Additive measurement of market concentration.
Ginevicius, Romualdas ; Cirba, Stasys
1. Introduction
Today, the success of an enterprise depends on its ability to sell
the products under the conditions of fierce competition rather than on
its ability to manufacture goods. Therefore, the focus has shifted from
production to marketing and market relations. Enterprises should notice
in time new prospects of development and threats--to take use of the
former and to avoid the latter. In this environment, the best way to
success is to adapt to constantly changing market conditions. An
enterprise can survive if the complexity and dynamics of the decisions
made are adequate to the complexity and dynamics of the environment
(Ansoft 1965; Ginevicius 1998, 2009).
One of the main principles, on which enterprise adaptation to
constantly changing market conditions depends, is the increase of the
scope of production or production concentration. It is influenced by
both external and internal factors because reinforcement and extension
of the market share largely depends on the increase of productivity. On
the other hand, the long-term experience shows that the introduction of
up-to-date machinery and advanced technologies and their effective use,
in particular, is possible only by concentrating the production. Thus,
fierce competition in the market gives rise to the need for production
concentration. In turn, the growth of the scope of production causes the
increase of productivity as well as competitiveness of an enterprise.
2. Additive measures of market concentration
Though the globalization process taking place in the world
contributes to the concentration of production and markets, the problems
of concentration measurement do not receive the attention they deserve.
This is confirmed by the fact that rather outdated measures are used now
for measuring concentration (Herfindahl 1950; Horwath 1970; Spuretling
1970; Hani 1987; Rosenbluth 1955, 1961; Hall, Tideman 1967).
Their drawbacks have been demonstrated more than once, however, new
more accurate measures have not been offered (Hani 1987; Ginevicius
2005; Ginevicius, Cirba 2007). Searching for a better measure of
concentration, it could be helpful to revise the commonly used ones,
demonstrating why they cannot be fully acceptable.
Actually, in all cases, concentration measurement is based on the
concept of concentration curve. This curve can be obtained if we plot on
the abscissa of the system of coordinates the market players (criterion
bearers) in the descending order of their values and the respective
additive values (the sums of criterion bearers)--on the ordinate (Piesch
1975).
The additive concentration measures cover all the criterion
bearers' values of the ordinate of the concentration curve. The
variants of these measures are obtained by applying various schemes of
determining the significance of criterion bearers.
Due to its simplicity, Herfindahl index is most commonly used now
for market concentration measurement. It is obtained by raising to the
square and summing up relative values of criterion bearers (Herfindahl
1950):
HER = [n.summation over (i=1)] [P.sup.2.sub.i], (1)
where HER is Herfindahl concentration index; [P.sub.i] is a
relative value of i-th criterion bearer in fractures of unity; n is the
number of criterion bearers.
Considering the problem of Herfindahl index applicability, basic
principles of determining the significance of criterion bearers should
be analysed. It follows from the formula (1) that the criterion bearers
which obtained a larger part of their sum are assigned a larger weight,
while those, which obtained a smaller part of this sum, get a smaller
weight. This is a natural result of weighting the criterion bearers with
respect to each other, i.e. raising their values to the square. Then,
for example, the relation between the values of two criterion bearers
2:1 is turned by the Herfindahl index to the relation 4:1, the relation
4:1 is turned to 16:1, etc. It follows that, actually, the value of HER
is determined by the criterion bearers with large values, while the
criterion bearers with small values, even in large number, have
insignificant effect on the result. Thus, a measure distorts actual
market concentration. Moreover, its insensitivity to the criterion
bearers with small values makes it hardly suitable for investigations
primarily aimed at determining the effect of small or new criterion
bearers on the market structure. On the other hand, if the emphasis is
placed on large market players in the competitive environment, the
results yielded by Herfindahl index are rather accurate.
The next additive measure of concentration is the Horwath index
(Horwath 1970):
HOR = [P.sub.1] + [n.summation over (i=2)] [P.sup.2.sub.i] (2 -
[P.sub.i]), (2)
where HOR is Horwath index; [P.sub.1] is the market share of the
largest criterion bearer.
