首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月29日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Dependence of multi-criteria evaluation result on choice of preference functions and their paramaters/Daugiakriteriniu vertinimu rezultatu priklausomybe nuo prioritetu funkciju ir ju parametru pasirinkimo.
  • 作者:Podvezko, Valentinas ; Podviezko, Askoldas
  • 期刊名称:Technological and Economic Development of Economy
  • 印刷版ISSN:1392-8619
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Vilnius Gediminas Technical University
  • 摘要:Reality often raises the task of evaluation of several possible alternatives and outlining them in the order of preference. Such task could be selection of the best alternative among investment projects, evaluation of different regions of a country or rate of development of different countries, etc.
  • 关键词:Multiple criteria decision making;Nonlinear functional analysis

Dependence of multi-criteria evaluation result on choice of preference functions and their paramaters/Daugiakriteriniu vertinimu rezultatu priklausomybe nuo prioritetu funkciju ir ju parametru pasirinkimo.


Podvezko, Valentinas ; Podviezko, Askoldas


1. Introduction

Reality often raises the task of evaluation of several possible alternatives and outlining them in the order of preference. Such task could be selection of the best alternative among investment projects, evaluation of different regions of a country or rate of development of different countries, etc.

A considerable usage increase of multi-criteria methods is recently observed in quantitative analysis of social or economical phenomena or other complex processes (Brauers, Zavadskas 2006; Brauers et al. 2007; Figueira et al. 2005; Hui et al. 2009; Maskeliunaite et al. 2009; Plebankiewicz 2009; Podvezko 2009; Turskis et al. 2009; Ulubeyli, Kazaz 2009; Ustinovichius et al. 2007; Zavadskas, Antucheviciene 2006; Zavadskas et al. 2008a, b, 2009).

The range of the PROMETHEE (Preference Ranking Organisation Method for Enrichment Evaluation) group of methods is wide: from the PROMETHEE I method indicating the best alternative among the ones in question, the PROMETHEE II (full classification method), which is ranging alternatives in respect of desired objectives, up to the PROMETHEE VI method, which yields an indication if the problem is hard or soft, and the visual model GAIA (Brans, Mareschal 1992, 1994, 1996, 2005).

The PROMETHEE methods are well-known and are often being used. Bibliography comprises hundreds of publications (Brans, Mareschal 2005; Behzadian et al. 2010). PROMETHEE methods were used in many different areas, from logistics to health service (Behzadian et al. 2010; Brans, Mareschal 2005). Lithuania is at the initial stage of using the methods (Nowak 2005; Podvezko, Podviezko 2009).

PROMETHEE methods comprise criteria values of chosen indices and their weights in more sophisticated way by using preference functions with few parameters. Preference function shapes and their parameters are chosen by responsible persons of the evaluation, decision-makers or qualified experts. In addition to already existing, new types of preference functions were proposed in this paper, with intention of widening the range of choice for decision-makers and evaluation experts.

The goal of this paper is to extend and deepen study of this method, to describe the algorithm of the PROMETHEE II method, to apply this method to obtain outranking relationship of alternatives, to add some knacks to this method, to broaden the scope of users and to demonstrate dependence of results of evaluation on the choice of shapes of preference functions and their parameters.

2. The brief description of the algorithm of the PROMETHEE methods

We will briefly recall the algorithm of the PROMETHEE methods (Brans, Mareschal 2005; Podvezko, Podviezko 2009). The core of this method is the same as in other multi-criteria methods. The method uses criteria value matrix of statistical data or experts' assessment data R [paralllel][r.sub.ij][parallel] = characterising objects being evaluated and weights of criteria [m.summation over (i=1)] [[omega].sub.i], i = 1, 2, ..., m; j = 1, 2, ..., n, where m is the number of criteria, n is the number of evaluated objects or alternatives. Every criterion must be defined to be maximising or minimising. Maximum values of maximising criteria are considered to be the best as minimum values of minimising criteria. Multi-criteria methods usually use normalised criteria values [[??].sub.ij] and weights [[omega].sub.i]. A good example is SAW (Simple Additive Weighting) method, which suggests formula for calculation criteria of evaluation (Hwang, Yoon 1981; Ginevicius, Podvezko 2008a, b, c, 2009; Ginevicius et al. 2008a, b; Jakimavicius, Burinskiene 2009):

PROMETHEE methods use values od so-called preference functions p(d) instead of normalised values of criteria [[??].sub.ij].

