23% part
of renewables in the final energy demand of Lithuania by 2020. These
renewables could come from non-fossil energy sources: wind, solar,
geothermal, wave, tidal, hydropower, biomass, landfill gas, sewage
treatment plant gas and biogases. The European Commission remarks:
"they are related to the promotion of local employment and
opportunities for small and medium-sized enterprises, regional and rural
development, stimulating economic growth and increasing global European
industry leadership" (Commission of the European Communities
2008b). Anyway it would mean an opportunity for industrialization of the
Lithuanian regions.
7. General conclusions
The remark that significance of robustness depends on the context
is specified in different ways. First, robustness can be considered
either as cardinal or as a nominal robust. Second, if robustness is
indicated as vague or arbitrary perhaps it is also the case with
inference statistics, probability theory and statistical specification.
Third, robustness is characterized by completeness being present in the
statistical population covering events and opinions which are present,
as well as in the statistical universe with events and opinions not only
present but also possible.
Concerning the most robust method of multi-objective optimization
the following conditions are to be satisfied:
1) the method of multiple objectives in which all stakeholders are
involved is more robust than one in which only one decision maker or
different decision makers defending only a limited number of objectives
are involved. All stakeholders mean everybody interested in a certain
issue. Consequently, the method of multiple objectives which takes into
consideration consumer sovereignty is more robust than this one which
does not respect consumer sovereignty. Consumer sovereignty is measured
with community indifference loci. Solutions have to deliver points
inside the convex zone of the highest community indifference locus;
2) the method of multiple objectives in which all non-correlated
objectives are considered is more robust than this one in which only a
limited number of objectives is considered;
3) the method of multiple objectives in which all interrelations
between objectives and alternatives are taken into consideration at the
same time is more robust than this one in which the interrelations are
only examined two by two;
4) the method of multiple objectives which does not need separate
normalization is more robust than this one which needs a subjective
separate normalization. Consequently, a method of multiple objectives
which uses non-subjective dimensionless measures with inside
normalization is more robust than this one which for normalization uses
subjective weights or subjective non-additive scores like in the
traditional Reference Point Theory;
5) the method of multiple objectives based on cardinal numbers is
more robust than this one based on ordinal numbers: an ordinal number is
one that indicates order or position in a series, like first, second,
etc.. The robustness of cardinality is based on the saying of Arrow
(1974): "Obviously, a cardinal utility implies an ordinal
preference but not vice versa", and also on the fact that the four
fundamental operations of arithmetic: adding, subtracting,
multiplication and division are only reserved for cardinal numbers;
6) the method of multiple objectives which uses the last recent
available data as a base in the response matrix is more robust than this
one based on earlier data;
7) once the previous six conditions are fulfilled, the use of two
different methods of multi-objective optimization is more robust than
the use of a single method; the use of three methods is more robust than
the use of two, etc.
The Multi-Objective Optimization by Ratio Analysis Method (MOORA)
satisfies the first six conditions. In addition, MOORA satisfies
partially the seventh condition by using two different methods of
Multi-Objective Optimization. MOORA is the most robust method as no
other method satisfies the seven conditions better. For all these
reasons we selected MOORA.
In a country economic development can differ from region to region.
A policy of smoothing out the differences in economic development may
not result in a killing disadvantage for the richer regions. On the
contrary, an eventual redistribution of income has to be a
win-win-operation.
Next question is how to measure this redistribution. The
computation of the Regional Income, being an exponent of the welfare
economy, is not sufficient for the measurement of the well-being of the
regional population. A well-being economy goes further than a welfare
economy. In the well-being economy each individual would have to feel
good concerning material wealth, health, education, all kind of security
and concerning the environment. in other words, multiple objectives have
to be fulfilled. However, these different multiple objectives are
expressed in different units, which means that a problem of
normalization is posed. For this purpose the attribution of weights,
scores or exponents can be used, which means introduction of
subjectivity. Therefore, an internal mechanical procedure is operated in
order to escape from that subjective problem, namely Multi-Objective
Optimization by Ratio Analysis (MOORA). Dimensionless numbers obtained
in this manner will also form the basis for Reference Point Theory, the
second part of MOORA.
Given all the objectives MOORA measures finally the well-being
differences between the ten regions of Lithuania. Three well-being
regions are in sharp contrast with two regions with a rather poor
well-being. The other regions are more self-supporting concerning
general well-being. In addition, the labour drain to the district of
Vilnius from all the other regions represents a serious problem.
The redistribution of income has to take place inside certain
limits, whereas commercialization and industrialization of the regions
has to occur, beside the three regions already doing well where
well-being is concerned.
Does the regional application of Lithuania satisfy the seven
conditions of robustness?
1) First condition of robustness
The choice of the objectives and their respective importance has to
be made by all the stakeholders involved in the issue. As this procedure
is rather cost and time-consuming the authors have taken the
responsibility to choose objectives for all the regions. Consequently,
this condition also respects consumer sovereignty.
2) Second condition of robustness
All objectives were taken into consideration as much as possible.
The choice of the objectives for all the regions is represented in the
fields of migration of the population between the regions, the
unemployment rate, income and expenditure, housing and other floor space
problems, education, production, commerce, justice and health care
problems. For pollution the following average emissions in kg and per
[km.sup.2] are taken into account: solid emissions, S[O.sub.2],
N[O.sub.x], CO, and volatile organic compounds. The greenhouse effect
([CO.sub.2]) is not included as Lithuania may still exceed its actual
emission level. On the contrary, the production of renewable energy will
form an opportunity for further industrialization of Lithuania.
Significance coefficients are too subjective to characterize the
importance of an objective. Instead, sub-objectives, heightened to
objectives, were introduced in order to give importance to a certain
objective.
3) Third condition of robustness
All interrelations between objectives and alternatives were
involved at the same time under the form of a matrix of responses
considered as a whole and as a starting point for the application of
MOORA.
4) Fourth condition of robustness
The use of dimensionless measures is a more robust method than
subjective methods of normalization. In the application MOORA's
dimensionless ratios satisfied this condition. Significance coefficients
are too subjective to characterize the importance of an objective.
Instead, sub-objectives, heightened to objectives, are introduced in
order to give importance to a certain objective.
5) Fifth condition of robustness
The method of multiple objectives based on cardinal numbers is more
robust than this one based on ordinal numbers. The application was
entirely based on cardinal numbers.
6) Sixth condition of robustness
The last available data were used. Perhaps more recent raw data
exist, but regrouping, aggregation and overlapping of data was not done
up until now.
