Regression methods for hesitant fuzzy preference relations.
Zhu, Bin ; Xu, Zeshui
JEL Classification: C81; D7; D8.
Introduction
Fuzzy preference relations (FPRs) are widely used in decision
making, where consistency of FPRs is a major goal and interesting
research topic (Herrera-Viedma et al. 2004, 2007; Jiang, Fan 2008;
Tanino 1984, 1988; Wu et al. 2012; Wei et al. 2012; Stankeviciene,
Mencaite 2012; Balezentis et al. 2012). Recently, hesitant fuzzy sets
(HFSs), originally introduced by Torra (2010), become a hot topic (Zhu
et al. 2012a, b, 2013; Xu, Xia 2011). HFSs can consider the degrees of
membership by a set of possible values. The motivation to propose HFSs
is that when defining the membership of an element, the difficulty of
establishing the membership degree is not a margin of error (as in
intuitionistic fuzzy sets; Atanassov 1986), or some possibility
distributions on the possible values (as in type 2 fuzzy sets; Zadeh
1975), but a set of possible values (Torra 2010).
With respect to the preference relations of HFSs, Xia and Xu (2013)
defined hesitant fuzzy preference relations (HFPRs) and developed an
approach to apply HFPRs to decision making. However, as a basic issue of
HFPRs, the studies on consistency of HFPRs is not easy because the
numbers of possible values in different hesitant fuzzy elements (HFEs)
are often different. Since FPRs have been proven to be an effective tool
used in decision making problems (Chiclana et al. 2001; Orlovsky 1978;
Tanino 1984), we consider some techniques to transform HFPRs into FPRs
based on their close relationship. Two regression methods are developed
for the transformations based on the complete consistency and the weak
consistency respectively.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 1 reviews
some basic knowledge. In Section 2, we develop the regression methods,
and illustrate their advantages with some examples. The final section
ends the paper with some conclusions.
1. Preliminaries
This section introduces some concepts related to hesitant fuzzy
sets (HFSs), fuzzy preference relations (FPRs), and hesitant fuzzy
preference relations (HFPRs).
1.1. Hesitant fuzzy preference relations
Torra (2010) originally developed HFSs which cover arguments with a
set of possible values.
Definition 1 (Torra 2010). Let X be a fixed set, a hesitant fuzzy
set (HFS) on X is in terms of a function that when applied to X returns
a subset of [0,1].
To be easily understood, Xia and Xu (2011) expressed the HFS by a
mathematical symbol:
E = {< x, h(x) >| x [member of] X}, (1)
where h(x) is a set of some values in [0,1], denoting the possible
membership degrees of the element x e X to the set E. For convenience,
Xia and Xu (2011) called h a hesitant fuzzy element (HFE).
For a HFE h , Xia and Xu (2011) developed some operations as
follows:
1) [h.sup.[lambda]] = [[union].sub.[gamma][member of]h]
{[[gamma].sup.[lambda]}, [lambda] x > 0;
2) [lambda]h = [[union].sub.gamma.][member of]h] {1 - [(i -
[gamma]).sup.[lambda]]}, [lambda] 0.
FPRs (Orlovsky 1978) are an effective tool in decision making. The
definition is as follows.
Definition 2 (Orlovsky 1978). A fuzzy preference relation (FPR) P
on a set of objectives, X, is a fuzzy set on the product set X x X, that
is characterized by a membership function [[mu].sub.p]: X x X [right
arrow] [0,1].
When the cardinality of X is small, the fuzzy preference relation
may be conveniently represented by a n x n matrix P =
[([p.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], where [p.sub.ij] = [[mu].sub.p]([x.sub.i],
[x.sub.j]). [p.sub.ij] is interpreted as the preference degree of the
objective [x.sub.i] over [x.sub.j]: [p.sub.ij] = 0.5 indicates
indifference between [x.sub.i] and [x.sub.j], which can be represented
by [x.sub.i] ~ [x.sub.j]; [p.sub.ij] = 1 indicates that [x.sub.i] is
absolutely preferred [x.sub.j]; [p.sub.ij] > 0.5 indicates that
[x.sub.i] is preferred to [x.sub.j], which can be represented by
[x.sub.i] [??] [x.sub.j]. Generally, P is assumed to be additive
reciprocal: [p.sub.ij] + [p.sub.ij] = 1, i, j = 1, 2, ..., n.
