Economic recession, work, and solidarity.
Hinze, Christine Firer
ECONOMIC PAIN AMID SEVERE RECESSION is the organizing focus of this
note; understanding and crafting adequate theoretical and practical
responses to this pain is its interest. Theological ethics approaches
such economic matters in light of a Christian interpretation of God,
human nature, and destiny. This approach suffuses Pope Benedict
XVI's 2009 encyclical on integral human development. Released in
the thick of global economic crisis, Caritas in veritate proclaims
"love in truth" the "principle on which the Church's
social doctrine turns." (1) "Love in truth" takes
practical form in criteria for moral action--justice and the common
good, solidarity, and subsidiarity. The yardstick for measuring economic
systems and policies is their success in advancing holistic and
sustainable human development and well-being. (2)
Grappling with economy's veritas demands just agents and
systems; but, the pope insists, persons and institutions can only be
just if vivified by caritas. Solidarity, the virtue that acknowledges
the complex truth of social, economic, and material interconnectedness,
strives to understand it, and then responds in generous service to the
common good, captures the posture and practice to which Benedict's
treatise points. A successful market economy serves the integral
flourishing of its participants inclusively. (3) To accomplish this,
Benedict emphasizes that market logics must be rooted in,
"salted," and guided by greater-hearted logics of generosity,
solidarity, and gift. (4)
Amid pressing economic problems, Caritas in veritate's talk of
love, solidarity, and gift--indeed, Catholic social teaching (CST) in
general--easily reads as idealistic side-conversation. To counter this
impression requires a Catholic economic-ethical agenda prepared to
grapple credibly and persuasively with both the economic and the ethical
challenges that current economic circumstances present. (5)
These circumstances are complex and daunting. With markets
crisscrossing the planet, abetted by instantaneous communications and
computerized connectivity, the 21st-century economy is coming to
resemble the invisible planetary web that Teilhard de Chardin envisioned
as the evolving "noosphere." Yet economics, however
globalized, technical, or arcane, is grounded in the realities of the
material world and human bodies. Directly or remotely, every economic
process touches the commerce between embodied persons' needs and
desires, and the material and social environments within which people
extract, concoct, amass, exchange, and distribute the means to fulfill
them.
Robust ethical analysis, therefore, must take into account the
material-moral habitats of economic activity and attend carefully to the
economy's concrete effects on the daily lives of individuals,
families, and communities. As Christian ethics works from its
theocentric perspective, its subject matter demands, as well,
interdisciplinary and experiential competence. In that spirit, I here
sample literature whose foci range from globe to household, from credit
derivative products to mundane physical labor. Among myriad urgent
discussions, I target four topics of special importance: debates over
economics' descriptive and normative "axis"; ethical
treatments of the global financial crisis; issues and disparities in the
"real economy" of employment, work, and wages; and, very
briefly, solidarity and sustainability.
WHAT IS THE SUBJECT? CONTESTING ECONOMY'S DESCRIPTIVE AND
NORMATIVE "AXIS"
Weaving their way through debates about what has gone wrong in the
Great Recession and how to fix it are fundamental, often-unexamined
assumptions concerning "free market economy" or
"currently-existing capitalism." Those attempting to join
these debates must either subscribe to, credibly challenge, or
creatively subvert a set of convictions that shapes the ways economic
matters are understood by theorists, policy makers, and the general
public. (6) This regnant "economic orthodoxy" comprises three
interrelated tenets: (1) a complex factual claim, (2) a consequent norm,
and (3) a utilitarian defense. (1) Factual claim: Markets (and
successful market behaviors (a) are amoral, profit maximizing, and
growth-driven mechanisms of great complexity, which (b) work best
(maximize productivity, profit, and growth) when outside interference
motivated by nonmarket goals is minimized. (2) Consequent norm:
Therefore, the amoral, profit-maximizing dynamics of modern capitalist
markets must be respected and protected for the sake of the great goods
(material prosperity) that such markets make possible for great numbers
of people. (3) Utilitarian defense: It is true that capitalist market
dynamics can breed vice and cause harm, fomenting at times ruthless
competition and rivalries for scarce goods and profits, fostering the
treatment of people as means rather than ends, generating disparities in
accumulation and power, and marginalizing or excluding those lacking
salable goods or services/skills. Nonetheless, the great benefits
generated by markets outstrip the debits, so the aforementioned norm
stands.
This market orthodoxy informs the theory and practice of
contemporary capitalist markets and oxygenates the moral atmosphere in
which market actors live, move, and have their beings. Insofar as market
orthodoxy naturalizes existing economic relations, conceals the ways
business-as-usual disproportionately benefits sectional interests, or
predetermines limits on imagining anything different, it also functions
as ideology.