7) Seventh condition of robustness
All the previous six conditions are fulfilled and also the seventh
condition as two different methods of Multi-Objective Optimization were
used. No other Multi-Objective Optimization Method exists which uses
more than two Multi-Objective Optimization Methods and fulfill the
previous six conditions.
In this way the regional research on Lithuania satisfies all
conditions on robustness.
Annex B
Ordinal Numbers and Rank Correlation Methods
The statistician Kendall wrote in 1948 (p. 1), even repeated in
1990 (Kendall and Gibbons):"we shall often operate with ordinal
numbers as if they were the cardinals of ordinary arithmetic, adding
them, subtracting them, and even multiplying them", but he never
put this statement into practice at least for subtraction and
multiplication.
The method of correlation of ranks, consisting of totalizing ranks
of ordinal numbers, can it be considered for banning subjectivity? Rank
correlation was introduced first by psychologists such as Spearman (1904, 1906, 1910) and later taken over by the statistician Kendall in
1948. Kendall (1948: 87) gave the following example after a kind of
Lexicographic Method. C is ranked first because it has two firsts, G has
the remaining first and then B is ranked third as it has two seconds,
etc. Then Kendal proved that "this procedure is not
self-consistent".
Let us illustrate this inconsistency with the question: "how
to choose a wife?" The first choice is a woman extremely beautiful
and extremely good in cooking but extremely stupid. The second choice is
the extraordinary intelligent woman, but extremely ugly and extremely
bad in cooking. The woman who is simply beautiful, a good cook and quite
intelligent has no chance at all. The method of correlation of ranks
chooses always extreme situations as the best choice. An in between
alternative solution will never have a chance. In this way rank
correlation is subjective.
Another possibility consists of giving weights to the first,
second, third, etc. rank but then we end again with subjective weights.
However, the introduction of a supplemental notion, the statistical term
of Correlation, may help. Suppose the statistical universe is just
represented by two experts nominated by two stakeholders. If they both
rank in the same order different items to reach a certain goal, it is
said that the correlation is perfect. However, perfect correlation is a
rather exceptional situation. The problem is then posited: how in other
situations correlation is measured. Therefore, the following
Spearman's coefficient is used (Kendall 1948: 8):
[rho] = 1 - 6 [SIGMA] [D.sup.2] / N([N.sup.2] - 1), (B1)
where: D = difference between paired ranks; V = number of items
ranked.
According to this formula, perfect correlation yields the
coefficient of one. An acceptable correlation reaches the coefficient of
one as much as possible. No correlation at all yields a coefficient of
zero. If the series are exactly in reverse order, there will be a
negative correlation of minus one, as shown in the following example.
This Table shows that the sum of ranks in the case of an ordinal
scale has no sense.
Correlation leads to: [rho] = 1 6 x 112 / 7(49-1) = -1.
The correlation for an ordinal scale is only estimated two by two.
This means few chances for a perfect or even for an acceptable
correlation if more than two experts, groups of stakeholders or sets of
data are involved. In addition, weighing is present, namely the same
weight for every item.
Mueller et al. (1970: 270) gave the example of a perfect
correlation between income and monthly rental of six families. We
extended this example with a set of data on the size of households.
It is clear, that this perfect correlation is rather exceptional.
There is even more.
1) Another psychologist maintains that a scale from 1 to 7 is
considered as a maximum to think of for the human brain (Miller 1965).
2) In ordinal ranking 3 is farther away from 1 than 2 from 1, but
Kendal (1948:1) goes too far.
As for Kendal, B is far away from A as it has 7 ranks before and A
only 4, whereas it is not true cardinally. Once again we quote Arrow
(1974): "Obviously, a cardinal utility implies an ordinal
preference but not vice versa".
Despite Arrow's warning some authors show an excess of
subjectivity by deducing a cardinal value from an ordinal ranking.
Sometimes an Arithmetical Progression is used under the form: 0
(non-existing), 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10. A scale from 1 to 7 is
considered as a maximum (Miller 1965). A more limited choice would be,
for instance, from 1 to 4. This range may be still too large as 2 is the
double of 1, and four equals four times one. Seldom a direct cardinal
scale will show such huge jumps. Perhaps the scale 3, 4, 5 would be
preferable. Zero can still be added to the scale for somebody who
disapproves completely. The choice of categories remains arbitrary. To
our mind, these dimensionless numerals are Cardinal Numbers. An Ordinal
Scale is given by: 1st, 2nd, 3rd, 4th, ...
Saaty (1987) makes another proposition inside his pair-wise
comparisons: the Fundamental Scale:
1 equal importance
3 moderate importance of one over another
5 essential or strong importance
7 very strong importance
9 extreme importance
When compromise is needed, 2,4,6,8 are intermediate values between
the two adjacent judgments.
Some authors go even further. Lootsma (1987) promotes the Normal
Scale:
[e.sup.0] = 1; [e.sup.1] = 2.7; [e.sup.2] = 7.4; [e.sup.3] = 20.1
...
This scale seems exaggerated, which is even more the case with his
Stretched Scale:
[e.sup.0] = 1; [e.sup.2] = 7.4; [e.sup.4] = 54.6; [e.sup.6] = 403.4
...
Anyway, the comparisons between Ordinal Scales and Dimensionless
Numbers seem disputable. It is better that from the beginning as much as
possible ordinal scales are avoided.
Received 07 January 2008; accepted 27 February 2009
References
Admati, A. R.; Pfleiderer, P. 1994. Robust financial contracting
and the role of venture capitalists, Journal of Finance 49(2): 371-402.
Arrow, K. J. 1974. General economic equilibrium: purpose,
analytical techniques, collective choice, American Economic Review
64(3): 253-272.
Beveridge, W. H. 1942. The Beveridge Report. His Majesty's
Government. London.
Beveridge, W. H. 1944. Full Employment in a Free Society. London:
Allen and Unwin.
Brauers, W. K. 1987. Nominal Methods in Group Multiple Decision
Making. Research Paper No. 3. Institute for Developing Countries,
University of Antwerp, Antwerp.
Brauers, W. K. 2002. The multiplicative representation for multiple
objectives optimization with an application for arms procurement, Naval
Research Logistics 49: 327-340.
Brauers, W. K. 2004. Optimization Methods for a Stakeholder Society. A Revolution in Economic Thinking by Multi-objective
Optimization. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers and Springer. ISBN 1-4020-7681-9.
Brauers, W. K.; Lepkova, N. 2002. The application of the nominal
group technique to the economic outlook for Lithuania over the period
2002-2011, Ukio technologinis ir ekonominis vystymas [Technological and
Economic Development of Economy] 8(1): 19-24.
