If institutional performance matters: development comparisons of Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia.
Tvaronaviciene, Manuela ; Grybaite, Virginija ; Tvaronaviciene, Agne 等
1. Introduction: institutional facet of sustainable development
There is almost unanimous agreement that countries with rather
similar level of economic development can differ a lot. The mostly used
and statistically available indicator of countries development is GDP per capita; nevertheless, it does not reflect multi-facet differences of
seemingly similar countries, which, in their turn, are reflected by
other indicators. In scientific literature devoted to sustainable
development, questions about taking into account various aspects of
development, not embraced by GDP per capita indicator, are being widely
discussed. Arrays of indicators tackling estimation of sustainable
development levels have been elaborated by various scientists and
organizations (Summers, Heston 1991; England 1998; Emes, Hahn 2001; The
World Bank Group 2007; Eisner 1988; Robinson 2004; Hamilton, Clemens
1999; Dasgupta 2007; Grybaite, Tvaronaviciene 2008). Nevertheless, the
issue of development evaluation remains urgent and arguable. While
aspects to be taken into account--economic, social, environmental and
institutional--could be considered as conventional, specific roles,
played by each development facet, still continue to be addressed in
ample discussions. In that context, strand of scientific literature,
tackling role of institutional development side, specifically, is to be
seen as consistent with the topic. Hence, a group of scientists claim
that institutions have to be perceived as a coherent part of sustainable
development: from the one point, it reflects level of development, and,
from the other one, it serves as a driving force pushing towards
quantitative and qualitative prosperity of a country.
Scientists asserting prime importance of institutions in the
process of development have a lot of disagreements on the whole range of
questions, starting from definition of institution (whether political
and economic institutions should be distinguished; whether institutions
and organizations are synonymous, etc.). Another point of polemic concerns origin of institution, i.e. endogenous versus exogenous one.
And the last, even admitting those pitfalls of interpretation, we still
need to select indicators, reflecting institutional state, in order to
be able to take into account institutional development input into
achieved aggregated sustainable development level.
In order to shed light on institution's definition discussion
range, we can employ the World Bank working paper (Acemoglu, Robinson
2008). Authors claim that differences in economic institutions serve as
the main determinant of prosperity across different countries. Economic
institutions are seen as "collective choices that are the outcome
of a political process", i.e. "depend on the nature of
political institutions and the distribution of political power in
society". If to put authors' understanding in the other way,
we perceive that authors distinguish two types of institutions: economic
and political. Political institutions condition efficiency of economic
ones. Economic institutions, in their turn, are the main players
consequently determining level of sustainable development. While
admitting that economic institutions are shaped by political ones, the
authors state that they have "a highly preliminary understanding of
the factors that lead a society into a political equilibrium which
supports good economic institutions". According to authors, some
examples of political transitions leading to accomplishment of economic
outcomes ex-post could be observed. Nevertheless, good practices do not
lead to clear frameworks. We can add, that, according to Acemoglu,
Robinson (2008) the role of geographic, cultural and human interaction
determinants in strengthening economic institutions remains unclear. To
generalize, the impression is that authors' distinguished economic
and political institutions equally efficiently can be renamed,
respectively, into "organizations" and "state
institutions", or policies. We will return to those considerations
after review of other authors' approaches. Other authors (e.g.
North 1991), admit rather similarly that institutions provide the
incentive structure of an economy and that, as the structure evolves, it
shapes the direction of economic movement towards growth, stagnation or
decline. Nevertheless, institutions, according to scientists, could
obtain different meaning. North (1994) perceives institutions as humanly devised formal and informal constraints, respectively, rules, laws,
constitutions, and norms of behaviour, conventions, self-imposed codes
of conduct. Those formal and informal constrains, respectively, define
the incentive structure of societies and, specifically, economies. North
(1991) distinguishes institutions and organizations by indicating, that
it is the interaction between institutions and organizations that shapes
the institutional evolution of an economy. If institutions are the rules
of the game, organizations and their entrepreneurs are the players.