On the basis of FPRs, Xia and Xu (2013) developed HFPRs which can
be restated as follows.
Definition 3. Let X = {[x.sub.1], [x.sub.2], ..., [x.sub.n]} be a
fixed set, then a hesitant fuzzy preference relation (HFPR) H on X is
presented by a matrix H = [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] [subset] X x X, where
[h.sub.ij] = {[[gamma].sup.l.sub.ij]|l = 1, ..., #[h.sub.ij]}
(#[h.sub.ij] is the number of values in [h.sub.ij]) is a HFE indicating
all the possible preference degree(s) of the objective [x.sub.i] over
[x.sub.j]. Moreover, [h.sub.ij] should satisfy the following conditions:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
where: [[gamma].sup.[sigma](l).sub.ij] is the lth largest element
in [h.sub.ij].
1.2. Consistency measures
The transitivity property is used to represent the idea that the
preference degree obtained by directly comparing two objectives should
be equal to or greater than the preference degree between those two
objectives obtained using an indirect chain of objectives. This property
is desirable to avoid contradictions reflected in preference relations.
For the FPR P = [([p.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], Tanino (1984) introduced an
additive fuzzy transitivity property, or called the complete
consistency:
[p.sub.ij] + [p.sub.jk] = [p.sub.ik] + 0.5. (3)
Tanino (1988) also introduced an additive fuzzy weak transitivity,
or called the weak consistency: [p.sub.ij] [greater than or equal to]
0.5, [p.sub.jk] [greater than or equal to] 0.5 [right arrow] [p.sub.ik]
[greater than or equal to] 0.5, i, j,k = 1, ..., n. It means that if
[x.sub.i] is preferred to [x.sub.j] and [x.sub.j] is preferred to
[x.sub.k], then [x.sub.i] should be preferred to [x.sub.k]. This
property verifies the condition that a logical and consistent person
does not want to express his/her opinions with inconsistency, which
guarantee the minimum requirement for consistency.
2. Regression methods for HFPRs
In this section, we develop two regression methods for HFPRs, which
depend on the complete consistency and the weak consistency
respectively.
2.1. A regression method for HFPRs based on the complete
consistency
Herrera-Viedma et al. (2007) developed a method with error analysis
to measure the consistency levels of FPRs. Motivated by this method, and
based on the complete consistency and error analysis, we develop a
regression method to transform HFPRs into FPRs.
Given a HFPR, represented by a matrix H = [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn]
[subset] X x X, where X = {[x.sub.1], [x.sub.2], ..., [x.sub.n]} is a
fixed set of objectives. According to the definition of the complete
consistency, the possible preference degrees over the paired objectives
(i,k) represented by a HFE [h.sub.jk] (i [not equal to] k) can be
estimated using an intermediate objective [x.sub.j] (j [not equal to] i,
k):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
where: [h.sup.j.sub.jk] can be called an estimated HFE, and the
operations "[??]" and "[??]" are efined as follows.
Definition 4. Let h , [h.sub.1] and [h.sub.2] be three HFEs, and a
be a real number, then we define
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
In order to use Eq. (4) to estimate [h.sup.j.sub.jk], the
objectives [x.sub.i] (i = 1,2,n) should generally be classified into
several sets defined as follows:
B = {(i, k)|i, k [member of] {1, 2, ...,n} [and] (i [not equal]
k)}; (7)
O[V.sup.B] = {(i, k) [member of] B}; (8)
K[V.sup.B] = [(O[Vsup.B])sup.c]; (9)
[M.sup.j.sub.ik] = {j [not equal] i, k|(i, j), (j, k) [member of]
K[V.sup.B]}, (10)
where: B is a set of all paired objectives; O[Vsup.B] is a set of
paired objectives (i, k); K[V.sup.B] is the complement set of O[V.sup.B]
satisfying K[V.sup.B] [union] O[V.sup.B] = B; [M.sup.j.sub.jk] is the
set of the intermediate objectives [x.sub.j](j [not equal to] i, k).