Brauers, W. K.; Zavadskas, E. K. 2006. The MOORA Method and its
application to privatization in a transition economy, Control and
Cybernetics 35(2): 445-469.
Brauers, W. K.; Lepkova, N. 2003. The application of the nominal
group technique to the business outlook for the facilities sector of
Lithuania over the period 2003-2012, International Journal of Strategic
Property Management 7(1): 1-9.
Brauers, W. K. 2008a. Group decision making with multi-objective
optimization, Foundations of Computing and Decision Sciences 33(2):
167-179.
Brauers, W. K. 2008b. Multi-objective decision-making by reference
point theory for a wellbeing economy, Operations Research International
Journal 8: 89-104.
Brauers, W. K.; Zavadskas, E. K. 2008. Multi-objective optimization
in location theory with a simulation for a department store,
Transformations in Business and Economics 7(3): 163-183.
Casella, G.; Berger, R. L. 2002. Statistical Inference. Second
Edition. Duxbury Press.
Churchman, C. W.; Ackoff, R. L. 1954. An approximate measure of
value, Operations Research 2: 172-180.
Churchman, C. W.; Ackoff, R. L.; Arnoff, E. L. 1957. Introduction
to Operations Research. New York: Wiley.
Commission of the European Communities. 2008a. Joint Impact
Assessment. SEC (2008) 85/3. Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities. 2008b. Proposal for a
decision of the European Parliament and the Council on the effort of the
Member States to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions. COM (2008) SEC
(2008). Brussels.
Commission of the European Communities. 2008c. Proposal for a
Directive of the European Parliament and the Council on the promotion of
energy from renewable sources. COM version 15.4. Brussels.
Dalkey, N.; Helmer, O. 1963. An experimental application of the
delphi method to the use of experts, Management Science 9(3): 458-487.
Darnell, A. C.1997. Dictionary of Econometrics. Cheltenham, UK,
Edward Elgar.
Dasgupta, P.; Maskin, E. 2008. On the robustness of majority rule,
Journal of the European Economic Association 6(5): 949-973.
Edin, P. A.; Ohlson, H. 1991. Political determinants of budget
deficits: coalition effects versus minority effects, European Economic
Review 35(8): 1597-1603.
Frisch, R. 1933. Pitfalls in the Statistical Construction of Supply
and Demand Curves. Leipzig: Hans Buske Verlag.
Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V. 2004. Quantitative assessment of
regional development, Environmental Research, Engineering and Management
1(27): 10-14.
Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V.; Mikelis, D. 2004. Quantitative
evaluation of economic and social development of Lithuanian regions,
Ekonomika 65: 1-13.
Hays, W. L. 1974. Statistics for the Social Sciences. London: Holt,
Rinehart and Winston.
Heckman, J. J.1992. Havelmo and the birth of modern econometrics,
Journal of Economic Literature 30: 876-886.
Hoel, P. G. 1971. Elementary Statistics. New York: John Wiley.
Huber, P. J. 1969. Theorie de l'Inference Statistique Robuste.
Montreal: Les Presses de l'Universite de Montreal.
Huber, P. J. 1981. Robust Statistics. New York: Wiley.
Intriligator, M. D. 1978. Econometric Models, Techniques and
Applications. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company.
Karlin, S.; Studden, W. J. 1966. Tchebycheff Systems: with
Applications in Analysis and Statistics. New York: Interscience
Publishers, 278-280.
Keeney, R. L.; Raiffa, H. 1993. Decisions with Multiple Objectives,
Preferences and Value Tradeoffs. Cambridge: University Press.
Kendall, M. G. 1948. Rank Correlation Methods. Griffin London.
Kendall, M. G.; Gibbons, J. D. 1990. Rank Correlation Methods.
London: Edward Arnold.
Kennedy, P. 1998. A Guide to Econometrics. Oxford: Blackwell.
Kreps, D. M. 1990. Game Theory and Economic Modelling. Oxford:
Oxford University Press and Clarendon Press.
Lootsma, F. A. 1987. Numerical Scaling of Human Judgement in
Pairwise-comparison Methods for Fuzzy Multi-criteria Decision Analysis,
in Proceedings of the NATO Advanced Study Institute. Val d'Isere,
France, July 2-August 6.
Machina, M. J.; Schneider, D. A. 1992. More Robust Definition of
Subjective Probability, Econometrica 60(4): 745-80.
Matyas, L.; Sevestre, P. 1992. The Econometrics of Panel Data.
Handbook of Theory and Applications. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Mazeikhj. nafta. Available from Internet:
<www.nafta.lt/en/content.php?pid=34>.
Mendershausen, H. 1949. Future foreign financing, Review of
Economics and Statistics November: 272-274.
Miller, G. A. 1965. The magical number seven plus or minus two:
some limits on our capacity for processing information, Psychological
Review 63: 81-97.
Mills, J. A. 1992. Bayesian Prediction Tests for Structural
Stability, Journal of Econometrics 52(3): 381-388.
Mueller, J. H.; Schuessler, K. F.; Costner, H. L. 1970. Statistical
Reasoning in Sociology. Second Edition. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Pigou, A. C. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. Fourth Edition.
London: Macmillan.
Polak, J. J. 1954. IMF, Conceptual Problems involved in projections
of the international sector of Gross National Product, Long-Range
Economic Projection. Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Rhodes, G. F.; Fomby, T. B. 1988. (Eds.). Nonparametric and Robust
Inference. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Rieder, H. (Ed.). 1996. Robust Statistics, Data Analysis and
Computer Intensive Methods. New York: Springer.
Ruggeri, F. 2008. Bayesian Robustness, Newsletter of the European
Working Group "Multiple Criteria Decision Aiding" 3(17): 6-10.
Saaty, T. L. 1987. What is the Analytic Hierarchy Process? In
Proceedings of the NATO Advanced Study Institute. Val d'Isere,
France, July 26 - August 6.
Sarndal, C. E.; Swensson, B.; Wretman, J. 1992. Model Assisted
Survey Sampling. New York: Springer.
Spearman, C. 1904. The proof and measurement of association between
two things, The American Journal of Psychology 15: 72-101.
Spearman, C. 1906. A footrule for measuring correlation, British
Journal of Psychology 2: 89-108.
Spearman, C. 1910. Correlation calculated from faulty data, British
Journal of Psychology 3: 271-295.
Statistics of Lithuania. 2006. Counties of Lithuania. Department of
Statistics to the Government of Lithuania. ISSN 1648-0260.
Stigler, S. 1973. Simon Newcomb, Percy Daniell and the History of
Robust Estimation 1885-1920, Journal of the American Statistical
Association 68: 872-879.
Thomas, R. L. 1985. Introductory Econometrics. London: Longman.