Institutions are the humanly devised constraints that structure human
interaction. Organizations are made up of groups of individuals bound
together by some common purpose to achieve certain objectives. To
generalize that ap proach, it could be stated, that institutions and
organizations must be two interacting parties, the first of which set
rules or transmit those, which are already set, and another party (i.e.
organizations), which act accordingly to the established rules.
Meanwhile authors' further considerations make that understanding
rather obscure by claiming, "organizations include political bodies
(e.g., political parties, the Senate, a city council, regulatory
bodies), economic bodies (e.g., firms, trade unions, family farms,
cooperatives), social bodies (e.g., churches, clubs, athletic
associations)". Frontiers between organizations and political
institutions (terms introduced above by cited authors) remain rather
blunt. Presented considerations appear rather consistent with
North's criticism provided by other authors elaborating role of
institutions in sustainable development process (e.g. Hodgson 2006).
They start from distinguishing the main characteristic features of
institutions, and, later, use those characteristics for comparison of
organizations with institutions. Hence, authors recall, that
"organizations are special institutions that involve (a) criteria
to establish their boundaries and to distinguish their members from
non-members, (b) principles of sovereignty concerning who is in charge,
and (c) chains of command delineating responsibilities within the
organization". Hodgson (2006) claims that North has been
insufficiently clear. To wrap up discussion, we agree that there could
be found rather differing interpretations of institutions. Nevertheless,
we assert that notion of institution is much wider than notion of
organization. To our mind, institutions could be considered in broad and
narrow sense. In broad sense notions of institution embrace
organizations, while in narrow sense North's approach can be
adopted, i.e. "if institutions are the rules of the game,
organizations and their entrepreneurs are the players" (North 1994:
361). It seems that in his comparatively late works North comes to
similar corollary. He agrees that differences between institutions and
organizations depend on the context (recall we introduced context
specification as "narrow" and the "wide" one).
To conclude discussion about institution's notion or its
perception let us stick to contextual framework, i.e. institutions
embrace organizations in their direct understanding. If to consider
further institutional impact on sustainable development processes we
need to take into account both exogenous (outer) and indigenous (inner)
stimuli to expand on various possible modes.
Nevertheless, for estimation purposes first of all we will consider
the role of institutions as environment conditioning tools. The better
institutional performance at separately taken country, the better
performance of organizations-market players, and the faster sustainable
development processes. We adopt that premise, or to put it another way,
hypothesis, we will employ for further elaborations.
2. Composing indicators' set in order to reflect institutional
aspect of sustainable development
Despite principle agreement about impact of institutions on
economic growth and sustainable development, a lot of criticism claiming
comparative importance of other driving forces goes in parallel (Glaeser
et al. 2004). Not going into polemic and basing our further elaborations
on the premise about significance of institutions, let us choose a set
of indicators suitable for further analysis, i.e. for processing by
mathematical methods such as multi-criteria ones. As role of
institutions could be partially expressed in their business environment
conditioning outcomes, Economic Freedom of the World (EFW) index
constructed by Gwartney and Lawson (2003) is widely discussed. Many
authors (Ulubasoglu, Doucouliagos 2004) agree that both political and
economic freedom impacts growth significantly and, as they claim, it has
a positive effect. Alas, choosing compounding indicators for the set,
reflecting institutional development facet, appears to be a much more
complicated task. Authors indicate a wide array of possibly important
aspects, which should be taken into account. One group of scientists
(Gwartney et al. 2006) express an idea that institutional quality could
be reflected through private investment. It means, that not only
business environment (e.g. measured by EFW), but also supposed outcomes
are important. Here we need to recall, that direction of relationship,
i.e. whether institutional environment causes investments, whether
investments just reflect quality of institutions, remains an arguable
issue. Another group of scientists (e.g. Rodrik 2000) raise a question,
which institutions are important, and consequently, (we reckon) what
effects should be measurable. E.g., the following facets of
institutional impact are being listed: property rights, macroeconomic stabilization, social insurance, and conflict management. It is obvious
that listed facets of institutional performance embrace a too wide range
of sustainable development facets.