Based on the discussions above and according to Eq.(4), we can get
all the estimated HFE [h.sup.j.sub.ik (j = 1,2, ...n; j [not equal] i,
k). To select the optimal preference degree from [h.sup.j.sub.ik] (j =
1, 2, ...n; j [not equal] i, k), we calculate an average estimated
preference degree defined as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (11)
where: [S.sub.s] is a function that indicates the summation of all
elements in a set; #[h.sup.j.sub.ik] indicates the numbers of possible
preference degrees in [h.sup.j.sub.ik].
Comparing the possible values in the HFE [h.sub.ik] and its average
estimated preference degree [h.sup.A.sub.ik], we define the error
between them as follows.
Definition 5. For the HFE [h.sub.ik] and its average estimated
preference degree [h.sup.A.sub.ik], the error between them is defined
as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (12)
where: the coefficient 2/3 is used to make sure each value of the
error belongs to the unit interval [0,1].
If there exists a preference degree [h.sup.*.sub.ik]
([h.sup.*.sub.ik] [member of] [h.sub.ik]) that corresponds to the
minimum value of the error [epsilon][h.sub.ik] satisfying:
2/3 ([h.sup.*.sub.ik] - [h.sup.A.sub.ik]) = min
([epsilon][h.sub.ik]), (13)
then we should choose this preference degree as the optimal one.
Following this principle and collecting [h.sup.*.sub.ik] for all i, k =
1, 2, ...n; i [not equal] k, we can transform H into a FPR [H.sup.*] =
[([h.sup.*.sub.ik]).sub.nxn], which can be called a reduced FPR.
Further to measure the consistency level of [H.sup.*], we now give
some definitions.
Definition 6. For the reduced FPR [H.sup.*] =
[([h.sup.*.sub.ik]).sub.nxn], the consistency level of [h.sup.*.sub.ik]
is defined as:
c[l.sub.ik] = 1 - min([epsilon][h.sub.ik]). (14)
With respect to one objective xi, the consistency level is defined
as follows.
Definition 7. For [H.sup.*] = [([h.sup.*.sub.ik]).sub.nxn], the
consistency level of the objective xi is defined as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (15)
So the consistency level of [H.sup.*] can be further defined with
respect to all the objectives.
Definition 8. For [H.sup.*] = [([h.sup.*.sub.ik]).sub.nxn], its
consistency level is defined as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (16)
Clearly, the bigger the value of [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] [member of][0,1]), the higher the consistency level of [H.sup.*].
Based on the analysis above, for a fixed set X = {[x.sub.1], [x.sub.2],
..., [x.sub.n]}, and a constructed HFPR H = [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], the
algorithm that transforms H into [H.sup.*] is shown in Algorithm I.
Algorithm I
Step 1. Randomly locate a HFE [h.sub.ik](i [not equal] k),then
calculate [h.sup.j.sub.ik(j = 1, 2, ...n; j [not equal] i, k) according
to Eq. (4).
Step 2. Calculate the average estimated preference degree
[h.sup.A.sub.ik] by Eq. (11), and then obtain [h.sup.*.sub.ik by Eqs.
(12) and (13).
Step 3. Repeat Steps 1 and 2 until all HFEs have been located, then
turn to the next Step.
Step 4. Collecting [h.sup.*.sub.ik] for all i, k = 1, 2, ...n (i
[equal to] k), we can get the reduced FPR [H.sup.*] =
[([h.sup.*.sub.ik]).sub.nxn].
Step 5. Calculate the consistency level of [H.sup.*] according to
Eqs. (14), (15) and (16).
Step 6. End.
Example 1. Assume a HFPR as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Step 1. Locate the HFE [h.sub.12], and according to Eq. (4), we
have:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Step 2. According to Eq. (11), we have:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Thus, [h.sup.*.sub.12] = 0.5.
Step 3. Repeat Steps 1 and 2, we have:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Step 4. Collecting [h.sup.*.sub.ik] for all i, k = 1, 2, ...n (i
[not equal] k), we can get the reduced FPR [H.sup.*.sub.1] as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Step 5. According to Eq. (14), we have:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
According to Eq. (15), we can get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Furthermore, by Eq. (16), the consistency level of [H.sup.*.sub.1]
is:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Step 6. End.