Tinbergen, J. 1930. Bestimmung und Deutung von Angebotskurven,
Zeitschrift fur Nationaldkonomie 1(1): 669-679.
U. S. Department of Commerce. 1951. National Income and Product of
the U.S. 1929-1950.
Van De Ven, A. H.; Delbecq, A. L. 1971. Nominal versus interacting
group processes for committee decision-making effectiveness, Academy of
Management Journal 14(2): 203-213.
Vincke, P. 1999. Robust solutions and methods in decision aid,
Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis 8: 181-187.
Wonnacott, R. J. and Wonnacott, T. H. 1970. Econometrics. New York:
Wiley.
DOI: 10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.
Endnotes
(1) As well known, statistics already existed in Roman times with
the census of population.
(2) At a later time, namely in 1981, Huber wrote a more complete
book on Robust Statistics. In 1994 on the occasion of Huber's
birthday his colleagues edited a book on Robust Statistics (Rieder
1996).
(3) A good overview of this problem of robustness and Bayesian
Analysis is brought by Ruggeri, 2008.
(4) Webster's new Universal Unabridged Dictionary: robust:
strong; stronger, strongest.
(5) Brauers and Zavadskas (2006), prove that the most robust choice
for this denominator is the square root of the sum of squares of each
alternative per objective.
(6) Instead of a normal increase in productivity growth a decrease
remains possible. At that moment the interval becomes [-1, 1]. Take the
example of productivity, which has to increase (positive). Consequently,
we look for a maximization of productivity e.g. in European and American
countries. What if the opposite does occur? For instance, take the
original transition from the USSR to Russia. Contrary to the other
European countries productivity decreased. It means that in formula (2)
the numerator for Russia was negative with the whole ratio becoming
negative. Consequently, the interval changes to: [-1, +1] instead of [0,
1].
(7) Brauers 2008b proves that the Min-Max metric is the most robust
choice between all the possible metrics of reference point theory.
(8) This convergence of opinion has to be brought not by
face-to-face methods, but rather by nominal methods such as the
Ameliorated Nominal Group Technique or by the Delphi Method.
For the Ameliorated Nominal Group Technique see: Brauers 2004:
44-60; 1987; Brauers and Lepkova 2002, 2003; Van De Ven, Delbecq 1971.
For Delphi see: Brauers 2008a; 2004: 40-44; Dalkey and Helmer 1963.
(9) Lithuanian greenhouse gas emission limited by 2020 compared to
2005: 18,429,024 tons of [CO.sub.2] equivalent or 15% above the 2005
emission; cf. other Baltic States: Latvia 17%, Estonia 11% (Commission
of the European Communities 2008c).
Willem Karel M. Brauers [1], Romualdas Ginevicius [2]
[1] University of Antwerp, Birontlaan, 97, B2600 Antwerpen, Belgium
E-mail: willem.brauers@ua.ac.be
[2] Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11,
LT-10223 Vilnius, Lithuania E-mail: romualdas.ginevicius@adm.vgtu.lt
Annex A. MOORA applied on 16 objectives for the 10 Lithuanian Regions
(2002)
Aa. Matrix of Responses of Alternatives on Objectives: ([x.sub.ij)
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
MAX. MAX. MAX. MIN.
1 2 3 4
Alytus 0.331 1.04 19.950 8.6
Kaunas 0.378 0.938 13.660 4.6
Klaipeda -0.018 1.123 16.430 5.1
Marijampole 0.887 1.014 18.600 8
Panevezys -0.655 0.95 20.120 7.6
Siauliai -0.545 0.986 26.800 9
Taurage -1.131 1.029 30.600 8.8
Telsiai -0.142 1.052 21.970 6.4
Utena 0.517 1.15 17.330 7
Vilnius 1.089 0.978 16.330 5.7
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
MAX. MAX. MAX. MAX.
5 6 7 8
Alytus 844 22.2 88 4.79
Kaunas 865 22.5 80 3.49
Klaipeda 950 19.5 84 3.72
Marijampole 755 19.7 71 5.65
Panevezys 851 22.8 89 4.69
Siauliai 807 21 86 4.22
Taurage 724 21.4 79 5.79
Telsiai 936 21 73 4.41
Utena 982 24.4 93 5.29
Vilnius 1061 19.6 86 3.29
animal retail
products trade investment construction
MAX. MAX. MAX. MAX.
9 10 11 12
Alytus 1314 1927 1138.3 820.3
Kaunas 1189 4999.5 1393.2 916.4
Klaipeda 1133 3917.9 3294.1 1003.9
Marijampole 1252 2904.1 737.5 437.9
Panevezys 1039 2870.8 1489 848.7
Siauliai 1143 3410.2 949.1 546
Taurage 1289 2306.3 365.3 202.3
Telsiai 1084 4177.8 2144.2 1166.3
Utena 943 2078.4 1440 900.2
Vilnius 1428 6776.3 2457.3 1248
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
MAX. MIN. MAX. MIN.