To our mind, tackling institutional development impact on
sustainable development it is reasonable to distinguish two general
groups of indicators: economic indicators, and institutional indicators.
It is obvious, that those groups in some respects overlap (e.g. Redek,
Susjan 2005), and any attribution to one or another group is rather
conditional (Grybaite, Tvaronaviciene 2008). Agreeing, that economic
indicators would embrace major macroeconomic and some social facets
(Table 1, Economic indicators), let us concentrate further very
specifically on indicators, which do not fall under economic development
characteristics. Taking into account the above presented considerations
about direct or indirect interconnection of almost all sustainable
development indicators let us select indicators, which would reflect
institutions in "narrow" sense, as was distinguished in
theoretical discussion about institution's perception. Hence, the
following indicators, as reflecting institutional impact on sustainable
development processes are being selected: Rule of law (measuring
perceptions of the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide
by the rules of society, and, in particular the quality of contract
enforcement, property rights, the police, and the courts, as well as the
likelihood of crime and violence), Government effectiveness index
(measuring perceptions of the quality of public services, the quality of
the civil service and the degree of its independence from political
pressures, the quality of policy formulation and implementation, and the
credibility of the government's commitment to such policies), GDP
on R&D, % of GDP, Level of Internet access, Level of citizen's
confidence in EU institutions, in per cent, Index of Economic Freedom,
Corruption perception index, E-government online availability, in per
cent, Voter turnout in national and EU parliamentary elections, in per
cent (Table 1, Institutional indicators). Listed indicators will
comprise institutional indicator group, while estimating relative
sustainable development level of Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia.
Indicators, included into the set (Table 1) meet the following
requirements (Bruntland (1987); National Strategy for ... (2003); Disano
(2002): they do not contradict each other; could be put into the
hierarchical range according to significance; are intrinsic to all
considered countries; numeric values of chosen indicators are available.
Indicators are attributed to two groups, representing, respectively,
economic and institutional aspects of development.
3. Quantitative evaluation of relative sustainable development in
Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia
Indicators' set, or we could call it a system, is composed ad
hoc to reflect institutional aspect of sustainable development. To put
it another way, we suggested the set of indicators, which is customized
for research purposes, i.e. is suitable for revelation of relative
impact of institutional development on aggregated level of sustainable
development. Recall, that complexity of task to construct a set of
indicators reflecting the level of country's sustainable
development and variety of opinions has led to a situation in which,
e.g. Germany uses a system, which includes 218 indicators; France's
and Finland's systems include, respectively, 307 and 88 indicators
(Statistical Office.. .2004; Department of Statistics.2007; United
Nations 2007).
As it was pointed above, the presented paper does not aim to
compliment devised sets of indicators already reflecting a wide range of
development aspects. On the contrary, authors raise questions of
practical application of complex approach, i.e. how aggregation
technique of rather limited indicators' set affects country's
ranging. Composing indicators' set, modelling different
significances and application of multi-criteria evaluation on data of
Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia, would allow us to reveal limits, within
which obtained results could fluctuate. Fluctuation range, in its turn,
would indicate how much results could be affected by application of
different development estimation premises.
Authors have chosen presented research questions for clearly set
practical purposes. Multi-criteria methods, as a rule, use experts'
questioning. For countries' comparisons multi-criteria methods,
which conventionally suggest participation of experts, are usually
applied. We assert that the so-called "experts" in that
particular case would express only their personal beliefs and values;
discussion about, what aspects of development are more significant, is
too great and complex to be wrapped up by experts. Opinions about more
or less significant development sides can vary; experts could be biased.
Switching from experts' questioning to modelling of significances
of indicators included into set, would allow us to reveal how much
results could change if differently thinking groups of experts would be
employed. Those revealed differences are seen as tertiary data letting
to judge about the impact of institutional development on sustainable
development level, when different approaches to significances of
economic and institutional aspects are being adopted.