The Horwath index assigns larger weights to all market players
compared to Herfindahl index. The main emphasis is placed on the largest
criterion bearer, whose absolute value is presented in the measure.
Unlike HER, the Horwath index, due to some peculiarities of the
criterion bearer's weight determination, does not accumulate the
value in the lower variation interval, ranging from 0 to 1. In this way,
the threat of improper evaluation of actual market concentration is also
avoided. On the contrary, a trend of accumulating the points in the
middle or upper part of the interval can be observed (Hani 1987). The
situation is balanced by assigning a larger weight to smaller criterion
bearers, compensating the domination of large criterion bearers.
The structure of the Horwath index is not ideal. First, its
division into discrete and additive parts is not well grounded. It is
also not clear why only one, the largest criterion bearer, but not two
or three of them, is taken into consideration in the discrete part of
formula (2). The determination of the criterion bearer's
significance in the additive part of the formula (2) is not clear
either. Its values range from 1,5 to 2 for larger criterion bearers,
while the value of smaller criterion bearers is equal to 2.
Another additive concentration measure is entropy (Spuretling
1970):
ENT = - [n.summation over (i=1)] [P.sub.i] ln [P.sub.i], (3)
where ENT is the measure of entropy.
A measure of entropy also provides for a different approach to
determining weights of criterion bearers, compared to that used in
Herfindahl index, which is based on the entropy's logarithm rather
than their value. As a result, the significance of larger criterion
bearers is decreased, while that of the smaller ones is respectively
increased.
The value of entropy's measure, ENT, shows the information
which may be generally expected when one of all events happens. The
question arises, why this concept of the information theory may be used
as a concentration measure. The relationship between the competition
level and entropy is evident in the case of pure monopoly because, in
the absence of competition, a monopolist should not worry that a
customer would not choose his product. When the number of suppliers
increases, implying that the competition is getting more fierce, the
uncertainty of the supplier, who cannot be sure that a customer will
choose his particular product (service), is increasing. Moreover, the
above uncertainty also depends on the relative size of a supplying
enterprise. Thus, entropy may be treated as a measure of competition,
depending on market structure and performance, and strongly affected by
a concentration measure (Horowitz, A. R., Horowitz, J. 1968).
The analysis of entropy's measure shows that its theoretical
basis differs considerably from measures based on the concentration
curve. This makes its interpretation and comparison with them more
complicated.
One more additive concentration measure is the index suggested by
Hani (Hani 1987):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
where EXP is the index offered by Hani.
A comparison of Herfindahl and Hani's indices shows that the
latter only differently evaluates the significance of large and small
criterion bearers. In particular, Herfindahl index is more sensitive to
large criterion bearers, while Hani's index--to small ones. This
affects the capacities of calculating the indices. To calculate the
latter index, a distribution of the value of all criterion bearers of
the market should be known. To obtain an approximate but relatively
precise value of Herfindahl index, a 'reduced' distribution of
the concentration curve is sufficient. The empirical study of
Hani's index shows that the concentration of points can be observed
at the lower part of the interval of the expected values (0:I), similar
to the case of HER index. The calculated values are usually smaller than
the respective values of Herfindahl index. Thus, the probability that
intuitively real level of concentration will be underestimated
increases.
Another additive concentration measure is Rosenbluth index (Hall,
Tideman 1967; Rosenbluth 1955, 1961):
ROS = 1/2[n.summation over (i=1)] i[P.sub.i]-1], (5)
where ROS is Rosenbluth concentration index.
Rosenbluth index provides for the following principle of ranking
the criterion bearers: the larger the total number of criterion bearers,
the larger weight is assigned to small criterion bearers. Therefore,
this index is more sensitive to their number rather than value. It can
be shown that when the leading criterion bearer has more than 50 % of
their sum total, while the number of the criterion bearers is growing,
the value of ROS index is rapidly approaching zero. Thus, despite the
evident monopolistic nature of the market, a distorted picture of actual
market concentration is shown.