Economist Julie Nelson finds that even critics who challenge market
orthodoxy's other tenets rarely question its description of markets
as dynamic but amoral efficiency mechanisms, fueled by self-interest
toward maximal profits and continuing bottom-line growth. Orthodox
"market cheerleaders" scorn "ethical critics" for
pushing policies that threaten to starve or strangle the golden
egg-laying goose. Ethical critics propose reforms intended to mitigate
markets' negative effects, but most critics stop short of
contesting markets' productive and distributive "rules."
Nelson urges market supporters and critics to join forces to
maximize both market goods (production of necessary and life-enhancing
goods and services, job creation, opportunities for financial
self-support, creativity, collaboration) and the goods (moral, esthetic,
and spiritual values, care and concern for the vulnerable, ecological
sustainability, social justice) advanced by ethics. To do so, however,
both sides must first relinquish the view of
"market-as-inviolable-mechanism" for a more practical view
that treats markets as important and necessary--though not absolute or
sufficient-tools for human provisioning, development, and well-being.
Forging a more adequate relationship between economics and ethics
requires "respecting the good things that each side values, while
dropping the idea that these good things are automatically either
provided or destroyed by economic life." (7)
Robert Lane argues that the framing of such basic questions
constitutes the descriptive and moral "axis" around which a
society's major politico- economic debates then revolve. (8) This
axis "offers to whole societies a central theme" that gives
"purpose and direction to their striving." The axial theme
also "creates major partisan camps whose shifting alignments
produce the dominant patterns of political life." Modern capitalism
revolves around an "economistic axis," grounded "on the
correct assumption that economic welfare is the foundation of
life," and "the incorrect assumption that quality of life or
happiness is (above a decent minimum) directly related to levels of
income and wealth." (9) Lane appeals for an axial reorientation
toward a more comprehensive, well-being and development (WBD) axis. This
fresh axis "does not ignore economic issues but rather reformulates
them," focusing less on "local 'utilities' but on
satisfaction with life-as-a-whole" and on human capital over
physical capital. (10) In a WBD economy, actors can derive happiness and
"psychic income" from such things as productivity and
meaningful work, and more readily prioritize and enjoy
"non-transferable, non-zero-sum goods" that can be widely
distributed. (11)
Christian ethicist Rebecca Todd Peters also connects economic
discourse to orienting visions of the good life. She identifies a
"social development" model of global economy that has arisen
to correct problems generated by dominant neoliberal economics,
especially its marginalization of caring labor, its general disregard
for nonpecuniary well-being, and its tendency to increase economic
inequality and insecurity to the detriment of peace and social order.
The social development economy's moral axis is
"responsibility," especially of the advantaged toward the
disadvantaged; it frames human flourishing as "equity,"
wherein social and economic opportunities are widely distributed and
great disparities overcome. Flourishing is pursued by way of
market-focused economic and social development. (12)
While the social-development paradigm is an improvement on
neoliberal economic models, Peters judges it insufficient, absent a
radical orientation to solidarity with the poor and solidarity with the
earth. She contends that a social-development (or WBD) axis requires
both a more radical, earthist reorientation that makes care for the
earth coconstitutive of human well-being, and a postcolonialist
reorientation that makes democratizing power a central goal and guiding
norm.
Catholic ethics, too, contests the descriptive and normative axes
around which cluster the beliefs, values, and aspirations that animate
current global economics. In line with heterodox economists, CST affirms
economy's traditional purpose, namely, to provide sustenance for
community members. To this end, CST acknowledges the allocative benefits
of market exchange and markets' remarkable capacities for
productivity and efficiency, but it criticizes neoclassical economics
for ignoring or undermining crucial aspects of economy's
provisioning mission.
Daniel Finn, for instance, underscores the "moral
ecology" that markets require in order to function well and for the
common welfare. Self-interest- driven interactions in the market can
produce great benefits. But "no one will have confidence that the
interactions of self-interest in markets will be just if markets operate
without a well-functioning civil society" and a legal system that
embeds a set of moral and legal fences around the market's
activities and infuses the internal workings of the market with the
necessary virtues. (13)
Introducing a new collection on economics and CST, Finn judges most
Catholic economic ethics since the 1960s as overly determined by either
"free market" or "liberationist" commitments.
Attempting to approach the economy from viewpoints as "free from
ideology as possible," the volume's authors address, from
various disciplinary perspectives, a single, "empirical
proposition": "The economic and cultural criteria identified
in the tradition of Catholic social thought provide an effective path to
sustainable prosperity for all." (14)
Their common project yields a substantive harvest. However, I fear
that a "nonideological" framing may inadvertently marginalize
the resources that radical and critical social theory have to contribute
to Catholic economic ethics, particularly in the areas of ideology
critique, power analysis, and conflict. Catholic ethics needs resources
and methods for addressing these dimensions of economic life. Furthering
a solidary common good requires keen and adaptable "ideological and
power antennae"; to cultivate these antennae Catholics must learn
from heirs of Karl Marx and Adam Smith. (15)
Recent CST, as Finn notes, has more explicitly embraced the good
things that market economy offers, while continuing to insist that
economy's orienting axis must be human welfare and the common good.