For the HFPR H = [([h.sub.j]).sub.nxn], since each preference
degree in [h.sub.ij] is a possible value, H can be directly separated
into all possible FPRs. Then based on some existing consistency measure
methods, the FPR with the highest consistency level can be found out. In
order to compare this straightforward method with our method, we give
the following example.
Example 2. Based on the same HFPR [H.sub.1], we can generate eight
possible FPRs from [H.sub.1] denoted as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
According to the consistency measure of FPRs introduced by
Herrera-Viedma et al. (2007), we can get the consistency levels of
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (i = 1, 2, ..., 8)
denoted by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Since:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is with the
highest consistency level.
Obviously, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. So
the results are the same by the regression method and the
straightforward method. Considering the efficiency, the number of
operations of our regression method and the straightforward method are
2n(n - 1) + n +1 and m(n(n - 1) + n + 1) (m is the number of all
possible FPRs separated from a HFPR), respectively. Since m [greater
than or equal to] 2 (at least two FPRs can be separated from a HFPR), we
have m(n(n - 1) + n + 1) > 2n(n - 1) + n + 1. So our method is
simpler. Moreover, the bigger the value m, the simpler the regression
method.
2.2. A regression method for HFPRs based on the weak consistency
For the decision making problems in practical applications, the
complete consistency is sometimes not necessary due to the complicated
environment and the cognitive diversity of humans. But, the weak
consistency is essential because a contradictory HFPR doesn't make
sense. On the basis of the weak consistency, we now develop another
regression method to get reduced FPRs satisfying the weak consistency.
In what follows, we begin with some necessary definitions and
discussions.
Definition 9. Assume a HFPR, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], its hesitant preference degree (HPD) is defined
as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (17)
where: [s.sub.ij] is called a hesitant preference element (HPE),
satisfying:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (18)
Then M = [([m.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] is called a hesitant preference
relation (HPR).
According to graph theory (Bondy, Murty 1976), the relationship
included in the HPR can be described by a directed graph which can be
called a hesitant fuzzy preference graph. In such a graph, each node
stands for an objective, and each directed edge stands for a preference
relation. If [m.sub.ij] = 1, then there is a directed edge from a node i
to a node j, which represents that the objective i is superior to the
objective j.
Example 3. Assume a fixed set X = {[x.sub.1], [x.sub.2],
[x.sub.3],[x.sub.4]}, and two constructed HFPRs as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
According to Definition 9, we get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The hesitant fuzzy preference graphs of [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] are shown in Figures 1 and 2 respectively.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
With respect to a HFPR, if there is no circular triad in a hesitant
fuzzy preference graph, it means that a circular relation of objectives
does not exist. So the HFPR satisfies the weak consistency, such as in
Fig. 1. However, in Fig. 2, we can see that the objectives [x.sub.1] and
[x.sub.4] are connected by two opposite directed edges. In such a case,
we can get a circular triad of objectives as [x.sub.1] [right arrow]
[x.sub.4] [right arrow] [x.sub.2] [right arrow] [x.sub.1] in Fig. 2.
Thus the corresponding HFPR, H3, does not satisfy the weak consistency.
Therefore, the circular triad can be used to test the weak consistency
of HFPRs, which is defined as follows.
Definition 10. Let M = [([m.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] be the HPR of a HFPR
H = [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], where [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], then:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (19)
is called a circular triad power, and [c.sub.ijk] is called a
circular triad power element.
Theorem 1. For a HFPR, H = (hj)nxn, we can get its HPR M =
(mij)nxn, and the circular triad power Cjk = Uc eC {cijk}. If and only
if there exists cijk = 3, then H does not satisfy the weak co nsistency.
Proof. If [c.sub.ijk] = 3 exists, then there exists one circular
triad indicating a relation of objectives as [x.sub.i] [??] [x.sub.j]
[??] [x.sub.k] [??] [x.sub.i]. According to the definition of the weak
consistency, H does not satisfy the weak consistency; if H does not
satisfy the weak consistency, then there exists a circular triad of
objectives as [x.sub.i] [right arrow] [x.sub.j] [right arrow] [x.sub.k]
[??] [x.sub.i]. According to Definition 10, there exists [c.sub.ijk] =
3, which complete the proof.