The range of values of preference functions falls between zero and one. Values of the functions reveal the level of preference of one alternative over another. Shapes of functions depend on boundary parameters q and s, which are chosen by a decision-maker for each criterion i, namely [q.sub.i] for the lower and si for the upper boundary of the argument thus making two alternatives [A.sub.j] and [A.sub.k] indifferent in respect of the criteria [R.sub.i] when the difference between values of criteria [r.sub.ij] and [r.sub.ik] for these alternatives [d.sub.i]([A.sub.j],[A.sub.k]) = [r.sub.ij]--[r.sub.ik] is smaller than the boundary parameter [q.sub.i] and thus making the alternative [A.sub.j] of the strict preference in favour of the alternative [A.sub.k] when the difference between criteria values [r.sub.ij] and [r.sub.ik] for these alternatives [d.sub.i]([A.sub.j],[A.sub.k]) = [r.sub.ij]--[r.sub.ik] is greater than the boundary parameter [s.sub.i]. When the difference falls between [q.sub.i] and [s.sub.i] preference criterion of the alternative [A.sub.j] in respect of the alternative [A.sub.k] varies between zero and one.

PROMETHEE methods suggest the following formula for calculation the aggregated preference index [pi]([A.sub.j],[A.sub.k]) of the alternative [A.sub.j] in respect of the alternative [A.sub.k]:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] (2)

where [[omega].sub.i] is the weight of the i-th criterion [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] is the difference between values [r.sub.ij] and [r.sub.ik] of the criterion [R.sub.i] for the alternatives [A.sub.j] and [A.sub.k]; [p.sub.t](d) = [p.sub.t]([d.sub.i]([A.sub.j], [A.sub.k])) is the t-th preference function chosen by a decision-maker for the i-th criterion from the set of available preference functions.

The PROMETHEE method adds all positive preference indices and thus the positive outranking flow is obtained

[F.sup.+.sub.j] = [n.summation over (k+1)] ([A.sub.j], [A.sub.K] (j = 1,2, ..., n (3)

and all negative preference indices to have the negative outranking flow

[F.sup.-.sub.j] = [n.summation over (k+1)] ([A.sub.k], [A.sub.j] (j = 1,2, ..., n (3)

The PROMETHEE I method reveals mutual outranking relationship between alternatives [A.sub.j] and [A.sub.k] by summing all "outgoing" and "incoming" outranking indices with respective positive or negative sign. Possible outcomes are denoted as [P.sup.+], [P.sup.-], [I.sup.+], [I.sup.-] (Brans, Mareschal 2005; Podvezko, Podviezko 2009).

Thus, the alternative [A.sub.j] is outranking the alternative [A.sub.k] (or [A.sub.j]P [A.sub.k]), if [F.sup.+] ([A.sub.j]) > [F.sup.+] ([A.sub.k]) (or [A.sub.j] [P.sup.+] [A.sub.k]) and [F.sup.-]([A.sub.j]) < [F.sup.-]([A.sub.k]) (or [A.sub.j][P.sup.-][A.sub.k]). The same holds if [A.sub.j][P.sup.+][A.sub.k] and [A.sub.j][I.sup. [A.sub.k] ([F.sup.-]([A.sub.j]) = [F.sup.-]([A.sub.k])), or in case if [A.sub.j][I.sup.+][A.sup.k] and [A.sub.j][P.sup.-][A.sub.k].

Similarly, indifference and incomparability of alternatives [A.sub.j] and [A.sub.k] are described. The PROMETHEE II method uses the idea of the PROMETHEE I method. But in addition it lists all evaluated alternatives in accordance with the level of their attractiveness, which is measured by the value of the difference (the net outranking flow) [F.sub.j] = [F.sup.+.sub.j] - [F.sup.-.sub.j]. The biggest difference between all positive ("outgoing") preference indices [F.sup.+.sub.j] and negative ("incoming") preference indices [F.sup.-.sub.j] (j = 1, 2, ..., n) corresponds to the best alternative. The PROMETHEE II method is ranging alternatives in decreasing order in respect of values [F.sub.j].

In contrast to the PROMETHEE II method, the PROMETHEE I method was designed to indicate only the best alternative, for which the number of worse alternatives in terms of preference is the highest.

3. Preference functions and their features

As was already mentioned, the argument d of preference function p(d) is the difference of criteria values. More precisely, for the i-th criterion for alternatives [A.sub.j] and Ak, we have [d.sub.i]([A.sub.j], [A.sub.k]) = [r.sub.ij]--[r.sub.ik], where [r.sub.ij] and [r.sub.ik] are values for the criterion i for mentioned alternatives. In spite of the fact that preference functions are of similar purpose as normalised values of data in other multi-criteria methods, their features and practical realisation are much more profound. We outline main features of preference functions:

--values of preference functions are falling to the interval from zero to one: 0 [less than or equal to] p(d) [less than or equal to] 1;

-- preference functions were projected to be functions representing maximising criteria by normalised values; the higher is value of the function p(d), the higher is preference of the alternative;

-- preference function p(d) value equals to zero when the difference d is smaller than the boundary value q: p(d) = 0 when d [less than or equal to] q (in some cases the boundary value q is not set and it is implied that q = 0);

-- in case when the upper boundary value s of the difference of values is set, then p(d) = 1 whenever d = s (there are cases when the upper boundary value s is not set and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]

There are known six preference functions p(d) (Brans, Mareschal 2005; Podvezko, Podviezko 2009), although some new preference functions will be proposed in this paper.