But recent CST has also embraced key elements of liberationist theology,
most importantly its foregrounding of solidarity and the preferential
option for the poor. Effectively incorporating these latter developments
may be the most pressing task facing Catholic economic ethics today.
ETHICAL ANALYSES OF THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS
The global financial meltdown has unleashed a torrent of analyses,
highlighting several prominent themes.
(1) Economic orthodoxy has especially pernicious moral effects in
the practice of international finance. One reason for this is economic
orthodoxy's role in a new "turbo-capitalism" (16) whose
complexity, pace, and technicality, given "orthodox market"
conditions, dismantles practitioners' already limited capabilities
for moral behavior. By 1997 finance economist John Dobson (17) was
observing that, in the field of finance, neoclassical economics'
"first principle," that "'every agent is motivated
solely by self interest,'" had been sharpened, so that
self-interest came to be defined in these terms: "individuals
always prefer more wealth to less" and will "act with, if
necessary, guile and deceit." Finance economics had come to
"characterize self-interest as the narrowly individualistic and
opportunistic pursuit of material wealth, to the exclusion of all other
motivations." (18)
Dobson names this belief set the finance paradigm. "The force
of this paradigm is so strong and so entrenched that it continues to be
maintained in the face of considerable evidence that it is
self-contradictory," most obviously because global financial
transactions depend upon trustworthy contracts and reputation effects.
(19) The paradigm posits only "opportunistic agents" who
should not be trusted; but without mutual trust and confidence in the
validity of contracts, inefficiency results, and wealth maximization is
undercut. Dobson concludes that neoclassical finance theory is unable to
explain what really happens in financial systems.
Ghanaian banker David Sifah sees a similar inconsistency in the
finance industry's reliance on "principal-agent"
relationships. The "behavioral assumption of modern
financial-economic theory runs counter to the ideas of trustworthiness,
loyalty, fidelity, stewardship and concern for others that underlie the
traditional principal-agent relationship." "A system that has
rules requiring agents to look out for others while encouraging
individuals to look out only for themselves, destroys the practice of
looking out for others." (20)
Some authors go further to argue that the teaching and practice of
finance actively incentivizes immoral, even pathological, market
behavior. John Mixon postulates "a cause-and-effect connection
between the ascendant theory of the purely economically driven person
and the bad behavior that led to the recent failure of economic
institutions." Bluntly stated, the "economic person" as
presented in neoclassical economics "is a sociopath." Mixon
worries about the corrosive impact of this anthropology, and the
Hobbesian world it implies, on the values and behavior of business and
law school graduates. Business decision-making that begins with the
premise, "people are equally endowed, rational, purely
self-interested, unconnected individuals who compete for goods in the
free market," will proceed very differently than "if the
beginning premise were, 'People are moral beings who are members
of, and who are largely defined by, mutually supportive
communities.'" In the former case, "if there is money to
be made by an otherwise legal scheme that destroys the entire banking
system, what would a rational sociopath do?" For moral values to
thrive in markets, Mixon concludes, "those who exercise economic
and political power must care about the effects of their actions on the
total community. Hobbesian creatures, homo economici, and sociopaths
really don't care." (21)
(2) Financial market agents and structures conspired in generating
dangerous, maldistributed levels of systemic risk. Risk rose as
technical complexities and connections compounded rapidly, beyond the
capability of many managers to adequately comprehend or direct. Risk was
further intensified because exponentially-increasing "network
connectivities" lacked commensurate, "networked
communities." Paul David underscores a chronic instability in the
dynamics of capitalist "information societies" that focus
people's creative energies and imagination almost exclusively on
enabling new forms of "hyper-connected exchange networks," but
fail to cultivate "network communities that can effectively govern
the complex socio-technical systems they have built." (22)
Ross Hammond employs a network science perspective to suggest three
vulnerabilities in financial-market structures that may have contributed
to the crisis: financial networks may have lacked "robustness"
(making the whole system vulnerable to breakdown when a few major
entities failed); patterns of linkage among institutions and individuals
may have left the system vulnerable to "contagion"; and "
lack of diversity in financial networks" (risk management
strategies became homogenous as the system got more complex) may have
impaired their "resilience" in the face of changed financial
environments. (23)
Along with systemic opacity and poor oversight, imprudence, greed,
and disregard of fiduciary responsibilities to clients and firms
contributed to over-risk. Etienne Perrot argues that the ethics of
financial risk requires equitable "risk solidarity" among
parties involved. Asymmetrical possession of information concerning risk
and other factors contributes to an unethical "lack of risk
solidarity, inasmuch as it guarantees secure profits for some and not
for others who are facing the same economic situation." Alluding to
the problem of calculating risk in situations of genuine (incalculable)
uncertainty, Perrot concludes that the use of a financial instrument
"can be qualified as immoral when the user cannot answer for the
consequences of his or her acts." (24)
Paul Dembinski situates the financial crisis in the context of
"institutional chaos" and outdated structures of international
oversight. "The Bretton Woods system [of international monetary
institutions, established in 1944, when 'international finance was
almost nonexistent'] was geared to managing an order based on fixed
rates of exchange between currencies that were a recognized means of
payment." Now, in global financial markets, "we are confronted
by an amalgam of currency-finance that is highly mobile and that
combines monetary liquidity with financial profitability. This amalgam
is the result of the merging of the monetary and the financial."