3.1. Multi-criteria method and indicators' weighting
Multi-criteria method allows us to aggregate values of included
indicators into system, and receive the value of one integral indicator.
That integral indicator would represent measure of considered
countries' development at a particular moment. Computing of such
indicators for a certain period (in our case years 2004-2008) allow
deriving tendency of development of a concrete country. Integral
indicators computed for Baltic countries would allow comparing countries
and getting insights of their development specifics.
We will use the most popular method: multi-criteria complex
proportional method (MCP). This method is used to normalize (convert
indicators being maximized and minimized into one direction changing
ones) values of included into system indicators (Ginevicius et al. 2006;
Ginevicius 2006, 2008; Ginevicius, Podvezko 2008a, b; Zavadskas et al.
2006, 2008; Zavadskas 2008; Turskis et al. 2009). Not going into
details, we just recall principles of multi-criteria methods'
application.
Multi-criteria methods are devised to connect the product of two
values. The first value is significance or weight of a particular
indicator included into system; the second value is the value of the
indicator, for which significance has been determined. Usually
significances are set as decimals, sum of which is equal to one (1):
[m.summation over (i=1)] [w.sub.i] = 1, (1)
where [w.sub.i] - i- significance of considered indicator ; m -
number of indicators included into system (i = 1, n).
In our case multi-criteria evaluation was performed on 19
indicators' basis (Table 1). Development of Lithuania, Latvia and
Estonia was estimated taking annual values of considered indicators
[r.sub.ij] (i = 1, ... m; j = 1, ...,n), where m - number of indicators,
n - number of countries.
Researchers' input includes selecting indicators to include
into system, characterizing elaborated phenomenon, and attributing
significances to those indicators. The mostly spread approach to
deciding, what significance to attribute to a particular indicator, is
to employ experts. Experts are extremely useful in providing information
about e.g. personal priorities, perception of stimuli for work, etc.
Considering such a complicated question as estimation of countries'
development we allowed that opinions of experts, which due to a variety
of beliefs, can be diametrically different. Even more, there is a
principal question if opinions of randomly chosen experts in our case
can be employed. Different sets of experts most likely would give
different weights. For those reasons we adopted an idea to model
mathematically three plausibly different approaches to development; one
would emphasize economic aspects of development, the second one would
emphasize institutional aspects, and in the third case all indicators
included into system would be considered as equally significant.
Comparisons of resulting aggregated indicators' values would reveal
how much adopted approach reflected by attributed significances affects
the final result.
To get answers to the raised scientific question, three different
situations are being mathematically modelled.
In the first situation economic aspects of development are
considered as the most important and, appropriately, economic indicators
receive the highest significances.
In the second situation institutional aspects are more stressed,
hence, higher significances are attributed to them.
In the third situation economic and institutional aspects are
considered equally important; hence all indicators receive the equal
significances.
3.2. Results of Baltic countries' development estimation in
the EU context
In the first mathematically modelled situation economic aspects of
development are stressed; the highest significances are attributed to
indicators included into group of economic ones (Table 1). Data employed
in calculations represent mathematical averages of selected indicators,
computed for years 2004-2008. Rationale behind choosing of averages lies
in the following considerations. As we know, macroeconomic conditions
during the last years have been changing drastically in the majority of
countries. Notion of sustainable development embrace a vast array of
dimensions of development, hence, to avoid distortions we decided to
base our countries' comparisons on period averages, as providing
more objective insights into processes of sustainable development.
Aggregated indexes computed for Lithuania, Latvia, Estonia, for old
European Union (EU-15), and extended European Union (EU-27) countries
for averaged 2004-2008 period, let us draw the following conclusions.
Emphasis on economic development puts Estonia into the first place. It
is followed by Latvia and Lithuania. It is especially peculiar, that
according to received results Estonia in terms of development surpasses
countries of EU-15 and EU-27 blocks during the considered period (Fig.