1. The so-called usual preference function could be used only in cases, when the decisionmaker cannot allocate importance for the differences between criteria values and only seems to know the formula "the more the better". This function does not depend on parameters q and s. In other words, the lower and the upper boundary values are not set for this type of preference function. This function could be proposed only in such cases when it is only important that the difference [d.sub.i]([A.sub.j],[A.sub.k]) = [r.sub.ij]--[r.sub.ik] between values [r.sub.ij] and [r.sub.ik] is positive (p(d) = 1) or negative (p(d) = 0) and the value of the difference does not matter. For example, one job offer is preferred over another if offered salary is higher without assigning any importance to the difference; it is important if distance to the office is higher or smaller; if interest rate offered by banks for term deposits is higher or smaller; if length of work experience between two candidates for a job is higher or smaller; if gasoline price at two gas stations is higher or smaller; if price between two investment projects is higher or smaller; if one candidate for a job knows more languages than another; if processor speed of one computer for sale is higher or lower than another's, etc.

We emphasise the fact that preference function is used in simultaneous pairwise evaluation by all m criteria. For example, the multi-criteria evaluation of candidates for a job offer will be conducted by simultaneous comparison of their length of work experience, level of education, knowledge of foreign languages, age, etc. By the other hand, the candidate will himself simultaneously compare salary, perspective, colleagues, distance to the office, office space, fringe benefits, etc.

The analytical expression and the shape of the first usual function are given on Fig. 1.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

2. The second U-shape preference function differs from the usual one by setting the lower boundary value q (here it is identical to the upper boundary value s), starting from which the difference of values of applied criterion is considered to induce the strict preference of one alternative over another. So, when the difference d is higher than q, value of the preference function equals to one and p(d) = 0 when d [less than or equal to] q.

The analytical expression and the shape of the second U-shape preference function are given on Fig. 2.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

This function has a higher practical importance comparing with the first usual preference function. We can easily adopt the above mentioned examples to fit them to the case of U-shape preference function. The new job will have strict preference (p(d) = 1) over another only in case if salary differs by no less than 100 euros (q = 100) and is of no importance to the employee (p(d) = 0), if an offered salary exceeds by less than 100 euros comparing to another offer. A bank's offer will be of interest in case if interest rate for term deposits exceeds 1% comparing to another bank's offer (q = 1); a candidate will be of interest in case his work experience exceeds work experience of another candidate by three years (q = 3) or he correctly answers at least three test questions more than another candidate and so on.

3. The third V-shape (or linear preference) preference function differs from the previous one in the interval from zero to s, where the link between the point of indifference of alternatives (p(d) = 0), no preference of one alternative over another) and the point of strict preference of one alternative over another (p(d) = 1) is not of a shape of a shift, but is linear. Another difference is by setting the upper boundary parameter s, from which one alternative has strict preference over another instead of the lower boundary parameter q, until which both alternatives are indifferent.

The analytical expression and the shape of the third V-shape preference function are given on Fig. 3.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Again, we can apply previous examples to this case of preference function by their slight modifying. Now, a job offer will have a strict preference over another in case of salary difference of 100 euros or more, is of no interest in case a lower salary is offered (p(d) = 0, when d is negative) and is of some gradually increasing interest in case the difference is up to 100 euros (0 < d [less than or equal to] 100). Preference function value is then expressed by the formula: p (d) = d/100. Other examples could be easily modified in the similar way.

4. The fourth preference function is called level preference function. It depends on two parameters p and q, thus both boundary values are set: the indifference boundary q and the strict preference boundary s. So, in case if the difference d of values of two alternatives is not greater than q, then the alternatives are indifferent (p(d) = 0); when the difference d is greater than s, then one alternative has the strict preference over another and whenever the difference d falls between q and s, or d [member of] [q, s], then value of the preference function equals to 0.5. In this case one alternative has a medium preference over another.

The analytical expression and the shape of the fourth level preference function are given on Fig. 4.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

For example, a candidate for a job will have no advantage if he knows less foreign languages than another candidate (p(d) = 0, d is negative) some advantage in case if he knows one language more than another candidate (p(d) = 0.5), and will have strict preference over another candidate in case he knows two more languages than another candidate (p(d) = 1). A similar preference function but with more step gradations could be used in case of more discreet options. It approximates the linear function as the number of gradations increases.

5. The fifth V-shape with indifference preference function (as well as level preference function) has both parameters q and s, which set boundaries of indifference and strict preference. But when the difference criteria values of two alternatives falls into the interval from q to s, or d [member of] [q,s], the preference function uniformly linearly increases from zero to one in accordance with the formula d - q/s - q and its value indicates the level of preference of one alternative over another. In the case when q = 0 this function becomes the third V-shape preference function.

Another example described above again could be easily transformed to this particular case. An employee will be indifferent if salary between two job offers differs by less than 100 euros (p(d) = 0). The new job will be of strict preference in case if salary in the new job offer exceeds 500 euros (p(d) = 1) and the new job will be of some preference over another in case if salary in the new job offer exceeds by a number between 100 and 500 euros; the level of preference is calculated by the formula p (d) = d - 100/500 - 100 = d - 100/400.