(25) A "new Bretton Woods" would need to retrieve its
predecessor's commitment to economic security and prosperity for
all, and rethink the very meaning of development in today's
financial setting. (26)
3. Needed reforms must target both financial markets'
structure and organization and the behavior of market agents. For
Richard Nielsen, the 2007-2009 economic crisis showcased a new kind of
capitalism, "high-leverage finance." Nielsen considers four
types of high-leverage finance capitalism and their
"structurally-related ethics issues": high-leverage hedge
funds, private equity-leveraged buyouts, high-leverage, subprime
mortgages, and, high-leverage banking; and attendant ethical issues
concerning: harm to others, leverage proportionality and prudence, moral
hazard, transparency, and social control and regulation. (27)
Nielsen pays special attention to private equity, leveraged buy-out
(PELBO) firms, which differ from traditional private equity firms in
three striking ways:
first, high debt leverage instead of high equity investment;
second, relatively short investment/deal horizon (less than five, and
often less than two, years) instead of long-term investment horizon; and
third, how much the PE-LBO firm pays itself in cash dividends, with its
highly leveraged debt rather than using the debt to invest in
business/technology development.
A PE firm invests primarily with its own equity; the PE-LBO firm
borrows most of its investment capital from banks and other financial
institutions. In addition, after the PE-LBO firm acquires a company
(using mostly borrowed money), it greatly increases the acquired
company's debt and often pays itself dividends from most of the
newly borrowed money before reselling the acquired company, thus
creating a sort of "double leverage." (28) Nielsen's
assessment of these firms' behavior in the run-up to the crisis is
stinging: rather than "creating wealth and bettering ourselves and
the world," their actions led to "the massive destruction of
wealth and allowing some to get very rich at the expense of others....
Financial markets have directly and indirectly done enormous harm to
others." (29)
Nielsen cites Michael Jensen, who connects PE-LBO
"value-destroying activities" to a dysfunctional ethos that
stresses short-term, shareholder value-maximization instead of
"long-term value." These conditions heighten "moral
hazard," the temptation for financiers to do wrong. To address
this, Jensen says, "we must give employees and managers a structure
that will help them resist the temptation to maximize the short-term
financial performance... [which] is a sure way to destroy value."
(30) Nielsen perceives another source of moral hazard in a pattern of
"increasingly dangerous, bailout-facilitated bubbles." In
crises since the 1970s, the U.S. Federal Reserve has repeatedly bailed
out financial institutions, their investors, and top managers.
Meanwhile, "ordinary people are, in effect, subsidizing the
bailouts and transferring income and wealth to recapitalize financial
institutions while average incomes are stagnating and declining in real
terms although the incomes of the upper 2% are rising
exponentially." "Are we," Nielsen asks,
facilitating a political economy of 'private profits and
socialized risks'? If we cannot avoid subsidizing, bailing out, and
recapitalizing the financial institutions to some extent at the expense
of ordinary people, at a minimum, we need better and stronger
enforcement and regulations to protect against the recurring,
exponentially negative effects of large, subprime, and often
over-leveraging, bubbles and bailouts. (31)
Nielsen discusses four areas for reform: leverage; compensation;
transparency; and lobbying, cronyism, and campaign finance. He cautions
that if the latter problems are not effectively addressed, other reforms
"may have so many loopholes that they will be ineffective."