1).
For the comparison reason, let us glance at dynamics of aggregated
indexes of the Baltic countries during the time period of 2004-2008 and
respective EU-15 and EU-27 ones, in that particular case, they display
different tendencies for change (Fig. 2). Calculations here were
performed by employing statistical data for each considered year. We can
observe, that countries regroup in the year 2008, what confirms our
considerations presented above, i.e. suggestions rely on period data
averages, while emphasizing economic aspects of sustainable development.
In the second modelled situation we assume that institutional
aspects of development are being emphasized. Hence, economic indicators
are being considered as less important in comparison with institutional
ones, when level of sustainable development is estimated. Application of
multi-criteria method provides us with rather similar results: in the
averaged period of 2004-2008 Estonia is the country, which among the
Baltic countries achieved the highest level of development (after EU-27
and EU-15). Lithuania and Latvia according to calculations appear,
respectively, in the second and the third places (Fig. 3). Differently,
compared to the first situation, the European Union countries appear
better developed than Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia. If European context
is taken into consideration, EU-15 countries get into the first place,
EU-27 get into the second, the third place is occupied by Estonia, the
fourth and the fifth by Lithuania and Latvia respectively. Observation
of development dynamics of all considered countries (Fig. 4) provides us
with some additional specific insights.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Comparison of calculations' results based on the averaged
2004-2008 period data versus results on year-toyear data provides us
with similar ranking of countries according to estimated sustainable
development level. That confirms the above presented speculations about
distorting impact of economic downturn on evaluation of sustainable
development and adds ground to application of data averages for
multi-criteria computations, especially, when economic aspects in
estimations prevail.
In the third modelled situation we assume that economic and
institutional aspects of development are being treated as equally
important, and hence, equal significances are attributed to all
indicators included into sustainable development system. Application of
multi-criteria method provides us with rather similar results as in the
modelled second situation, where greater significances are attributed to
institutional indicators. In the averaged period of 2004-2008 Estonia is
the country, which among the Baltic countries achieved the highest level
of development (after EU-15 and EU27). Differently, if to compare with
the second situation, Estonia surpasses EU-27 countries. Lithuania and
Latvia according to calculations appear, respectively, in the second and
the third places (Fig. 5). If European context is taken into
consideration, EU-15 countries get into the first place, EU-27 get into
the third, the second place (third in the second situation) is occupied
by Estonia, the fourth and the fifth by Lithuania and Latvia
respectively. Observation of development dynamics during the period of
2004-2008 of all considered countries (Fig. 6) does not provide any
additional specific insights besides described above. In the year 2008
ranking of countries regroup, obviously, because of the impact of
economic downturn.
Juxtaposed Baltic States' multi-criteria sustainable
development rankings' results obtained using averaged data of the
2004-2008 period are presented in Table 2.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
4. Conclusions
Research has led us to the following generalizations. Despite the
strand of scientific literature is devoted to institutional performance
issues and discusses the impact of institutional development on
sustainable development, there is no general agreement how to perceive
institution itself. We suggest that institutions in a "broad"
and "narrow" sense should be distinguished. Categorization of
institutions let define the object of research and select respective
indicators for reflection of its development dimensions.
Selection of sustainable indicators' system is complicated and
partly subjective. For multi-criteria evaluations indicators'
system has to be sufficiently concise, comprising indicators
quantitatively available. Hence, reflecting of, e.g., institutional
performance requires short cut of other aspects of sustainable
development. Significances, attributed to indicators included into
system, are crucial because, finally, they affect ranging of countries.
Countries' ranking changes when emphasis is switched from economic
indicators' group towards institutional indicators' group.
Attributing higher significances to economic indicators distorts
the concept of sustainable development during the period of economic
downturn.
Modelling of significances of indicator's system suggested
that institutional performance affects sustainable development level.