Other examples can be easily transformed similarly.

The analytical expression and the shape of the fifth V-shape with indifference preference function are given on Fig. 5.

This function is the most valuable and it attracts the largest number of theoretical and practical applications for evaluations carried out by PROMETHEE methods.

6. The sixth Gaussian preference function is used in case the initial statistical data is consisting of random values with the normal distribution. Preference at low differences of criteria values increases slowly by increase of d, starting from zero. The same applies also at large differences [d.sub.i]([A.sub.j],[A.sub.k]) of criteria values; the preference function in this case is gradually approaching one never reaching this value. This function requires a parameter [sigma] of standard deviation of given random data, and is increasing most rapidly at values of differences d close to [sigma].

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

The analytical expression and the shape of the fourth Gaussian preference function are given on Fig. 6.

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

We propose several new preference functions.

7. Multistage preference function. Some alternatives can only have discreet criteria values.

Very often, they are natural positive numbers. Consider the number of spoken languages, number of children in a family, number of stock in farms, number of shops in a supermarket chain in a town, number of ATM machines possessed by a bank. In all such cases, differences of criteria values are discrete or are natural numbers (positive and negative). Quite interesting is the case, when criteria values are real numbers, like amounts in euros, but criteria of preference should be expressed in natural numbers. For example, consider the fact that the GDP plan is usually revealed to the public and will be perceived in billions, while projection versions are given in real numbers. Consequently, evaluation of the plan or its outcome in public is going to be in integer billions, not in real numbers. In addition, consider evaluation of bank performance. Precise data is produced in real numbers while evaluation is going to be made and discussed in millions. Price for a large possession is given in real numbers while perception of the price is going to be in thousands. These examples show how important might be the multistage preference function in order to match expert's perception of the criterion. The fourth level function with its only values 0, 0.5, 1 is too rough to deal with all mentioned cases.

For integer criteria values we must have the largest difference d = s, where s is integer number. In case it is not available, take [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] or any lower value, which sets an expert.

For real criteria values, the analytical expression and the shape of the seventh new multistage preference function are given on Fig. 7.

[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]

In case criteria values are discrete, the function can be defined in a different way. The analytical expression of the multistage preference function for discrete criteria values is given in formula (5):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] (5)

8. The eighth C-shape preference function is rapidly increasing at low differences of criteria values [d.sub.i]([A.sub.j],[A.sub.k]) by increase of d, starting from zero. The higher become values of difference d, the smaller is relative increase of preference function. This function is somewhat similar to the linear priority function, although is sensitive to even large differences of criteria values and induces more relative sensitivity at low differences d.

The analytical expression and the shape of the seventh C-shape preference function are given on Fig. 8.

[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]

This function could be used instead of the third V-shape preference function; it fits better for such cases when small differences between two criteria values induce more relative importance than large differences. A good illustration is again job-searching, when small increases of salary are usually of more relative practical value than high increases.

We also propose some other preference function: p (d) = 3[square root of (d/s)] (its shape looks similar to the one shown on the 8-th graph), p (d) = 2/[pi] arctg d (its shape looks similar to the shape of the 6th preference function, but is applicable for non-statistical data).

4. Dependence of evaluation result on choice of preference function types and their parameters

Dependence of evaluation result will be illustrated by the example of growing of economies of the Baltic States and Poland for the year of 2003. Calculations were made using different multi-criteria methods (Ginevicius et al. 2006). A solution having used the PROMETHEE I method was already demonstrated (Podvezko, Podviezko 2009). Statistical data is given in Table 1.

Experts have chosen the following weights of these criteria values (Ginevicius et al. 2006): [[omega.sub.1] = 0.28; [[omega.sub.2] = 0.19; [[omega.sub.3] = 0.15; [[omega.sub.5]= 0.20

We are now going to explore dependence of evaluation results using PROMETHEE I and PROMETHEE II methods on the choice of the type of the preference function p(d) among the five used in practice and described above, and its parameters (Brans, Mareschal 2005; Podvezko, Podviezko 2009). The sixth Gaussian function was not used, as the given data does not contain standard deviation parameter s, which also cannot be derived.

In order to choose parameters q and s for preference functions first we find out the smallest module of differences between given criteria values [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] and the largest module of differences [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] using the following algorithm. The largest module of difference could be obtained using the formula: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] For the first criterion, for example, it yields: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]. To obtain the smallest module of difference, the data is sorted in the descending order, differences of nearby criteria values are calculated and the smallest difference is therefore taken. For example, the sorted list of values of the criterion in the first row is the following: (9.7; 7.5; 5.1; 3.8). The smallest module of differences for this criterion is equal:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]

Values of parameters q and s for preference functions are falling to the interval between the smallest and the largest modules of differences of values of criterion:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] (6)

It is clear that setting parameter q lower than just obtained the smallest value [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] and parameter s larger than the largest obtained value [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] will not make sense.