A comparison of the reflection of actual markets by
Rosenbluth's and Herfindahl indices reveals the differences caused
by different approaches to weight determination. The empirical studies performed also show that the differences in values of indices,
considered both from the perspective of their absolute values and the
correlation of ranks, are significant (Hall, Tideman 1967). Both of the
indices, like Hani's index, tend to accumulate the criterion
bearer's points at the lower part of the interval (0:1). Therefore,
all of them are fraught with the threat that, intuitively, the
concentration will be evaluated too low. Greater differences between HER
and ROS indices may be also expected, when large criterion bearers will
dominate in the market structure and their total number will be large at
the same time (Hani 1987).
The so-called GIN index (Ginevicius 2005) was also offered as a
concentration measure:
GIN = [n.summation over (i=1)] [P.sub.i/1 + n (l - [P.sub.i]). (6)
This index is intended to assess two basic market indicators, the
value and the number of the criterion bearers, properly, i.e. in a
balanced way. The author of the concentration index thinks that all
indices offered, except Rosenbluth index, have one common drawback--they
do not emphasize (or emphasize insufficiently) an essential market
attribute, the number of criterion bearers. However, this particular
value reflects the interrelations between market players and customers
characteristic of market economy, implying that the larger the number of
suppliers, the stronger the competition and the higher the uncertainty
because a supplier cannot be sure in this environment that a customer
would choose his product (service) rather than the product of his
competitor. It is clear that this uncertainty depends on the relative
value of the supplying firm, therefore, in the formula, every criterion
bearer is reduced by a coefficient reflecting its weight, depending on
the number of market players as well.
On the other hand, the considered index has other drawbacks. For
example, given a highly concentrated market, consisting of only two
criterion bearers, with the first one possessing 90 % of all market
shares, the value of GIN index is equal to 0.786. It is evident that
this value is not adequate to the real state, i.e. it is too small.
Therefore, more accurate but computationally complicated measure of
concentration (Ginevicius, Cirba 2007) was offered:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
In reviewing concentration indices, the drawbacks observed by other
authors (Hani 1987) were also considered. In addition to the considered
disadvantages, more comprehensive analysis of concentration indices
revealed some other more significant drawbacks associated with the
problems of their application (Ginevicius, Cirba 2007).
One of concentration measure characteristics is that, when the
value of any criterion bearer P is growing, their value should also
increase. However, Horwath's index HOR and a measure of entropy ENT
do not satisfy this condition. For example, we have two P1 and [P.sub.2]
([P.sub.1] = p; [P.sub.2] = 1 -p). In this case:
HOR = [p.sup.3] - [p.sup.2] + 1, (8)
ENT = -p lnp - (1 - p) ln(1 -p). (9)
The graphs drawn according to formulas (8) and (9) are presented in
Fig. 1.
As shown in Fig. 1, min HOR = HOR (2/3) = 23/27 = 0.852.
Other concentration measures, when we have two equivalent bearers
([P.sub.1] = [P.sub.2] = 0.5), obtain the value of 0.5, and, when one of
the bearers is growing, their value is increasing, i.e., when [P.sub.1]
= 0.5, then, HER(0.5) = ROS(0.5) = EXP(0.5) = GIN(0.5) = 0.5.
In Fig. 1 we can see that the maximum value of the entropy's
measure is equal to 0.69, and when the bearer [P.sub.1] is growing, the
value of the measure is decreasing. The analysis of concentration
measures has shown their another characteristic: if the criterion
bearers are of the same magnitude, the relative weight of each bearer in
the value of the measure is the same, being equal to the criterion
bearer's value. To check if ROS index satisfies this condition, it
is expressed as follows:
[n.summation over (i=1)] i[P.sub.i] = 1 + ROS/2 ROS. (10)
By using formula (10), we can approximately estimate a relative
input of each criterion bearer into the value of ROS index. Suppose that
we have four equivalent criterion bearers, i.e. [P.sub.1] = [P.sub.2] =
[P.sub.3] = [P.sub.4] = 0.25. By using formula (10), let us determine a
relative input of each bearer into the value of concentration index ROS
(Table 1).