13 14 15 16
Alytus 109.3 135 25.7 463
Kaunas 143.03 215 43.5 1886
Klaipeda 97.5 245 32.9 2694
Marijampole 109.31 174 23.5 437
Panevezys 102.77 216 26 539
Siauliai 83.26 176 23.9 722
Taurage 110.53 172 17.5 386
Telsiai 85.12 154 18.3 7716
Utena 84.25 135 22.7 288
Vilnius 225.97 250 44.1 1296
Tables Ab and Ac, the part of the Ratio System in MOORA (2002)
Ab. Sum of squares and their square roots
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
Alytus 0.1096 1.0816 398.003 73.96
Kaunas 0.1429 0.87984 186.596 21.16
Klaipeda 0.0003 1.26113 269.945 26.01
Marijampole 0.7868 1.0282 345.96 64
Panevezys 0.429 0.9025 404.814 57.76
Siauliai 0.297 0.9722 718.24 81
Taurage 1.2792 1.05884 936.36 77.44
Telsiai 0.0202 1.1067 482.681 40.96
Utena 0.2673 1.3225 300.329 49
Vilnius 1.1859 0.95648 266.669 32.49
[SIGMA] 4.52 10.57 4310 524
root 2.1256 3.25115 65.6475 22.89
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
Alytus 712336 492.8 7744 22.94
Kaunas 748225 506.3 6400 12.18
Klaipeda 902500 380.3 7056 13.84
Marijampole 570025 388.1 5041 31.92
Panevezys 724201 519.8 7921 22
Siauliai 651249 441 7396 17.81
Taurage 524176 458 6241 33.52
Telsiai 876096 441 5329 19.45
Utena 964324 595.4 8649 27.98
Vilnius 1125721 384.2 7396 10.82
[SIGMA] 7798853 4607 69173 212
root 2792.643 67.87 263 14.58
animal retail
products trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
Alytus 1726596 3713329 1295727 672892.1
Kaunas 1413721 24995000 1941006 839789
Klaipeda 1283689 15349940 10851095 1007815
Marijampole 1567504 8433797 543906.3 191756.4
Panevezys 1079521 8241493 2217121 720291.7
Siauliai 1306449 11629464 900790.8 298116
Taurage 1661521 5319020 133444.1 40925.29
Telsiai 1175056 17454013 4597594 1360256
Utena 889249 4319747 2073600 810360
Vilnius 2039184 45918242 6038323 1557504
[SIGMA] 14142490 1.45E+08 30592607 7499705
root 3760.65 12057.12 5531.058 2738.559
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
Alytus 11946.49 18225 660.49 214369
Kaunas 20457.58 46225 1892.25 3556996
Klaipeda 9506.25 60025 1082.41 7257636
Marijampole 11948.68 30276 552.25 190969
Panevezys 10561.67 46656 676 290521
Siauliai 6932.228 30976 571.21 521284
Taurage 12216.88 29584 306.25 148996
Telsiai 7245.414 23716 334.89 59536656
Utena 7098.063 18225 515.29 82944
Vilnius 51062.44 62500 1944.81 1679616
[SIGMA] 148975.7 366408 8535.85 73479987
root 385.9737 605.3164 92.3897 8572.047
Ac. Objectives divided by their square roots and the results of
the ratio system
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
Alytus 0.1557 0.31989 0.3039 0.376
Kaunas 0.1778 0.28851 0.20808 0.201
Klaipeda -0.008 0.34542 0.25028 0.223
Marijampole 0.4173 0.31189 0.28333 0.35
Panevezys -0.308 0.2922 0.30649 0.332
Siauliai -0.256 0.30328 0.40824 0.393
Taurage -0.532 0.3165 0.46613 0.385
Telsiai -0.067 0.32358 0.33467 0.28
Utena 0.2432 0.35372 0.26399 0.306
Vilnius 0.5123 0.30082 0.24875 0.249
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
Alytus 0.302223 0.327 0.335 0.329
Kaunas 0.309742 0.332 0.304 0.239
Klaipeda 0.34018 0.287 0.319 0.255
Marijampole 0.270353 0.29 0.27 0.388
Panevezys 0.304729 0.336 0.338 0.322
Siauliai 0.288974 0.309 0.327 0.29
Taurage 0.259253 0.315 0.3 0.397
Telsiai 0.335166 0.309 0.278 0.303
Utena 0.351638 0.359 0.354 0.363
Vilnius 0.379927 0.289 0.327 0.226
animal retail
products trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
Alytus 0.349 0.159823 0.206 0.300
Kaunas 0.316169 0.414651 0.251887 0.334629
Klaipeda 0.301278 0.324945 0.595564 0.36658
Marijampole 0.332921 0.240862 0.133338 0.159902
Panevezys 0.276282 0.2381 0.269207 0.309908
Siauliai 0.303937 0.282837 0.171595 0.199375
Taurage 0.34276 0.191281 0.066045 0.073871
Telsiai 0.288248 0.346501 0.387665 0.425881
Utena 0.250755 0.17238 0.260348 0.328713
Vilnius 0.379722 0.562017 0.444273 0.455714
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
Alytus 0.283 0.223 0.27817 0.054013
Kaunas 0.370569 0.355186 0.470832 0.220017
Klaipeda 0.252608 0.404747 0.3561 0.314277
Marijampole 0.283206 0.287453 0.25436 0.05098
Panevezys 0.266262 0.356838 0.28142 0.062879
Siauliai 0.215714 0.290757 0.25869 0.084227
Taurage 0.286367 0.284149 0.18942 0.04503
Telsiai 0.220533 0.254412 0.19807 0.900135
Utena 0.218279 0.223024 0.24570 0.033598
Vilnius 0.585454 0.413007 0.4773 0.151189
rank
sum 2002
Alytus 2.696 6
Kaunas 3.242 2
Klaipeda 3.045 4
Marijampole 2.947 5
Panevezys 2.481 7
Siauliai 2.334 8
Taurage 1.959 10
Telsiai 2.249 9
Utena 3.202 3
Vilnius 4.375 1
Tables Ad and Ae, the part of the Reference Point theory in
MOORA (2002)
Ad. Reference Point Theory with Ratios: coordinates of the
reference point equal to the maximal objective values
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
[r.sub.i] 0.5123 0.35372 0.46613 0.2010
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
[r.sub.i] 0.379927 0.359 0.354 0.397
retail
products trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
[r.sub.i] 0.379722 0.562017 0.595564 0.455714
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
[r.sub.i] 0.58545 0.2230 0.477326 0.033598
Ae. Reference Point Theory: Deviations from the reference point
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
Alytus 0.3566 0.034 0.1622 0.1748
Kaunas 0.3345 0.06521 0.25804 0.0000
Klaipeda 0.5208 0.0083 0.21585 0.0218
Marijampole 0.095 0.04183 0.18279 0.149
Panevezys 0.8205 0.06152 0.15964 0.1311
Siauliai 0.7687 0.050 0.058 0.1923
Taurage 1.0444 0.03722 0 0.1835
Telsiai 0.5791 0.03014 0.13146 0.079
Utena 0.2691 0 0.20214 0.1049
Vilnius 0 0.0529 0.21737 0.0481
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
Alytus 0.077704 0.032 0.019 0.0686
Kaunas 0.070184 0.028 0.049 0.1578
Klaipeda 0.039747 0.072 0.034 0.1420
Marijampole 0.109574 0.069 0.084 0.01
Panevezys 0.075198 0.024 0.015 0.075
Siauliai 0.090953 0.05 0.027 0.108
Taurage 0.120674 0.044 0.053 0
Telsiai 0.04476 0.05 0.076 0.095
Utena 0.028289 0 0 0.034
Vilnius 0 0.071 0.027 0.172
retail
products trade investment construction
Alytus 0.0303 0.402194 0.3898 0.1562
Kaunas 0.0636 0.147365 0.3437 0.1211
Klaipeda 0.0784 0.237072 0.0000 0.0891
Marijampole 0.0468 0.321155 0.462226 0.295813
Panevezys 0.10344 0.323917 0.326357 0.145807
Siauliai 0.075785 0.27918 0.423969 0.256339
Taurage 0.036962 0.370735 0.529519 0.381843
Telsiai 0.091474 0.215516 0.207899 0.029833
Utena 0.128967 0.389637 0.335216 0.127001
Vilnius 0 0 0.151291 0
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
Alytus 0.3023 0.0000 0.199156 0.020415
Kaunas 0.2149 0.1322 0.006494 0.18642
Klaipeda 0.3328 0.1817 0.121226 0.28068
Marijampole 0.302249 0.064 0.222969 0.017382
Panevezys 0.319193 0.1338 0.1959 0.029281
Siauliai 0.36974 0.0677 0.218639 0.05063
Taurage 0.299088 0.0611 0.287911 0.011433
Telsiai 0.364921 0.031 0.279252 0.866537
Utena 0.367175 0.0000 0.231628 0
Vilnius 0 0.1900 0.00000 0.117592
rank
max. min.