The smallest [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] and the largest [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] differences of values of criteria describing development of economies of countries (see Table 1) are shown in the Table 2.

To demonstrate dependence of evaluation results on the choice of preference functions and their parameters, six following examples are proposed.

The first example was already studied (Podvezko, Podviezko 2009): [p.sub.5]([d.sub.1]) (q = 2; s = 3.5); [p.sub.3]([d.sub.2]) (s = 7); [p.sub.4]([d.sub.3]) (s = 150); [p.sub.2]([d.sub.4]) (q = 2); [p.sub.1]([d.sub.5]). This means that for the first criterion the fifth preference function was used with parameters q = 2 and s = 3.5; similarly, for other criteria. We aimed to use all the five preference functions here, different for every criterion. In the second example, the first preference function was used for all criteria. It does not have q and s parameters. In the third example, the only the second preference function was used with parameters: [q.sub.1] = 2.5; [q.sub.2] = 2; [q.sub.3] = 150; [q.sub.4] = 2.2; [q.sub.5] = 0.1. In the fourth example the third preference function was used for all criteria with the following parameters: [s.sub.1] = 5; [s.sub.2] = 8; [s.sub.3] = 100; [s.sub.4] = 10; [s.sub.5] = 0.1. In the fifth example the fourth preference function was used for all the criteria with the following parameters: [q.sub.1] = 2.5; [s.sub.1] = 5; [q.sub.2] = 2; [s.sub.2] = 8; [q.sub.3] = 130; [s.sub.3] = 195; [q.sub.4] = 2.3; [s.sub.4] = 10; [q.sub.5] = 0.06; [s.sub.5] = 0.15. In the sixth example the fifth preference function was used for all the criteria with the following parameters: [q.sub.1] = 2.5; [s.sub.1] = 5; [q.sub.2] = 2; [s.sub.2] = 8; [q.sub.3] = 130; [s.sub.3] = 195; [q.sub.4] = 2.3; [s.sub.4] = 10; [q.sub.5] = 0.06; [s.sub.5] = 0.15.

In different fourth and fifth preference functions used in fifth and sixth examples, we chose the same parameters q and s.

Now we find out dominance relation [pi]([A.sub.j], [A.sub.k] between all pairs of alternatives: preference, indifference and incomparability by using the formula (2). Then assessment of outranking flows [F.sup.+] and [F.sup.-], respectively positive and negative is made. Results are given in the Table 3.

It is clearly observed that outranking flows used in both PROMETHEE I and PROMETHEE II methods [F.sup.+.sub.j], [F.sup.-.sub.j] and [F.sub.j] considerably differ between themselves. Ranks are not always matching as well, when different preference functions are used (the third, the fourth and the fifth examples). Note that in the fifth and the sixth examples exposed in Table 3 two different preference functions were used (the fourth and the fifth) with the same parameters q and s, and this yielded different outcome.

Observe dependence of the result of evaluation on choice of parameters as well as on choice of the type of preference function. It is interesting to look simultaneously to influences of both the fourth and the fifth preference functions, which depend on two parameters q and s. The two functions differ in the interval [q, s], where the fifth function uniformly increases in accordance with the expression d - q/ s - q, as the difference of criteria values d increase, while the fourth function assigns the same average value of 0.5 in the interval. First, for every i-th criterion let us choose the largest possible interval [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] Table 2) and then diminish the interval, at each grade extinguishing worst or best alternative at the time. We obtain the following outcome (Table 4).

Our carried out computations display the fact that evaluation results may well differ upon the choice of preference functions as well as on their parameters q and s. Outranking flow values [F.sup.+.sub.j], [F.sup.-.sub.j] and mostly [F.sub.j] can considerably differ. Yielded evaluation ranks of countries can also differ. In spite of the fact that Lithuania outranks other countries by economic criteria of 2003, ranks of other countries depend on choice of preference function and chosen values of parameters q and s.

5. Conclusions

PROMETHEE methods fall to the range of complex quantitative multi-criteria methods. They account values of criteria (and their weights) indirectly over so-called preference functions. Computations of different examples reveal the fact that evaluation outcome depends on both choice of preference function and its parameters. What is the most important, choices cannot be made carelessly. Unlike other popular multi-criteria methods, active participation of decision-makers or qualified specialists is compulsory as they recommend types of preference functions for every criterion, set the largest and the lowers boundaries for all criteria parameters as well as other parameters. New tools were proposed in this paper, new types of preference functions, with intention of widening the range of choice for decisionmakers and evaluation experts. An algorithm yielding the largest and the lowest boundaries for parameters of preference functions thus helping to make a choice of these parameters is also presented.

doi: 10.3846/tede.2010.09

Received 13 July 2009; accepted 14 December 2009

Reference to this paper should be made as follows: Podvezko, V.; Podviezko, A. Dependence of multi-criteria evaluation result on choice of preference functions and their parameters, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 16(1): 143-158.