Jiang and Fan (2008) gave a definition of a reachability matrix
used to test the weak consistency of FPRs. Motivated by this idea, and
based on Theorem 1, we now develop a hesitant reachability matrix (HRM)
to identify the weak consistency of HFPRs.
Definition 11. Let M = [([m.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] be the HPR of a HFPR
H = [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] , then we call [M.sup.(k)] =
[([m.sup.(k).sub.ij]).sub.nxn] the kth power of M, where the (i, j)
entry, denoted by [m.sup.(k).sub.ij], is the number of different
directed edges of the length k from the node i to the node j.
Furthermore, we define the HRM as follows.
Definition 12. Let M = [([m.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] be the HPR of a HFPR
H = [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], [Msup.(3)] = [([m.sup.(3).sub.ij]).sub.nxn]
be the third power of M, then we call the matrix R =
[([r.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] the hesitant reachability matrix (HRM), where R =
[Msup.(3)].
Theorem 2. For a HFPR, H = [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] , if all diagonal
elements are zero in its hesitant reachability matrix R =
[([r.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], then H satisfies the weak consistency.
Proof. For the HFPR, H= [([h.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], if all the diagonal
elements are zero in its hesitant reachability matrix R =
[([r.sub.ij]).sub.nxn], i.e. [M.sup.(3)] =
[([m.sup.(3).sub.ii]).sup.nxn] = 0, then according to Theorem 1, we
know that there is no circular triad in H. So H satisfies the weak
consistency, which completes the proof.
According to Definition 12, and based on the two HFPRs [H.sub.2]
and [H.sub.3] in Example 3, we can get two HRMs as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
According to Theorem 2, [H.sub.2] satisfies the weak consistency,
but [H.sub.3] does not.
Based on the discussions above, we now give a step by step
procedure to obtain reduced FPRs satisfying the weak consistency shown
in Algorithm [PI].
Algorithm [PI]
Given a HFPR, [H.sup.p] = [([h.sup.p.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] (p = 0 ;
[H.sup.p] is the p th power of H indicating the number of being
modified).
Step 1. According to Definitions 9 and 12, we can get its HPR
[M.sup.p] = [([m.sub.jj]).sub.nxn] and HRM [R.sup.p] =
[([r.sub.ij]).sub.nxn] respectively.
Step 2. According to Theorem 2, if [H.sup.p] satisfies the weak
consistency, turn to Step 5; otherwise, turn to Step 3.
Step 3. For the HPR [M.sup.p] = ([m.sub.jj]), where [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], locate a pair of HPDs
([m.sub.ij], [m.sub.ji]), satisfying [m.sub.ij] = {0, 1}, [m.sub.ij] =
{1,0}.
According to Eq. (19), find out a [c.sub.ijk] = 3, remove the pair
of HPEs ([s.sub.jj], [s.sub.ji]) satisfying [s.sub.ij] + [s.sub.ji] = 1,
and remove their corresponding preference degrees in the pair of HFEs
([h.sub.ij], [h.sub.ji]) in H.
Step 4. Let p = p +1, construct a modified HFPR as [H.sup.p + 1],
turn to Step 1.
Step 5. Divide [H.sup.p] into all possible reduced FPRs.
Step 6. End.
Example 4. Continued with [H.sub.3] in Example 3, let [H.sub.3] be
[H.sup.p.sub.3](p = 0). Since Hp does not satisfy the weak consistency,
we turn to Step 3.
Step 3. Locate ([m.sub.14],[m.sub.41]), satisfying [m.sub.14] = {0,
1} and [m.sub.41] = {1, 0}. According to Eq. (19), we can find
[c.sub.142] = 3. Remove the pair of HPEs [s.sub.14] = {0} and [s.sub.41]
= {1}, and remove their corresponding preference degrees
[[gamma].sub.14] = 0.4, [[gamma].sub.41] = 0.6 in the pair of HFEs
([h.sub.14], [h.sub.41]).