Switching from emphasis on institutional performance indicators towards
equal treat of all system indicators provided with the same Baltic State countries ranking results, what, in its turn, verifies hypothesis about
high importance of institutional performance for the process of
sustainable development enhancing.
Received 13 January 2009; accepted 3 June 2009
References
Acemoglu, D.; Robinson, J. 2008. The Role of Institutions in Growth
and Development. The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / The World Bank. Working paper No.10. Available from
internet: <http://www.growthcommission.org/storage/cgdev/documents/
gc-wp-010_web.pdf>.
Bruntland, G. 1987. Our Common Future: The World Commission on
Environment and Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 416 p.
Dasgupta, P. 2007. Measuring sustainable development: theory and
application, Asian Development Review 24(1): 1-10. Department of
Statistics to the Government of the Republic of Lithuania. 2007.
Sustainable Development Indicators. Available from Internet:
<http://www.stat.gov.lt/uploads/
docs/Darnus_vystymasis_2006_internetui.pdf>.
Disano, J. 2002. Indicators of Sustainable Development: Guidelines and Methodologies. United Nations Department of Economic and Social
Affairs. Available from Internet:
<http://www.un.org/esa/sustdev/publications/indisdmg2001.pdf>.
Eisner, R. 1988. Extended accounts for national income and product,
Journal of Economic Literature 26: 1611-1684.
Emes, J.; Hahn, T. 2001. Measuring development: an index of human
progress, Public Policy Sources, No 36. Available from Internet:<
http://www.fraserinstitute.org/commerce.web/
product_files/MeasuringDevelopmentIHP.pdf>.
England, R. W. 1998. Measurement of social well-being: alternatives
to Gross Domestic Product, Ecological Economics 25(1): 89-103.
doi:10.1016/S0921-8009(97)00098-0
Ginevicius, R. 2006. Multicriteria evaluation of the criteria
weights by multicriteria methods based on their interrelationships,
Business: Theory and Practice 7(1): 3-13.
Ginevicius, R. 2008. Normalization of quantities of various
dimensions, Journal of Business Economics and Management 9(1): 79-86.
doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2008.9.79-86
Ginevicius, R.; Butkevicius, A.; Podvezko, V. 2006. Complex
evaluation of economic development of the Baltic States and Poland,
Ekonomicky Casopis [Journal of Economics] 54(9): 918-930.
Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V. 2008a. A feasibility study of
multi-criteria methods' application to quantitative evaluation of
social phenomena, Business: Theory and Practice 9(2): 81-87. doi:
10.3846/1648-0627.2008.9.81-87
Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V. 2008b. The problem of compatibility of
various multiple criteria evaluation methods, Business: Theory and
Practice 9(1): 73-80. doi: 10.3846/1648-0627.2008.9.73-80
Glaeser, E. L.; La Porta, R.; Lopez-de-Silane, F.; Shleifer, A.
2004. Do Institutions Cause the Growth. NBER Working Paper No. 10568.
Available from Internet:
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w10568.pdf?new_window=1>.
Grybaite, V.; Tvaronaviciene, M. 2008. Estimation of sustainable
development germination on institutional level, Journal of Business
Economics and Management 9(4): 327-335.
doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2008.9.327-334
Gwartney, J. D.; Holcombew, R. G.; Lawsonz, R. A. 2006.
Institutions and the impact of investment on growth, KYKLOS 59(2):
255-273. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.2006.00327.x
Gwartney, J. D.; Lawson, R. 2003. Economic Freedom of the World:
Annual Report 2003. Vancouver, B.C.: Fraser Institute.
Hamilton, K.; Clemens, M. 1999. Genuine savings rates in developing
countries, World Bank Economic Review 12(2): 333-356.
Hodgson, G. M. 2006. What are institutions? Journal of Economic
Issues 40(1): 1-25. National Strategy for Sustainable Development.
Resolution No 1160 11/09/2003 of Government of the Republic of
Lithuania. Available from Internet:
<http://www.am.lt/VI/en/VI/files/0.901665001073997792.pdf>.