References

Behzadian, M.; Kazemzadeh, R. B.; Albadvi, A.; Aghdasi, M. 2010. PROMETHEE: A comprehensive literature review on methodologies and applications, European Journal of Operational Research 200(1): 198-215. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2009.01.021.

Brans, J.-P.; Mareschal, B. 1992. PROMETHEE-V--MCDM problems with segmentation constraints, INFOR 30(2): 85-96.

Brans, J.-P.; Mareschal, B. 1994. The PROMETHEE-GAIA decision support system for multi-criteria investigations, Investigation Operative 4(2): 107-117.

Brans, J.-P.; Mareschal, B. 1996. The PROMETHEE-VI procedure. How to differentiate hard from soft multi-criteria problems, Journal of Decision Systems 4: 213-223.

Brans, J.-P.; Mareschal, B. 2005. PROMETHEE methods, in 'Multiple Criteria Decision Analysis: State of the Art Surveys'. Edited by J. Figueira, S. Greco, M. Ehrgott. Springer, Chapter 5: 163-195.

Brauers, W. K. M.; Ginevicius, R.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Antucheviciene, J. 2007. The European Union in a transition economy, Transformations in Business & Economics 6(2): 21-37.

Brauers, W. K. M.; Zavadskas, E. K. 2006. The MOORA method and its application to privatization in a transition economy, Control and Cybernetics 35(2): 445-469.

Figueira, J.; Greco, S.; Ehrgott, M. (Eds.). 2005. Multiple Criteria Decision Analysis: State of the Art Survey. Springer.

Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V. 2008a. Multicriteria graphical-analytical evaluation of the financial state of construction enterprises, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(4): 452-461. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.452-461.

Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V. 2008b. Multicriteria evaluation of Lithuanian banks from the perspective of their reliability for clients, Journal of Business Economics and Management 9(4): 257-267. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2008.9.257-267.

Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V. 2008c. Housing in the context of economic and social development of Lithuanian regions, Int. J. Environment and Pollution 35(2/3/4): 309-330. doi:10.1504/IJEP.2008.021363.

Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V. 2009. Evaluating the changes in economic and social development of Lithuanian counties by multiple criteria methods, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(3): 418-436. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.418-436.

Ginevicius, R.; Butkevicius, A.; Podvezko, V. 2006. Complex evaluation of economic development of the Baltic States and Poland, Ekonomicky Casopis 54(9): 918-930.

Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V.; Bruzge, S. 2008a. Evaluating the effect of state aid to business by multicriteria methods, Journal of Business Economics and Management 9(3): 167-180. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2008.9.167-180.

Ginevicius, R.; Podvezko, V.; Raslanas, S. 2008b. Evaluating the alternative solutions of wall insulation by multicriteria methods, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 14(4): 217-226. doi:10.3846/1392-3730.2008.14.20.

Hui, E. C. M.; Lau, O. M. F.; Lo, K. K. 2009. A fuzzy decision-making approach for portfolio management with direct real estate investment, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 13(2): 191-204. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2009.13.191-204.

Hwang, C. L.; Yoon, K. 1981. Multiple Attibute Decision Making-Methods and Applications. A State of the Art Survey. Springer Verlag, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York.

Jakimavicius, M.; Burinskiene, M. 2009. Assessment of Vilnius city development scenarios based on transport system modelling and multicriteria analysis, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 15(4): 361-368. doi:10.3846/1392-3730.2009.15.361-368.

Maskeliunaite, L.; Sivilevicius, H.; Podvezko, V. 2009. Research on the quality of passenger transportation by railway, Transport 24(2): 100-112. doi:10.3846/1648-4142.2009.24.100-112.

Nowak, M. 2005. Investment projects evaluation by simulation and multiple criteria decision aiding procedure, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 11(3): 193-202.

Plebankiewicz, E. 2009. Contractor prequalification model using fuzzy sets, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 15(4): 377-385. doi:10.3846/1392-3730.2009.15.377-385.

Podvezko, V. 2009. Application of AHP technique, Journal of Business Economics and Management 10(2): 181-189. doi:10.3846/1611-1699.2009.10.181-189.

Podvezko, V.; Podviezko, A. 2009. PROMETHEE I method application for identification of the best alternative, Business: Theory and Practice 10(2): 84-92 (in Lithuanian). doi:10.3846/1648-0627.2009.10.84-92.

Turskis, Z.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Peldschus, F. 2009. Multi-criteria optimization system for decision making in construction design and management, Inzinerine Ekonomika--Engineering Economics 1: 7-17.

Ulubeyli, S.; Kazaz, A. 2009. A multiple criteria decision-making approach to the selection of concrete pumps, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 15(4): 369-376. doi:10.3846/1392-3730.2009.15.369-376.