Alytus 0.40219 4
Kaunas 0.34368 2
Klaipeda 0.52080 6
Marijampole 0.46223 5
Panevezys 0.82048 8
Siauliai 0.76873 7
Taurage 1.04442 10
Telsiai 0.86654 9
Utena 0.38964 3
Vilnius 0.21737 1
Table B.1. Negative rank order correlations
Expert Expert Sum of
Items 1 2 ranks D [D.sup.2]
1 1 7 8 -6 36
2 2 6 8 -4 16
3 3 5 8 -2 4
4 4 4 8 0 0
5 5 3 8 2 4
6 6 2 8 4 16
7 7 1 8 6 36
112
Table B.2. Rank order of families by income, monthly
rental and number of persons in the household
Family income rank rental rank persons rank
A $10 000 1 $250 1 6 1
D 7000 2 200 2 5 2
F 5000 3 125 3 4 3
B 4500 4 90 4 3 4
E 4000 5 85 5 2 5
C 500 6 70 6 1 6
Table B.3. Ordinal versus cardinal: comparing the price
of one commodity
Ordinal Cardinal
A 1
2
3
4
5 6.03$
6 6.02$
7 6.01$
B 8 6$
Table 1. The statistical data on economic-social development
of Lithuanian regions for 2005
No Criterion Regions
Units Alytus Kaunas
1 Population migration (net quantity -5.277 -3.636
migration) per 1000
inhabitants
2 Municipal budget's revenue 1000 1.413 1.316
(average amount per capita) LTL
3 Municipal budget's LTL 203.79 173.169
expenditure (average
amount. social security)
4 Unemployment rate (%) % 8.2 8.9
5 Average gross monthly LTL 1072 1192
earnings
6 Average useful floor space [m.sup.2] 25.9 22.8
per capita
7 Number of pre-school number 109 88
establishments (places
per 100 children)
8 Number of schools number 2.81 2.46
(per 1000 of students)
9 Animal products 100 kg 1135 1576
recalculated in terms of
milk (100 kg per 100 ha
of agricultural land)
10 Indicators of activity of LTL 4565 6080
retail trade enterprises
(per capita)
11 Investment in tangible LTL 2175 3166
fixed assets (per capita)
12 Own-account construction LTL 1334.7 1523.0
work carried out within
the country (per capita)
13 Dwellings completed [m.sup.2] 0.102 0.220
(per capita)
14 Registered criminal number 135 181
offences (misdemeanours
per 100,000 inhabitants)
15 Physicians number 23.8 44.1
16 Average pollutant emissions kg 273 1883
per [km.sup.2]
No Criterion Regions
Klaipeda Marijampole Panevezys
1 Population migration (net -1.435 -3.791 -4.627
migration) per 1000
inhabitants
2 Municipal budget's revenue 1.424 1.361 1.366
(average amount per capita)
3 Municipal budget's 178.55 215.696 209.095
expenditure (average
amount. social security)
4 Unemployment rate (%) 7.0 3.0 10.8
5 Average gross monthly 1256 1001 1094
earnings
6 Average useful floor space 21.5 22.7 25.8
per capita
7 Number of pre-school 102 95 105
establishments (places
per 100 children)
8 Number of schools 2.59 3.01 2.97
(per 1000 of students)
9 Animal products 1378 1306 1210
recalculated in terms of
milk (100 kg per 100 ha
of agricultural land)
10 Indicators of activity of 6488 7024 5079
retail trade enterprises
(per capita)
11 Investment in tangible 4934 1834 2284
fixed assets (per capita)
12 Own-account construction 2494.0 994.2 1135.3
work carried out within
the country (per capita)
13 Dwellings completed 0.177 0.079 0.080
(per capita)
14 Registered criminal 270 116 196
offences (misdemeanours
per 100,000 inhabitants)
15 Physicians 31.9 20.6 26.8
16 Average pollutant emissions 2348 420 482
per [km.sup.2]
No Criterion Regions
Siauliai Taurage Telsiai
1 Population migration (net -5.748 -5.986 -5.522
migration) per 1000
inhabitants
2 Municipal budget's revenue 1.365 1.431 1.383
(average amount per capita)
3 Municipal budget's 220.793 241.635 223.101
expenditure (average
amount. social security)
4 Unemployment rate (%) 10.1 6.0 7.9
5 Average gross monthly 1049 936 1248
earnings
6 Average useful floor space 23.1 22.7 22.6
per capita
7 Number of pre-school 89 95 86
establishments (places
per 100 children)
8 Number of schools 3.14 3.43 3.34
(per 1000 of students)
9 Animal products 1087 1152 1137
recalculated in terms of
milk (100 kg per 100 ha
of agricultural land)
10 Indicators of activity of 4871 3798 4338
retail trade enterprises
(per capita)
11 Investment in tangible 2002 1194 2739
fixed assets (per capita)
12 Own-account construction 916.2 804.5 1040.9
work carried out within
the country (per capita)
13 Dwellings completed 0.057 0.070 0.079
(per capita)
14 Registered criminal 208 252 149
offences (misdemeanours
per 100,000 inhabitants)
15 Physicians 23.1 19.2 18.3
16 Average pollutant emissions 689 394 7868
per [km.sup.2]
No Criterion Regions
Utena Vilnius
1 Population migration (net -4.663 2.238
migration) per 1000
inhabitants
2 Municipal budget's revenue 1.546 1.314
(average amount per capita)
3 Municipal budget's 199.114 198.874
expenditure (average
amount. social security)
4 Unemployment rate (%) 6.0 8.6
5 Average gross monthly 1231 1487
earnings
6 Average useful floor space 28.7 24.3
per capita
7 Number of pre-school 104 96
establishments (places
per 100 children)
8 Number of schools 3.41 2.72
(per 1000 of students)
9 Animal products 1106 1691
recalculated in terms of
milk (100 kg per 100 ha
of agricultural land)
10 Indicators of activity of 4559 10453
retail trade enterprises
(per capita)
11 Investment in tangible 3545 5653
fixed assets (per capita)
12 Own-account construction 1573.8 2619.8
work carried out within
the country (per capita)
13 Dwellings completed 0.062 0.382
(per capita)
14 Registered criminal 165 332
offences (misdemeanours
per 100,000 inhabitants)
15 Physicians 22.7 43.7
16 Average pollutant emissions 188 1074
per [km.sup.2]
Source: Department of Statistics to the Government of the
Republic of Lithuania (Statistics Lithuania) 2006.