And if this new form of capitalism mutates again, with seriously
destructive impacts, "then we may be trying to regulate
yesterday's form of capitalism." In that case regulatory
reform may need to be accompanied with movement toward "a European
social democratic capitalist model" where "there is a large
social safety net of tax- supported health care, pensions, and high
unemployment benefits that can cushion the destructive effects of future
evolutionary forms of capitalism and/ or present forms that prove
politically impossible to regulate effectively." (32)
These authors' critiques align with concerns of Catholic
ethics; they represent varied scholarly efforts to resituate economics
within a more complete-picture treatment of human beings, their
behavior, and their contexts. Their prescriptions emphasize stronger
regulatory and oversight structures; creating intrafirm practices and
ethos that encourage and reward business virtue (Dobson); and
institutionalizing a finance professionalism that foregrounds trust,
honesty, and fiduciary responsibility essential to principal-agent,
contract, and reputational integrity (Sifah). Also consonant with
Catholic ethics, some (Dorrien, Peters, Nielsen) intimate that
addressing the moral issues involved may require radical changes in
political and economic business-as-usual.
THE "REAL ECONOMY": WORK, WAGES, AND EMPLOYMENT
Descending from the nebula of global finance, we see people working
to provide for themselves and their families. Work, workers, and work
justice are subjects close to the heart of the modern Catholic social
tradition, which envisions a successful economy as one that makes
available to workers and families a decent livelihood, through dignified
work performed under just material, social, and temporal conditions.
This standard throws into troubling relief four features of the
post-1973 landscape: growing sectors of low-wage work in a polarizing
job market, significant levels of unemployment and underemployment, vast
numbers living in poverty, and increasing income and wealth disparities.
While these economic woes touch every country, they disproportionately
affect those with fewer resources and greater physical or social
vulnerability. The current recession has exacerbated these factors, but
they are arguably "normal" side-products of current market
structure and practice. Faced with this evidence, Catholic ethics'
solidary commitments press questions about how to improve working
families' circumstances under present market arrangements, and
about more radical changes that justice may demand.
Unemployment/Underemployment
Ascendant market orthodoxy envisages the healthy economy as a high
productivity/low unemployment machine that churns out jobs, profits, and
choices for all. This "U.S. model" also presumes, and norms,
low unionization, lower minimum wages, less generous social benefits,
and lower taxes. (33) Even at its healthiest, this model assumes 5%
unemployment (its official definition of "full employment")
and depends on nonmarket sectors to provide safety nets for the jobless.
Prior to 2008, indeed since the early 1970s, bellwether symptoms of
problems in this model, especially its impacts on nonelite workers, had
been accumulating. (34) Globally, (35) aggregate (though unevenly
shared) economic growth in the early 2000s ended in 2009 with the onset
of recession. The International Labor Organization (ILO) reports that
the crisis is exacerbating chronic wage-related problems, especially
"the global imbalance in the pre-crisis distribution of profits and
wages" and growing wage inequality.
Increasing profits prior to the crisis have contributed to high
levels of liquidity on financial markets and low rates of interest,
while stagnating real wages relative to productivity gains--together
with growing wage inequality--have limited the ability of most
households to increase consumption other than through debt.
This combination provided incentives for unsustainable consumption
patterns by over-indebted households, including through sub-prime
lending of the kind that has fed the housing bubble in the U.S. (36)
The global crisis highlights a further problem, the "failure
of unrestricted markets to set appropriate executive pay. Malfunctioning
pay systems and excessive bonuses have distorted the incentive structure
in the financial sector, encouraging risk-taking and short-term profits
rather than sustained company performance." In both high finance
and local communities, "unhealthy incentive structures" bred
patterns that led to value-destruction for business, the economy, and
especially to vulnerable households and around the world. (37)
In the United States, these negative effects are evident in
statistics on employment and wages released in September 2010 (38): 7.6
million jobs lost since the start of the recession (including 2 million
manufacturing and 1.9 million--one in four--construction jobs); 14.9
million unemployed (up from 7.7 million in December 2007), with 42% of
these unemployed for over six months, 21% jobless for more than a year;
an additional 11 million underemployed, marginally attached and
involuntary part-time workers; an overall, but racially- and
geographically-skewed (39) unemployment rate of 9.6% (whites 8.7%,
blacks 16.3%, Hispanics 12%, Native Americans 15.2%). (40) Growth in
productivity between 2000 and 2007 was accompanied by a slight decrease
in median compensation during that same period. By October 2010,
unemployment was unchanged; job creation was increasing but at a pace
that would put a return to "full employment" (5 % unemployment
rate of December 2007) twenty years out. (41) Not surprisingly, poverty
rates are also rising. (42)
Philip Swagel summarizes experts' consensus: "The
financial crisis of 2007 to 2010 has had a massive impact on the United
States. Millions of American families suffered losses of jobs, incomes,
and homes--and the effects of these losses will play out on society for
generations to come." (43) But the pain will not be distributed
equally. Those least able to buffer these losses--who struggle with
fewer resources, (44) lower incomes, (45) and unemployment at
"permanent recession" (46) rates--continue to be hurt
disproportionately.