Ustinovichius, L.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Podvezko, V. 2007. Application of a quantitative multiple criteria decision making (MCDM-1) approach to the analysis of investments in construction, Control and Cybernetics 36 (1): 251-268.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Antucheviciene, J. 2006. Development of an indicator model and ranking of sustainable revitalization of derelict property: A Lithuanian case study, Sustainable Development 14(5): 287-299. doi:10.1002/sd.285.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Kaklauskas, A.; Turskis, Z.; Tamosaitiene, J. 2008a. Selection of the effective dwelling house walls by applying attributes values determined at intervals, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 14(2): 85-93. doi:10.3846/1392-3730.2008.14.3.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Turskis, Z.; Tamosaitiene, J.; Marina, V. 2008b. Multicriteria selection of project managers by applying grey criteria, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(4): 462-477. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.462-477.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Kaklauskas, A.; Turskis, Z.; Tamosaitiene, J. 2009. Multi-attribute decision-making model by applying grey numbers, Informatica 20(2): 305-320.

Valentinas PODVEZKO. Doctor, Professor. Department of Mathematical Statistics. Vilnius Gediminas Technical University. Author and co-author of over 100 publications. Research interests: sampling and forecasting models in economics.

Askoldas PODVIEZKO. PhD student at Vilnius Gediminas Technical University (VGTU), Department of Enterprise Economics and Management. MSc Dept of Applied Mathematics and Cybernetics, Lomonosov Moscow University (1989); University of Manchester, Manchester Business School (2005). Research interests: sampling models in economics, banking business.

Valentinas Podvezko (1), Askoldas Podviezko (2)

Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223 Vilnius, Lithuania (1)Department of Mathematical Statistics, (2) Department of Enterprise Economics and Management

E-mails: 1valentinas.podvezko@vgtu.lt; 2askoldas@gmail.com
Table 1. Criteria values of economical growth of different countries

Criteria Types of Estonia Latvia
 criteria

1 Annual growth of the GDP, % max 5.1 7.5
2 Annual growth of production, % max 9.8 6.5
3 Average annual salary max 430 298
 in euros, %
4 Unemployment rate, % min 9.3 10.3
5 Export/import ratio, % max 0.70 0.55

Criteria Lithuania Poland

1 Annual growth of the GDP, % 9.7 3.8
2 Annual growth of production, % 16.1 8.4
3 Average annual salary 306 501
 in euros, %
4 Unemployment rate, % 11.6 19.3
5 Export/import ratio, % 0.73 0.79

Table 2. The smallest and the largest modules of differences between
given criteria values

Criteria min [absolute value of [d.sub.i]
 ([A.sub.j],[A.sub.k])]
 1[less than or equal to]j,
 k<[less than or equal to] n

1 Annual growth of the GDP 1.3
2 Annual growth of production 1.4
3 Average annual salary in euros 8
4 Unemployment rate 1.0
5 Export/import ratio 0.03

Criteria max [absolute value of
 [d.sub.i]([A.sub.i], [A.sub.k])
 1 [less than or equal to]j,
 k [less than or equal to] n

1 Annual growth of the GDP 5.9
2 Annual growth of production 9.6
3 Average annual salary in euros 203
4 Unemployment rate 10.0
5 Export/import ratio 0.24

Table 3. Evaluations with different preference functions

Examples Evaluation outcome Estonia Latvia

1. All preference [F.sup.+.sub.j] 0.838 0.535
functions [F.sup.-.sub.j] 1.001 1.193
are different [F.sub.j] -0.163 -0.658
 PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2 --
 PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4

2. The first [F.sup.+.sub.j] 1.70 0.92
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 1.30 2.08
fo all criteria [F.sub.j] 0.40 -1.16
 PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2 --
 PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4

3. The second [F.sup.+.sub.j] 0.75 0.46
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.47 1.13
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] 0.28 -0.67
[q.sub.1] = 2.5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2 --
[q.sub.2] = 2; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 3
[q.sub.3] = 150;
[q.sub.4] = 2.2;
[q.sub.5] = 0.1

4. The third [F.sup.+.sub.j] 0.924 0.527
preference function [F.sub.j] 0.888 1.367
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] 0.036 -0.840
[s.sub.1] = 5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2-3 --
[s.sub.2]= 8; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4
[s.sub.3] = 100;
[s.sub.4] = 10;
[s.sub.5] = 0.1

5. The fourth [F.sup.+.sub.j] 0.450 0.230
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.335 1.010
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] 0.115 -0.780
[q.sub.1] = 2.5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2-3 --
[s.sub.1] = 5; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4
[q.sub.2] = 2;
[s.sub.2]= 8;
[q.sub.3] = 130;
[s.sub.3] = 195;
[q.sub.4] = 2.3;
[s.sub.4]= 10;
[q.sub.5] = 0.06;
[s.sub.5] = 0.15

6. The fifth [F.sup.+.sub.j] 0.426 0.291
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.438 0.986
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] -0.012 -0.695
[q.sub.1] = 2.5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2 --
[s.sub.1] = 5; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4
[q.sub.2] = 2;
[s.sub.2]= 8;
[q.sub.3] = 130;
[s.sub.3] = 195;
[q.sub.4] = 2.3;
[s.sub.4]= 10;
[q.sub.5] = 0.06;
[s.sub.5] = 0.15