Table 2. Classification of the Lithuanian regions by the
average gross monthly earnings for 2005 (in Litas)
1 Vilnius 1487
2 Klaipeda 1256
3 Telsiai 1248
4 Utena 1231
5 Kaunas 1192
6 Panevezys 1094
7 Alytus 1072
8 Siauliai 1049
9 Marijampole 1001
10 Taurage 936
Table 3. MOORA applied on 16 objectives for the 10 Lithuanian
Regions (2005)
3a. Matrix of Responses of Regions on Objectives: (xl7)
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
MAX. MAX. MAX. MIN.
Alytus -5.277 1.413 203.790 8.2
Kaunas -3.636 1.316 173.169 8.9
Klaipeda -1.435 1.424 178.550 7
Marijampole -3.791 1.361 215.696 3
Panevezys -4.627 1.366 209.095 10.8
Siauliai -5.748 1.365 220.793 10.1
Taurage -5.986 1.431 241.635 6
Telsiai -5.522 1.383 223.101 7.9
Utena -4.663 1.546 199.114 6
Vilnius 2.238 1.314 198.874 8.6
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
MAX. MAX. MAX. MAX.
Alytus 1072 25.9 109 2.81
Kaunas 1192 22.8 88 2.46
Klaipeda 1256 21.5 102 2.59
Marijampole 1001 22.7 95 3.01
Panevezys 1094 25.8 105 2.97
Siauliai 1049 23.1 89 3.14
Taurage 936 22.7 95 3.43
Telsiai 1248 22.6 86 3.34
Utena 1231 28.7 104 3.41
Vilnius 1487 24.3 96 2.72
products retail trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
MAX. MAX. MAX. MAX.
Alytus 1135 4565 2175 1334.7
Kaunas 1576 6080 3166 1523
Klaipeda 1378 6488 4934 2494
Marijampole 1306 7024 1834 994.2
Panevezys 1210 5079 2284 1135.3
Siauliai 1087 4871 2002 916.2
Taurage 1152 3798 1194 804.5
Telsiai 1137 4338 2739 1040.9
Utena 1106 4559 3545 1573.8
Vilnius 1691 10453 5653 2619.8
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
MAX. MIN. MAX. MIN.
Alytus 0.102 135 23.8 273
Kaunas 0.22 181 44.1 1883
Klaipeda 0.177 270 31.9 2348
Marijampole 0.079 116 20.6 420
Panevezys 0.08 196 26.8 482
Siauliai 0.057 208 23.1 689
Taurage 0.07 252 19.2 394
Telsiai 0.079 149 18.3 7868
Utena 0.062 165 22.7 188
Vilnius 0.382 332 43.7 1074
Subtables 3b and 3c: the part of the MOORA Ratio System for the 10
Lithuanian Regions (2005)
3b. Sum of squares and their square roots
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
Alytus 27.847 1.9966 41530 67.24
Kaunas 13.22 1.7319 29988 79.21
Klaipeda 2.0592 2.0278 31880 49
Marijampole 14.372 1.8523 46525 9
Panevezys 21.409 1.866 43721 116.64
Siauliai 33.04 1.8632 48750 102.01
Taurage 35.832 2.0478 58387 36
Telsiai 30.492 1.9127 49774 62.41
Utena 21.744 2.3901 39646 36
Vilnius 5.0086 1.7266 39551 73.96
[SIGMA] 205.02 19.41 429752 631
root 14.319 4.4062 655.55 25.129
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
Alytus 1149184 670.8 11881 7.8961
Kaunas 1420864 519.8 7744 6.0516
Klaipeda 1577536 462.3 10404 6.7081
Marijampole 1002001 515.3 9025 9.0601
Panevezys 1196836 665.6 11025 8.8209
Siauliai 1100401 533.6 7921 9.8596
Taurage 876096 515.3 9025 11.765
Telsiai 1557504 510.8 7396 11.156
Utena 1515361 823.7 10816 11.628
Vilnius 2211169 590.5 9216 7.3984
[SIGMA] 13606952 5808 94453 90
root 3688.76 76.21 307.3 9.5049
products retail trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
Alytus 1288225 20839225 4730625 1781424
Kaunas 2483776 36966400 10023556 2319529
Klaipeda 1898884 42094144 24344356 6220036
Marijampole 1705636 49336576 3363556 988433.6
Panevezys 1464100 25796241 5216656 1288906
Siauliai 1181569 23726641 4008004 839422.4
Taurage 1327104 14424804 1425636 647220.3
Telsiai 1292769 18818244 7502121 1083473
Utena 1223236 20784481 12567025 2476846
Vilnius 2859481 109265209 31956409 6863352
[SIGMA] 16724780 362051965 105137944 24508643
root 4089.594 19027.663 10253.680 4950.62
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
Alytus 0.0104 18225 566.44 74529
Kaunas 0.0484 32761 1944.81 3545689
Klaipeda 0.03133 72900 1017.61 5513104
Marijampole 0.00624 13456 424.36 176400
Panevezys 0.0064 38416 718.24 232324
Siauliai 0.00325 43264 533.61 474721
Taurage 0.0049 63504 368.64 155236
Telsiai 0.00624 22201 334.89 61905424
Utena 0.00384 27225 515.29 35344
Vilnius 0.14592 110224 1909.69 1153476
[SIGMA] 0.26693 442176 8333.58 73266247
root 0.51665 664.963 91.2884 8559.57
3c. Objectives divided by their square roots and the results of the
ratio system
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
Alytus -0.369 0.3207 0.3109 0.3263
Kaunas -0.254 0.2987 0.2642 0.3542
Klaipeda -0.1 0.3232 0.2724 0.2786
Marijampole -0.265 0.3089 0.329 0.1194
Panevezys -0.323 0.31 0.319 0.4298
Siauliai -0.401 0.3098 0.3368 0.4019
Taurage -0.418 0.3248 0.3686 0.2388
Telsiai -0.386 0.3139 0.3403 0.3144
Utena -0.326 0.3509 0.3037 0.2388
Vilnius 0.1563 0.2982 0.3034 0.3422
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