New work in business ethics (47) and social economics offers
scaffolding for Catholic arguments on behalf of worker justice; recent
analyses of unemployment in capitalist markets offer a case in point.
Economist Persefoni Tsaliki argues that in currently existing
capitalism, "unemployment is a systemic element of economic
development which need not and "normally" does not give rise
to full employment of labor regardless of the flexibility in labor
markets." Market dynamics continually produce "a stream of
displaced workers," and the drive for "labor flexibility"
has accelerated "the polarization of income distribution and the
poverty rate." If, Tsaliki contends, "the normal functioning
of capitalism is consistent with a [high or] rising unemployment
rate," robust policies are required to address unemployment and its
adverse personal and social effects. (48)
Jon Wisman builds an economic and ethical case for such policies,
specifically, government's obligation to serve as employer of last
resort (ELR). (49) Despite demonstrably high costs of unemployment to
its victims and to society, current economic orthodoxy assumes and
tolerates "a short-run trade-off between unemployment and
inflation." (50) A cruel utilitarian calculus dictates that
"the well-being of some portion of the population-- predominantly
the least privileged--must be sacrificed for the good of the
whole." For Wisman, this amounts to an immoral and socially
irrational "tyranny of the overwhelming majority," where
"the job of fighting inflation.., is horribly disproportionately
shared and is mostly put on the backs of those who have no market power
to cause wage inflation in the first place." (51)
Twenty-first-century markets require a new model, responsive to
"the ever-quickened pace of capitalism that not only increases
'churn' or the frequency with which workers lose their jobs,
but also renders old skills obsolete or inadequate." Wisman
outlines a plan to socially guarantee employment: government as ELR
would provide work, minimal economic security, and opportunities for
"life-long education and retraining." (52) In the United
States, creating jobs in the midst of a major recession seems especially
urgent, and jobs directed toward repairing aging infrastructure or
advancing ecological sustainability hold obvious appeal. (53) Is the
difficulty government leadership has encountered in getting traction for
widespread job-creation plans testimony to the power of reigning
economic orthodoxy?
Income Inequality via Labor Market Dualism and Segmentation
While rejecting communistic egalitarianism as a universal social
ideal, modern CST has consistently deemed large disparities in income or
wealth detrimental to social cohesion and the common good. (54) Trends
in U.S. labor markets over the past two decades confirm a movement
toward "market dualism" wherein jobs increasingly cluster at
very high or very low ends of the wage scale, (55) compounded by the
persistence of historical and newer forms of labor market segmentation,
(56) whereby certain groups (e.g., nonwhites, women, new immigrants) are
relegated disproportionately to lower-paying and lower-status job
categories. Both in the United States and globally, wealth and income
inequalities have increased steeply over this same period. (57)
Minimum and Living Wages
Since the 19th century, CST and "social Catholics" have
been vocal advocates for workers' rights to a decent livelihood by
way of a "living wage." In the United States, the work and
activism of Msgr. John A. Ryan and strong Catholic presence in the union
movement ensured this Catholic principle a public face. Dormant in the
1970s and 1980s, public discourse about "living wages"
reemerged in campaigns to ensure more-than-minimum hourly pay for
city-contracted workers, first in Baltimore and eventually in scores of
cities across the nation. (58)
Examining how "framing" helps present-day living-wage
ordinance campaigns fuel movements for political change, Christian
ethicist Melissa Snarr argues that appeals to "social equity
liberalism" enable living-wage activists "to challenge current
market inequities without denying the deep cultural affinity most
Americans have for neoclassical economics." (59) Social equity
liberalism accepts capitalist markets as the mechanism to promote
prosperity and wealth but maintains that "government must also
occasionally stimulate the economy to ensure its health and help those
at the lower rungs of society." In a sluggish economy, this view
contends, increasing wages for lower and middle classes both helps
working families and helps to jump-start the economy.
Using economic arguments drawn from "Keynesian cultural
residue," living wage spokespersons evoke support precisely by not
calling economic orthodoxy into direct question. Living-wage movements
gain adherents "in part because their proposals still embrace the
larger neoclassical claim that economic growth enables individual
freedom and flourishing." While rejecting neoliberalism's
"absolutist individual freedom," the living wage agenda
"relies heavily on the assumptions and positive evaluation of the
relatively independent capitalist market of neoclassical economic theory
and its goal of independent economic freedom. It is still a job that
should lift you out of poverty (not keep you in it) and it is still
economic independence (from government) that is the telos of a living
wage." (60)
Snarr's analysis is suggestive for Catholics pondering the
disconnect between their Church's rich social justice rhetoric, and
Catholic citizens' spotty engagement in justice movements. U.S.