Step 4. Let p = p +1, construct a modified HFPR [H.sup.1.sub.3] as
follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Then turn to Step 1.
Step 1. According to Definitions 9 and 12, and the modified HHPR
[H.sup.1.sub.3], we can get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Step 2. According to Theorem 2, [H.sup.1.sub.3] satisfies the weak
consistency, turn to Step 5. Step 5. Divide [H.sup.1.sub.3] into the
following possible reduced FPRs satisfying the weak consistency:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Step 6. End.
In practical applications, Algorithms I and n can be combined to
obtain reduced FPRs from HFPRs, where the obtained reduced FPR can not
only satisfy the weak consistency but also have the highest confidence
level.
For example, we replace Step 5 in Example 4 by Algorithm I. Then we
can obtain a reduced FPR, denoted by [H.sup.*.sub.2], with the highest
consistency level 95.56% :
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Conclusions
For a hesitant fuzzy preference relation (HFPR), it is not easy to
deal with its consistency due to different numbers of possible values in
hesitant fuzzy elements (HFEs). In this paper, we have developed two
regression methods to transform HFPRs into reduced fuzzy preference
relations (FPRs). Based on the complete consistency, we use error
analysis to select the optimal preference degree for each paired
objectives in HFPRs to produce reduced FPRs. The step by step procedure
of this regression method is shown in Algorithm I. On the basis of the
weak consistency, we have defined a hesitant preference relation (HPR)
and a circular triad power to find circular triads of objectives in
HFPRs. Then we have given Theorems 1 and 2 to identify the weak
consistency of HFPRs. With these definitions and methods, we have given
Algorithm n to transform HFPRs into FPRs that satisfy the weak
consistency.
doi: 10.3846/20294913.2014.881430
Caption: Fig. 1. Hesitant fuzzy preference graph of [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Caption: Fig. 2. Hesitant fuzzy preference graph of [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees for their
insightful and constructive comments and suggestions that have led to an
improved version of this paper. The work was supported by the National
Natural Science Foundation of China (No.61273209), the Fundamental
Research Funds for the Central Universities (No. CXZZ12_0132), the
excellent PhD thesis Foundation of Southeast University, and the Best
New PhD Foundation of China.
References
Atanassov, K. 1986. Intuitionistic fuzzy sets, Fuzzy Sets and
Systems 20(1): 87-96. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0165-0114(86)80034-3
Balezentis, A.; Balezentis, T.; Misiunas, A. 2012. An integrated
assessment of Lithuanian economic sectors based on financial ratios and
fuzzy MCDM methods, Technological and Economic Development of Economy
18(1): 34-53. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/20294913.2012.656151
Bondy, J. A.; Murty, U. S. R. 1976. Graph theory with applications.
The Macmillan Press Ltd., Great Britain. 270 p.
Chiclana, F.; Herrera, F.; Herrera-Viedma, E. 2001. Integrating
multiplicative preference relations in a multipurpose decision-making
model based on fuzzy preference relations, Fuzzy Sets and Systems
122(2): 277-291. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0165-0114(00)00004-X
Herrera-Viedma, E.; Alonso, S.; Chiclana, F.; Herrera, F. 2007. A
consensus model for group decision making with incomplete fuzzy
preference relations, IEEE Transactions on Fuzzy Systems 15(5): 863-877.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/TFUZZ.2006.889952
Herrera-Viedma, E.; Herrera, F.; Chiclana, F.; Luque, M. 2004. Some
issues on consistency of fuzzy preference relations, European Journal of
Operational Research 154(1): 98-109.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0377-2217(02)00725-7
Jiang, Y. P.; Fan, Z. P. 2008. Judgment matrix: theory and methods.
Beijing: Science Press.