Thus, the concentration index ROS, unlike other indices, does not
satisfy the above condition.
3. Assessing the accuracy of market concentration measures
The review of market concentration measures made according to the
scheme adopted in the literature on the problem, when all measures are
compared to the most commonly used Herfindahl index, revealed their and
HER index drawbacks. The main of these drawbacks is that all of the
indices provide a distorted (usually, better or worse) view of the
actual market. To consider the problem of the accuracy of a particular
concentration measure, the concepts of actual and calculated market
concentration should be defined. The actual market concentration level
is reflected by the relationship between the absolute or relative values
of criterion bearers. For example, if we take a hypothetical market of
four criterion bearers with absolute values of 40 %, 30 %, 20 % and 10 %
and the respective relative values of 0.4; 0.3; 0.2 and 0.1, the real
state of this market will be shown by the relation 4 : 3 : 2 : 1. The
calculated market concentration will be obtained if we take the relation
of the criterion bearer's value transformed according to the
respective formula of concentration measure (Table 2).
As shown in Table 2, each of the considered indices provides a
different view of market concentration, deviating from the real state to
a various extent. Therefore, the accuracy of a particular concentration
measure should be assessed.
Let us assume that the smaller the total difference between the
criterion bearer's relative value in the market and their relative
value calculated based on the considered market concentration measure,
the more accurate is the market concentration measure, reflecting the
real state of market concentration (Ginevicius 2005):
[R.sub.j] = [n.summation over (i=1)] [absolute value of [P.sub.ij]
- [P.sup.*.sub.ij]], (11)
where [R.sub.j] is the criterion of accuracy of j-th concentration
measure; [P.sup.*.sub.i] is a relative value of i-th criterion bearer
according to the formula of j-th concentration measure.
A concentration measure will be most accurate, when it ideally
reflects the situation in the market, i.e. when [R.sub.j] = 0.
Based on the data presented in Table 2 and using the formulas
(1-6), we will find the values of the criterion [R.sub.j] (Table 3).
As shown in Table 3, none of concentration measures is absolutely
precise because the total difference between the relative value of the
criterion bearers of the market considered and their value according to
the formula of concentration measure is more than zero in all of them.
This stimulates the search for a more accurate concentration measure.
4. Offering a measure of market concentration
Let us take Herfindahl index as a basis for the measure sought. It
has been mentioned that its main drawback is that the assignment of the
weights [w.sub.i] to criterion bearers is not grounded in theoretical
reasoning. Let us assume that [w.sub.i] should satisfy the following
conditions:
1. The value of the measure GRS sought ranges from 0 to 1, i.e. 0
[less than or equal to] GRS [less than or equal to] 1;
2. If all criterion bearers are equal, i.e. when [P.sub.i] = 1/n-,
i = 1, 2, 3, ..., n, then, GRS = 1/n;
3. The value of R should be smaller than its value calculated using
other well-known concentration coefficients.
In searching for a market concentration measure, we will rely on
the concept often used in calculating complicated functions, i.e.
functions developed as a series in powers. They are known as the first
two or three members in the Taylor's series, which are actually
first-or second-power polynomials (Fichtengolcas 1967). For this
purpose, the expression GRS = [an.sup.2] + bn + c is not suitable
because, in this case, the conditions 1-3 will not be met. It follows
that the relations between two second-power polynomials (square
trinomials) are well suited for calculating a concentration index:
GRS= [n.summation over (i=1)] [a.sub.1][n.sup.2] + [b.sub.1]n +
[c.sub.1]/[a.sub.2][n.sup.2] + [b.sub.2]n + [c.sub.2]. [P.sub.i], (12)
where [a.sub.1], [a.sub.2], [b.sub.1], [b.sub.2], [c.sub.1],
[c.sub.1] are constant values or values depending on [P.sub.i] (1[less
than or equal to] i [less than or equal to] n).