North, D. C. 1991. Institutions, Journal of Economic Perspectives
5(1): 97-112.
North, D. C. 1994. Economic performance through time, The American
Economic Review 84(3): 359-368.
Redek, T.; Susjan, A. 2005. The impact of institutions on economic
growth: the case of transition economies, Journal of Economic Issues
34(4): 995-1027.
Robinson, J. 2004. Squaring the circle? Some thoughts on the idea
of sustainable development, Ecological Economics 48: 369-384.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2003.10.017
Rodrik, D. 2000. Institutions for High Quality Growth: What They
Are and How to Acquire Them. NBER working paper No. 7540.
Statistical Office of the European Communities. EU member state
experiences with sustainable development indicators. Luxembourg: Office
for Official Publications of the European Communities, 2004. Available
from Internet: <http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_OFFPUB/KS-AU-04-001/EN/ KS-AU-04-001-EN.PDF>.
Summers, R.; Heston, A. 1991. The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An
expanded set of international comparisons, 1950-1988, Quarterly Journal
of Economics 103(2): 327-268. doi:10.2307/2937941
The World Bank Group 2007. Available from Internet:
<http://www.worldbank.org/depweb/english/beyond/global/chapter15.html>.
Turskis, Z.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Peldschus, F. 2009. Multicriteria
optimization system for decision making in construction design and
management, Inzinerine ekonomika--Engineering Economics 1(61): 7-17.
Ulubasoglu, M. A.; Doucouliagos, Ch. 2004. Institutions and
Economic Growth: A Systems Approach. Available from Internet:
<http://repec.org/esAUSM04/up.29323.1076501864.pdf>.
United Nations, Commission on Sustainable Development. 2007. Theme
Indicator Framework. Available from Internet:
<http://www.un.org/esa/sustdev/natlinfo/indicators/isdms2001/table_4.htm>.
Zavadskas, E. K. 2008. Beginning a new stage of development,
Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(3): 241-243. doi:
10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.241-243
Zavadskas, E. K.; Zakarevicius, A.; Antucheviciene, J. 2006.
Evaluation of ranking accuracy in multicriteria decisions, Informatica
17(4): 601-618.
Zavadskas, E. K.; Turskis, Z.; Tamosaitiene, J.; Marina, V. 2008.
Multicriteria selection of project managers by applying grey criteria,
Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(4): 462-477.
doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.462-477
DOI: 10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.
Manuela Tvaronaviciene (1), Virginija Grybaite (2), Agne
Tvaronaviciene (3)
Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223
Vilnius, Lithuania E-mails: (1) manuela@vv.vgtu.lt; (2)
virgi@vv.vgtu.lt; a.tvaronaviciene@post.lt
Table 1. Indicators' set characterizing sustainable development with
emphasis on institutional facets
Economic Institutional
GDP--current prices Rule of Law;
(euro per inhabitant);
Real GDP growth rate, percentage GDP on R&D, per cent of GDP;
of change
over previous year; Government effectiveness index;
Annual average inflation rate; Level of Internet access;
Business investment, per cent Level of citizens' confidence
of GDP;
High-tech exports, as a share of in EU institutions, in per cent;
total exports;
Growth rate of labour Index of Economic Freedom;
productivity per hour worked,
percentage of change over Corruption perception index;
previous year;
General government debt; E-government online availability,
in per cent;
FDI intensity; Voter turnout in national and
EU parliamentary
Inequality of income distribution; elections, in per cent
Unemployment rate, in per cent
Table 2. Ranking of Baltic countries according to multi-criteria
evaluation variants
Ranking according to
multi-criteria evaluations ESTONIA LITHUANIA LATVIA
1 situation 1 3 2
(economic development
aspect emphasized)
2 situation 1 2 3
(institutional development
aspect emphasized)
3 situation 1 2 3
(economic and institutional aspects
are considered as equally important)
Average 1 2 3
Place