Catholics may benefit from reflecting on how "the delicate work of
framing public religious ethics" can work to stimulate (or dampen)
action in support of change. (61) Snarr concludes with appreciation:
"Drawing both on moral and economic frames, the living wage
movement enables citizens to have a voice in the economy beyond
consumerism. Enhancing citizens' sense of their economic moral
agency lays the foundation for further analyses and action for worker
justice and flourishing." (62)
The contemporary living wage movement has its limitations. Living
wage ordinances only cover small numbers of municipal workers; arguably,
throwing political support behind increased federal or state minimum
wages would yield greater benefits for low-income families. Economist
Heidi Schierholz, for instance, advocates a federally mandated,
long-term fix of the minimum wage that would index it annually at 50% of
the average annual wage for nonsupervisory workers. (63) Economic
orthodoxy holds that mandating higher wages inevitably causes higher
unemployment; this claim has been disproven by careful studies in the
wake of previous hikes in minimum wages, but the conviction is popular
and tenacious. (64)
SOLIDARITY, SUSTAINABILITY
The recent financial crisis and subsequent recession have evoked,
as never before, a public language and imagery of interdependence.
Global technological connectivity via communications and computers has
facilitated the web of monetary and institutional interdependencies that
is the financial market, multiplying the impacts of recent economic
events. The fact that economic transactions occurring across the world
and "over the heads" of ordinary people could so literally
"hit home" has been, for those millions affected, viscerally
educative.
From a Catholic ethical perspective, global crisis and hardship
underscores the "explosion of worldwide interdependence" or
"de facto solidarities" within which the human community is
enmeshed. Acknowledging these connections invites a further step to
solidarity, the human, and Christian habitus of loving dedication to
advancing the good of each and all. (65)
To enact economic solidarity means to move beyond what philosopher
Sally Scholz calls general "human solidarity," or cheap,
sentimental "parasitic solidarity," to engaging in deliberate
"political solidarities" by taking stands and risking
suffering on behalf of justice for the vulnerable. (66) Pursuing
economic solidarity also demands that two vast sectors (which I can only
mention here), historically excluded from the purview of mainstream
economics, be incorporated into ethical deliberation: the "care
economy" and the "earth economy." Together, these sectors
comprise crucial conditions of sustainability upon which market
economies, and indeed, human material survival and flourishing, depend.
Care and earth economies are receiving specific attention in the
nascent fields of feminist and ecological economics. Feminist economics
understands economy as the multivalent process of material and social
provisioning in which market exchange plays only one part. Debra Figart
observes: "Social provisioning as a lens for viewing economic
activity changes the subject of economics by asking different questions
than does mainstream economics. It also suggests different answers to
questions that mainstream economics already addresses." (67)
Feminist economists further hold that ethical judgments are endemic to
economic analysis; that nonmarket provisioning processes, including
caring labor and domestic labor, are central, not peripheral, to
understanding economic life; and that adequate economic analysis attends
to diverse and power-asymmetrical particularities among individuals and
groups, rather than proceeding according to abstract models or laws.
(68)
Feminist economics seeks to accurately and justly relate care and
market economies; ecological economics works to connect market and
natural economies by reframing market theory and practice in light of
the finitude, noncommodifiability, or nonsubstitutability (by capital or
technology) of land, biota, biosphere, and natural resources. (69) For
ecological economists, facing limits to growth relative to
economy's "containing, sustaining ecosystem" (70) entails
asking moral questions concerning the fair distribution of natural and
economic wealth. Brian Czech writes:
If the tide of the global economy can rise only so far, then only a
limited fleet may be accommodated. In ecological economics, economic
justice is not about trying to defy the laws of physics by raising the
tide past the realm of possibility, but rather ensuring that tiny,
law-abiding boats are not capsized in the wakes of hulking luxury
liners, (71)
Here Catholic commitments to solidarity with the poor and a decent
livelihood for all complement the commitments of ecological economists.
Adumbrating a major challenge Catholic economic ethics must also
face, (72) Czech concludes with this (under)statement: "Ecological
economics faces numerous challenges stemming primarily from the
political difficulties entailed by a critical analysis of economic
growth as a policy goal." (73) His colleague, Peter Soderbaum,
concurs:
Neoclassical economics plays an important role in the mental maps
of many influential actors such as politicians, business leaders and
university professors. And neoclassical economics in the form of
neoclassical environmental economics has a role also in relation to
present challenges of Sustainable Development. But neoclassical
economics is not enough. (74)
(1) Pope Benedict XVI, Caritas in veritate (June 29, 2009) no. 6.
(2) Ibid. nos. 6-7, 53-58.
(3) Ibid. no. 37.
(4) Ibid. nos. 30, 36, 37.