The development of the function as the Taylor's series allows
the constant values to be expressed as first- or second-power members,
i.e. [P.sup.2.sub.i], [P.sub.i] [P.sub.j], [P.sub.i], [P.sub.j] . The
value of the index j is fixed. Otherwise, formula (1) would be too
complicated because each member of the sum, including the value of a
concentration index, would depend on j. In this case, the summation
should be made over the index j, and a double sum would be obtained. The
right-hand side of the formula (12) would become too complicated.
Meanwhile, our aim is to obtain a relatively simple expression of market
concentration, which, satisfying the third condition, would be more
accurate than the existing measures. Let us equate the value of index j
to unity because [P.sub.1], i.e. the values of the largest criterion
bearer, is always larger than [P.sub.i], the values of other criterion
bearers. It is clear that the value of the coefficient sought should be
more 'sensitive' to the market share of the first market
player.
For further investigation it is necessary to determine what power
should be assigned to the coefficients of formula (12). If it is not
smaller than two, each coefficient will also get a complicated
expression. Therefore, formula (12) will also become more complicated.
Suppose, the constant a1 is expressed as:
[a.sub.1] = [a.sub.11][P.sub.i][P.sub.1] +
[a.sub.13][P.sup.2.sub.i] + [a.sub.14][P.sup.2.sub.1] +
[a.sub.15][P.sub.1] + [a.sub.16]. (13)
We have six new constants in this formula. In the formula (12), we
also have six constants, therefore, in general, there are 36 new
constants. As a result, the concentration formula has become unsuitable
for calculations. In addition, trying to satisfy the second condition
and using a method of undetermined coefficients, we get a system of six
linear equations with 36 unknowns. Despite the fact that this system has
many unknown coefficients equal to zero or unity, it has a plenty of
solutions, which makes the choice of constants a very complicated task.
The first condition states that coefficient a1 should be smaller
than a2. Otherwise, when the number of criterion bearers in the market
is sufficiently large, particularly when one of them is dominant, the
value of the numerator of the first member of the sum in formula (12)
will be larger than the denominator's value, and the concentration
coefficient will not satisfy the first condition, i.e. it will be larger
than unity. The calculations show that, in this case, it is sufficient
to multiply [a.sub.1] by [P.sub.1] because [a.sub.1]<1.
Thus, limiting the weight of criterion bearers [P.sub.i] by the
first and the second powers and assuming the condition that, in formula
(12), the expression of the numerator and denominator with respect to
[P.sub.i] will be a square trinomial, we will obtain the following
version of the coefficient GRS:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (14)
The values of the coefficients [a.sub.i], [b.sub.i], [c.sub.i] (i =
1, 2) will be obtained based on the second condition. By substituting
[P.sub.i] = 1/n, I = 1, 2, ..., n, into formula (14), we will get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (15)
or
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (16)
It follows that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
and
[a.sub.1][n.sup.4] + [b.sub.1]n+[c.sub.1][n.sup.2] =
[a.sub.2][n.sup.4] + [b.sub.2]n + [c.sub.2]. (17)
By equating the coefficients to the same n degrees, we will get:
[a.sub.1] = [a.sub.2];[b.sub.1] = [b.sub.2];[c.sub.1] = 0;[c.sub.2]
= 0. (18)
By substituting the obtained relationships (18) into formula (14),
we obtain:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)
By factoring out a1 from formula (19) and introducing A =
[b.sub.1]/[a.sub.1] we will get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)
The concentration coefficient calculated by formula (20) will
satisfy the second condition for any a values, however, the first
condition will not be met for all a values. If [P.sub.1] is about unity,
a member of the sum in formula (20) may be larger than unity. The same
also applies to the value of GRS. For example, in the case, when a = -1,
[P.sub.1] = 0.95 and [P.sub.2] = 0.05, we get:
GRS = 1.254 + 0.049 = 1.303 >1.