Alytus 0.290613 0.340 0.355 0.296
Kaunas 0.323144 0.299 0.286 0.2588
Klaipeda 0.340494 0.282 0.332 0.2725
Marijampole 0.271365 0.298 0.309 0.3167
Panevezys 0.296577 0.339 0.342 0.3125
Siauliai 0.284377 0.303 0.29 0.3304
Taurage 0.253744 0.298 0.309 0.3609
Telsiai 0.338325 0.297 0.28 0.3514
Utena 0.333716 0.377 0.338 0.3588
Vilnius 0.403116 0.319 0.312 0.2862
products retail trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
Alytus 0.278 0.240 0.212 0.270
Kaunas 0.385368 0.3195348 0.3087672 0.307638
Klaipeda 0.336953 0.3409772 0.4811931 0.503775
Marijampole 0.319347 0.3691467 0.1788626 0.200823
Panevezys 0.295873 0.2669272 0.2227493 0.229325
Siauliai 0.265797 0.2559957 0.195247 0.185068
Taurage 0.281691 0.1996041 0.116446 0.162505
Telsiai 0.278023 0.2279839 0.2671236 0.210256
Utena 0.270442 0.2395985 0.3457295 0.3179
Vilnius 0.413488 0.5493581 0.5513143 0.529186
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
Alytus 0.197 0.203 0.26071 0.031894
Kaunas 0.42582 0.2722 0.48308 0.219988
Klaipeda 0.34259 0.40604 0.34944 0.274313
Marijampole 0.15291 0.17445 0.22566 0.049068
Panevezys 0.15484 0.29475 0.29357 0.056311
Siauliai 0.11033 0.3128 0.25304 0.080495
Taurage 0.13549 0.37897 0.21032 0.04603
Telsiai 0.15291 0.22407 0.20046 0.919205
Utena 0.12 0.24813 0.24866 0.021964
Vilnius 0.73937 0.49928 0.4787 0.125474
sum rank
Alytus 2.170 7
Kaunas 2.860 3
Klaipeda 3.118 2
Marijampole 2.672 5
Panevezys 2.278 6
Siauliai 1.923 9
Taurage 1.939 8
Telsiai 1.414 10
Utena 2.770 4
Vilnius 4.373 1
Subtables 3d and 3e: the part of the MOORA Reference Point Theory for
the 10 Lithuanian Regions (2005)
3d. Reference Point Theory with Ratios: coordinates of the reference
point equal to the maximal objective values
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
[r.sub.i] 0.1563 0.3509 0.3686 0.1194
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
[r.sub.i] 0.403116 0.377 0.355 0.361
products retail trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
[r.sub.i] 0.413488 0.549358 0.551314 0.529186
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
[r.sub.i] 0.73937 0.1744 0.48308 0.021964
3e. Reference Point Theory: Deviations from the reference point
immigration revenue expenditure unemploym.
1 2 3 4
Alytus 0.5248 0.030 0.0577 0.2069
Kaunas 0.4102 0.0522 0.1044 0.2348
Klaipeda 0.2565 0.0277 0.0962 0.1592
Marijampole 0.4211 0.042 0.0396 0.000
Panevezys 0.4794 0.0409 0.0496 0.3104
Siauliai 0.5577 0.041 0.032 0.2825
Taurage 0.5744 0.0261 0 0.1194
Telsiai 0.542 0.037 0.0283 0.195
Utena 0.482 0 0.0649 0.1194
Vilnius 0 0.0527 0.0652 0.2228
earnings floor-space pre-schools schools
5 6 7 8
Alytus 0.112504 0.037 0 0.0652
Kaunas 0.079973 0.077 0.068 0.1021
Klaipeda 0.062623 0.094 0.023 0.0884
Marijampole 0.131752 0.079 0.046 0.0442
Panevezys 0.10654 0.038 0.013 0.0484
Siauliai 0.118739 0.073 0.065 0.0305
Taurage 0.149373 0.079 0.046 0
Telsiai 0.064791 0.08 0.075 0.0095
Utena 0.0694 0 0.016 0.0021
Vilnius 0 0.058 0.042 0.0747
products retail trade investment construction
9 10 11 12
Alytus 0.1360 0.3094 0.3392 0.2596
Kaunas 0.0281 0.2298 0.2425 0.2215
Klaipeda 0.0765 0.2084 0.0701 0.0254
Marijampole 0.094141 0.1802113 0.3724517 0.328363
Panevezys 0.117616 0.2824309 0.328565 0.299861
Siauliai 0.147692 0.2933624 0.3560673 0.344118
Taurage 0.131798 0.3497539 0.4348683 0.366681
Telsiai 0.135466 0.3213742 0.2841907 0.31893
Utena 0.143046 0.3097595 0.2055847 0.211287
Vilnius 0 0 0 0
criminal total
dwellings acts physicians pollution
13 14 15 16
Alytus 0.5419 0.0286 0.22237 0.00993
Kaunas 0.3136 0.0977 0 0.198024
Klaipeda 0.3968 0.2316 0.13364 0.252349
Marijampole 0.58647 0.000 0.25743 0.027104
Panevezys 0.58453 0.1203 0.1895 0.034348
Siauliai 0.62905 0.1384 0.23004 0.058531
Taurage 0.60389 0.2045 0.27276 0.024067
Telsiai 0.58647 0.050 0.28262 0.897241
Utena 0.61937 0.0737 0.23442 0
Vilnius 0 0.3248 0.00438 0.10351
rank
max. min.
Alytus 0.541948 4
Kaunas 0.410234 3
Klaipeda 0.39678 2
Marijampole 0.58647 6
Panevezys 0.58453 5
Siauliai 0.62905 9
Taurage 0.60389 7
Telsiai 0.89724 10
Utena 0.61937 8
Vilnius 0.32483 1
Table 4. Ranking of the Lithuanian Regions according
to their well-being importance
MOORA MOORA
ratio system reference point
Regions Income 2005 2005
Vilnius 1 1 1
Klaipeda 2 2 2
Kaunas 5 3 3
Utena 4 4 8
Marijampole 9 5 6
Panevezys 6 6 5
Alytus 7 7 4
Taurage 10 8 7
Siauliai 8 9 9
Telsiai 3 10 10
MOORA MOORA
ratio system reference point
Regions 2002 2002
Vilnius 1 1
Klaipeda 4 6
Kaunas 2 2
Utena 3 3
Marijampole 5 5
Panevezys 7 8
Alytus 6 4
Taurage 10 10
Siauliai 8 7
Telsiai 9 9