Examples Evaluation outcome Lithuania Poland

1. All preference [F.sup.+.sub.j] 1.728 1.027
functions [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.605 1.325
are different [F.sub.j] 1.123 -0.293
 PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 --
 PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3

2. The first [F.sup.+.sub.j] 2.14 1.24
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.86 1.76
fo all criteria [F.sub.j] 1.28 -0.52
 PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 3
 PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3

3. The second [F.sup.+.sub.j] 1.51 0.50
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.33 1.29
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] 1.18 -0.79
[q.sub.1] = 2.5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 --
[q.sub.2] = 2; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 4
[q.sub.3] = 150;
[q.sub.4] = 2.2;
[q.sub.5] = 0.1

4. The third [F.sup.+.sub.j] 1.594 0.952
preference function [F.sub.j] 0.485 1.257
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] 1.109 -0.305
[s.sub.1] = 5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 2-3
[s.sub.2]= 8; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3
[s.sub.3] = 100;
[s.sub.4] = 10;
[s.sub.5] = 0.1

5. The fourth [F.sup.+.sub.j] 1.090 0.625
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.265 0.785
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] 0.825 -0.160
[q.sub.1] = 2.5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 2-3
[s.sub.1] = 5; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3
[q.sub.2] = 2;
[s.sub.2]= 8;
[q.sub.3] = 130;
[s.sub.3] = 195;
[q.sub.4] = 2.3;
[s.sub.4]= 10;
[q.sub.5] = 0.06;
[s.sub.5] = 0.15

6. The fifth [F.sup.+.sub.j] 1.348 0.567
preference function [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.150 1.058
for all criteria: [F.sub.j] 1.198 -0.491
[q.sub.1] = 2.5; PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 --
[s.sub.1] = 5; PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3
[q.sub.2] = 2;
[s.sub.2]= 8;
[q.sub.3] = 130;
[s.sub.3] = 195;
[q.sub.4] = 2.3;
[s.sub.4]= 10;
[q.sub.5] = 0.06;
[s.sub.5] = 0.15

Table 4. Influence of choice of parameters to the evaluation outcome

Interval of
parameters
[[q.sub.i], The fourth function
[s.sub.i]] Evaluation outcome Estonia Latvia

1) [1.3;5.9] [F.sup.+.sub.7] 0.620 0.460
2) [1.4;9.6] [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.650 0.975
3) [8;203] [F.sub.j] -0.030 -0.515
4) [1;10] PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2-3 --
5) [0.03;0.24] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 3 4

1) [2.2;4.6] 2) [F.sup.+.sub.7] 0.615 0.460
[1.9;7.7] 3) [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.475 0.910
[71;195] 4) [F.sub.j] 0.140 -0.450
[1.3;9] 5) PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2 --
[0.06;0.18] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4

Interval of
parameters
[[q.sub.i], The fourth function
[s.sub.i]] Evaluation outcome Lithuania Poland

1) [1.3;5.9] [F.sup.+.sub.7] 0.995 0.720
2) [1.4;9.6] [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.430 0.740
3) [8;203] [F.sub.j] 0.565 -0.02
4) [1;10] PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 2-3
5) [0.03;0.24] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 2

1) [2.2;4.6] 2) [F.sup.+.sub.7] 1.085 0.625
[1.9;7.7] 3) [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.430 0.970
[71;195] 4) [F.sub.j] 0.655 -0.345
[1.3;9] 5) PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 --
[0.06;0.18] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3

Interval of
parameters
[[q.sub.i], The fifth function
[s.sub.i]] Evaluation outcome Estonia Latvia

1) [1.3;5.9] [F.sup.+.sub.7] 0.549 0.379
2) [1.4;9.6] [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.487 1.003
3) [8;203] [F.sub.j] 0.062 -0.624
4) [1;10] PROMETHEE I (ranks) 3 --
5) [0.03;0.24] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4

1) [2.2;4.6] 2) [F.sup.+.sub.7] 0.537 0.378
[1.9;7.7] 3) [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.497 1.010
[71;195] 4) [F.sub.j] 0.040 -0.631
[1.3;9] 5) PROMETHEE I (ranks) 2 --
[0.06;0.18] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 2 4

Interval of
parameters
[[q.sub.i], The fifth function
[s.sub.i]] Evaluation outcome Lithuania Poland

1) [1.3;5.9] [F.sup.+.sub.7] 1.262 0.640
2) [1.4;9.6] [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.294 1.046
3) [8;203] [F.sub.j] 0.968 -0.406
4) [1;10] PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 --
5) [0.03;0.24] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3

1) [2.2;4.6] 2) [F.sup.+.sub.7] 1.434 0.550
[1.9;7.7] 3) [F.sup.-.sub.j] 0.237 1.155
[71;195] 4) [F.sub.j] 1.196 -0.605
[1.3;9] 5) PROMETHEE I (ranks) 1 --
[0.06;0.18] PROMETHEE II (ranks) 1 3
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有