In the opposite case, when a = 5, [P.sub.1] = 0.95 and [P.sub.2] =
0. 05, we will obtain:
GRS = 0.606 + 0.043 = 0.649,
1. e. the value of concentration coefficient is too small. Both
examples show that the parameter a should satisfy the condition -1 <
a < 5.
It follows from the analysis of the above two cases reflecting the
market structure that it is sufficient to develop a system of
inequalities to be satisfied by the parameter a for a case, when there
are two criterion bearers in the market, with the significances of one
being about the unity.
Thus, we will make a system of inequalities for the case, when
[P.sub.1] = 0.95, and [P.sub.2] = 0.05. It should be noted that this
case is similar to that when confidence intervals are determined in
statistical calculations, with the confidence level a = 0.95
(Cekanavicius, Murauskas 2000)
In making the first inequality, let us rely on a relatively simple
and accurate GIN value for the considered case (GIN = 0.88
[approximately equal to] 0.9) (Ginevicius 2005). In developing the
second inequality, we will base ourselves on the fact that the index
value, calculated using a number of the available concentration
measures, is smaller than [P.sub.1] (except for ENT index, whose value
for the case, when the values of criterion bearers are 0.4; 0.3; 0.2 and
0.1, respectively, is equal to 1.2821, and HOR = 0.644, which is the
least accurate in reflecting the market state).
Thus, we get the following system of inequalities:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
By solving this system of inequalities, we obtain that the
parameter a should meet the condition 0 < a < 0.3.
It follows from the above case, when a = 5; [P.sub.1] = 0.95;
[P.sub.2] = 0.05, that 0.3 should be taken as the value of the parameter
a. By substituting it into the formula (20), we will get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)
Now, we should check if the suggested concentration coefficient
reflects the situation on the market more accurately than other commonly
used measures. For this purpose, we will use formula (11). For example,
let us analyse the already considered hypothecary market, consisting of
four criterion bearers. Their absolute values are 40 %, 30 %, 20 % and
10 %, while relative values are 0.4; 0.3; 0.2; 0.1, respectively. The
calculation results of market concentration measures and the value of
[R.sub.j] are given in Table 3.
As shown in Table 3, the suggested measure of market concentration,
GRS, is most accurate, yielding almost ideal results (only the fourth
number after the point is significant). This allows the authors to offer
this index for use both in the research into the problem of market
concentration and in practical calculations.
5. Conclusions
Various methods are currently used for measuring market
concentration. Herfindahl index is one of the most widely known additive
measures. However, this and other units of measure are far from being
ideal, giving the distorted view of the market. The smaller the total
difference between the relative value of the criterion bearer in the
market and relative value calculated by the formula of an additive
measure, the more accurate is the additive measure. A new formula
suggested in the paper yields, actually, zero deviation, therefore, it
may be used both in theoretical research and practical calculations.
Received 9 January 2009; accepted 13 May 2009
References
Ansoft, H. J. 1965. Corporate strategy. New York: Mebraw-Hill Book
Comp.
Cekanavicius, V.; Murauskas, G. 2000. Statistics and its
applications (Part 1). Vilnius: TEV. 238 p. (in Lithuanian).
Fichtengolcas, G. M. 1967. Fundamentals of mathematical analysis
(Vol. 2). Vilnius: Mintis. 452 p. (in Lithuanian).
Ginevicius, R. 1998. Diversification of enterprise activities.
Vilnius: Technika. 154 p. (in Lithuanian).
Ginevicius, R. 2005. Some problems of measuring absolute market
concentration, in Modern business: priorities of development. Vilnius:
Technika, 12-36 (in Lithuanian).
Ginevicius, R. 2009. Quantitative evaluation of unrelated
diversification of enterprise activities, Journal of Civil Engineering
and Management 15(1): 105-111.
Ginevicius, R.; Cirba, S. 2007. Determining market concentration,
Journal of Business Economics and Management 8(1): 3-10.