Orlovsky, S. A. 1978. Decision-making with a fuzzy preference
relation, Fuzzy Sets and Systems 1(3): 155-167.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(78)90001-5
Stankeviciene, J.; Mencaite, E. 2012. The evaluation of bank
performance using a multicriteria decision making model: a case study on
Lithuanian commercial banks, Technological and Economic Development of
Economy 18(1): 189-205. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/20294913.2012.668373
Tanino, T. 1984. Fuzzy preference orderings in group decision
making, Fuzzy Sets and Systems 12(2): 117-131.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-0114(84)90032-0
Tanino, T. 1988. Fuzzy preference relations in group decision
making, in Kacprzyk, J.; Roubens, M. (Eds.). Non-Conventional Preference
Relations in Decision Making 1988. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 54-71.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-51711-2_4
Torra, V. 2010. Hesitant fuzzy sets, International Journal of
Intelligent Systems 25(6): 529-539.
Wei, G. W.; Zhao, X. F.; Wang, H. J. 2012. An approach to multiple
attribute group decision making with interval intuitionistic trapezoidal
fuzzy information, Technological and Economic Development of Economy
18(2): 317-330. http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/20294913.2012.676995
Wu, W. S.; Kou, G.; Peng, Y.; Ergu, D. J. 2012. Improved AHP-group
decision making for investment strategy selection, Technological and
Economic Development of Economy 18(2): 299-316.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/20294913.2012.680520
Xia, M. M.; Xu, Z. S. 2011. Hesitant fuzzy information aggregation
in decision making, International Journal of Approximate Reasoning
52(3): 395-407. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijar.2010.09.002
Xia, M. M.; Xu, Z. S. 2013. Managing hesitant information in GDM
problems under fuzzy and multiplicative preference relations,
International Journal of Uncertainty, Fuzziness and Knowledge-Based
Systems 21(6): 865. http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/S0218488513500402
Xu, Z. S.; Xia, M. M. 2011. Distance and similarity measures for
hesitant fuzzy sets, Information Sciences 181(11): 2128-2138.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ins.2011.01.028
Zadeh, L. A. 1975. The concept of a linguistic variable and its
application to approximate reasoning, Part I, Information Sciences 8(3):
199-249. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0020-0255(75)90036-5
Zhu, B.; Xu, Z. S.; Xia, M. M. 2012a. Hesitant fuzzy geometric
Bonferroni means, Information Sciences 205(1): 72-85.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ins.2012.01.048
Zhu, B.; Xu, Z. S.; Xia, M. M. 2012b. Dual hesitant fuzzy sets,
Journal of Applied Mathematics 2012: 1-13.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2012/879629
Zhu, B.; Xu, Z. S.; Xu. J. P. 2013. Deriving a ranking from
hesitant fuzzy preference relations under group decision making, IEEE
Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, PartB: Cybernetics
PP(99): 1. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/TCYB.2013.2283021
Bin ZHU received the Bachelor's degree from Southeast
University, China, in 2008. He is currently working toward the PhD
degree with the School of Economics and Management, Southeast
University. His research results have been published in Fuzzy Sets and
Systems, Information Sciences, IEEE Transactions on Fuzzy Systems, IEEE
Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, Part B: Cybernetics,
Journal of the Operational Research Society, Knowledge-Based Systems
among others. His research interests include decision analysis, decision
support, information fusion, and computing with words.
Zeshui XU received the PhD degree in Management Science and
Engineering from Southeast University, Nanjing, China, in 2003. From
April 2003 to May 2005, he was a Postdoctoral Researcher with School of
Economics and Management, Southeast University. From October 2005 to
December 2007, he was a Postdoctoral Researcher with School of Economics
and Management, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China. He is a
Distinguished Young Scholar of the National Natural Science Foundation
of China, and a Distinguished Professor of the Chang Jiang Scholars
Program of the Ministry of Education of China. He is with the Business
School, Sichuan University, Chengdu, China. He has authored seven
monographs and contributed more than 350 journal articles to
professional journals. He is currently the Associate Editor of Fuzzy
Optimization and Decision Making, Journal of Intelligence Systems, and
also a member of Editorial Boards of seventeen professional journals.
His current research interests include information fusion, group
decision making, computing with words, and aggregation operators.
Bin ZHU (a), Zeshui XU (b)
(a) School of Economics and Management, Southeast University,
Nanjing, 211189 Jiangsu, China
(b) Business School, Sichuan University, Chengdu, 610064 Sichuan,
China
Received 20 May 2012; accepted 18 November 2012
Corresponding author Bin Zhu
E-mail: binzhu@263.net