Hall, M.; Tideman, N. 1967. Measures of Concentration, Journal of
the American Statistical Association 62: 162-168. 162-168.
doi:10.2307/2282919
Hani, P. K. 1987. Die Messung der Unternehmenskonzentration: eine
theoretische und empirische Evolution von Konzentrationsmfien.
Diss.-Verlag Ruegger.
Herfindahl, O. C. 1950. Concentration in the Steel Industry.
Columbia University.
Horowitz, A. R.; Horowitz, J. 1968. Entropy, Markov processes and
competition in the brewing industry, The Journal of Industrial Economics
16(3): 196-211. doi:10.2307/2097560
Horwath, J. 1970. Suggestion for a comprehensive measure of
concentration, Southern Economic Journal 36(4): 446-452.
doi:10.2307/1056855
Piesch, W. 1975. Statistische Konzentrationsmasse: Formale
Eigenschaften und verteilungstheoretishen Zusammenhan ge, in
Mohr/Siebeck.Tubinger wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Abhandlungen. Vol.
18. Tubingen.
Rosenbluth, G. 1955. Measures of concentration, Business
Concentration and Price Policy. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Special Conference Series No. 5. Princeton, 57-89.
Rosenbluth, G. 1961. Diskussionsbeitrag, in Nichans, J. Round
Table-Gesprach uber Messung des industriellen Konzentration. Berlin:
Duncker & Humbolt, 367-395.
Spuretling, D. 1970. Zur Messung der wirtschafichen Konzentration
und des Wettbewerbsgrades uber einige neuere Masse der Wirtschaflichen
Konzentration, Zeitschrift fur angewewandte Konjukturforschung 16:
238-251.
DOI: 10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.
Romualdas Ginevicius (1), Stasys Cirba (2) Vilnius Gediminas
Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223 Vilnius, Lithuania
E-mails: (1) romualdas.ginevicius@adm.vgtu.lt; (2) jmmat@fm.vgtu.lt
Table 1. Relative input of criterion bearers into the value
of concentration index ROS, when [P.sub.I] = 0.25
Values of bearers
ROS 0.25 0.25 0.25 0.25
Relative input of bearers into index value
0,25 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4
Table 2. The structure of market concentration depending
on the formula used in calculation
Relationships between the values
of criterion bearers
criterion bearers
Concentration
measure first second third fourth
Herfindahl index 16.0 9.0 4.0 1.0
Horwath index 21.1 8.1 3.8 1.0
Entropy index 1.6 1.6 1.4 1.0
Rosenbluth index 1.0 1.5 1.5 1.0
GIN index 5.4 3.6 2.2 1.0
GIS index 3.9 2.8 1.9 1.0
GRS 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0
Table 3. Comparison of the accuracy of concentration measures
Relative value of criterion
bearers in the formula of
concentration measure
Concentration Concentration [P.sup.*. [P.sup.*.
index index value sub.1] sub.2]
HER 0.300 0.533 0.300
HOR 0.644 0.621 0.238
ENT 1.280 0.286 0.282
ROS 0.333 0.200 0.300
GIN 0.266 0.442 0.297
GIS 0.397 0.403 0.291
GRS 0.398 0.399 0.299
Relative value of
criterion bearers
in the formula of
concentration measure
Concentration [P.sup.*. [P.sup.*.
index sub.3] sub.4] R
HER 0.133 0.033 0.268
HOR 0.112 0.030 0.442
ENT 0.251 0.180 0.263
ROS 0.300 0.200 0.400
GIN 0.180 0.083 0.082
GIS 0.202 0.104 0.018
GRS 0.201 0.101 0.000
Fig. 1. Graphical representative of Howarth and
Concentration indices and entropy's measure, when [P.sub.i] = 2
ENT HOR
0.5 0.69 0.875
0.6 0.67 0.856
0.7 0.61 0.853
0.8 0.50 0.872
0.9 0.33 0.919
1.0 0.00 1.0
Note: Table made from bar graph.