(5) See Christine Firer Hinze, "Social and Economic
Ethics," Theological Studies 70 (2009) 159-76.
(6) See Kathryn Tanner, "Is Capitalism a Belief System?"
Anglican Theological Review 92 (2010) 617-36; Rowan Williams,
"Theology and Economics: Two Different Worlds?" ibid. 607-16.
(7) Julie Nelson, Economics for Humans (Chicago: University of
Chicago, 2006) 52-57, at 54. Jonathan Aldred, The Skeptical Economist:
Revealing the Ethics inside Economics (London: Earthscan, 2009) 2-4,
connects market orthodoxy to "black box" and "veto"
economics.
(8) Robert E. Lane, The Market Experience (New York: Cambridge
University, 1991).
(9) Ibid. 600-601.
(10) In a WBD society, markets will still exist, but institutions,
Lane cautions, "are not infinitely malleable" (ibid. 610).
Whether existing market institutions could absorb the changes demanded
by a WBD axial rotation remains an open question.
(11) Ibid. 602, 609, 603.
(12) Rebecca Todd Peters, In Search of the Good Life: The Ethics of
Globalization (New York: Continuum, 2003).
(13) Daniel K. Finn, The Moral Ecology of Markets: Assessing Claims
about Markets and Justice (New York: Cambridge University, 2006) 143.
"An awareness of the interplay of markets and their contexts is
critical for understanding under what conditions the outcomes of
voluntary actions of individuals and businesses in the market will be
considered just.... The exertion of self-interest in economic life can
receive conditional moral approval and can lead to just outcomes, but
only "if markets have been properly defined by law, if essential
goods and services are provided, if the morality of individuals and
groups is apparent, and if there exists a vibrant civil society"
(ibid. 145).
(14) Daniel K. Finn, ed., The True Wealth of Nations: Catholic
Social Thought and Economic Life (New York: Oxford University, 2010)
3-4.
(15) In his "Power and Public Presence in Catholic Social
Thought, the Church, and the CTSA, Proceedings of the Catholic
Theological Society of America 63 (2007) 62-77, Finn addresses
Catholics' need to cultivate better understandings of power.
(16) Gary Dorrien, "Turbo-Capitalism, Economic Crisis, and
Economic Democracy," Anglican Theological Review 92 (2010) 649-57,
at 650.
(17) John Dobson, Finance Ethics: The Rationality of Virtue
(Lanham, Md.: Rowman & Littlefield, 1997); see also Helen Alford,
review of Finance Ethics, Oikonomia: Journal of Ethics and Social
Sciences 1.0 (January 1999),
http://www.oikonomia.it/pages/genn/recensione.htm (this and all other
URLs herein cited were accessed on December 2, 2010).
(18) Dobson, Finance Ethics 1, 7.
(19) Alford, review of Finance Ethics; see Dobson, Finance Ethics,
chaps. 1-3.
(20) David Sifah, "Ethics: An Essential Prerequisite of the
Financial System," Finance & the Common Good/Bien Commun 33
(2009) 46-57, at 47. See also Paul H. Dembinski and Francois-Marie
Monnet, "When Loyalty Conflicts with Interest," Finance &
the Common Good/Bien Commun 34-35 (2009) 29-31.
(21) John Mixon, "Neoclassical Economics and the Erosion of
Middle-Class Values: An Explanation for Economic Collapse," Notre
Dame Journal of Law, Ethics, and Public Policy 24 (2010) 327-66, at 327,
377-78; see Dobson, Finance Ethics 92- 94; Joel Amernic and Russell
Craig, "Accounting as a Facilitator of Extreme Narcissism,"
Journal of Business Ethics 96 (2010) 79-93; and the Post-Autistic
Economics Network website at
http://www.paecon.net/PAEmovementindexl.htm.
(22) Paul A. David, "May 6th: Signals from a Very Brief but
Emblematic Catastrophe on Wall Street," real-world economics review
53 (June 26, 2010) 2-27, at 27,
http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue53/David53.pdf. See Paul Dembinski,
"Very Large Enterprises, Financial Markets and Global Value
Chains," Finance & the Common Good/Bien Commun 34-35 (2009)
136-41.
(23) Ross A. Hammond, "Systemic Risk in the Financial System:
Insights from Network Science," Pew Financial Reform Project,
Briefing Paper #12 (2009) 1-6,
http://fic.wharton.upenn.edu/fic/Policy%20page/EP_HammondNetworks_final_TF_ Correction.pdf.
(24) Etienne Perrot, "Le risque au coeur de l'ethique
financiere," Finance & the Common Good/Bien Commun 31-32 (2008)
119-28.
(25) Paul Dembinski, "Requiem for a Defunct System,"
Finance & the Common Good/Bien Commun 34-35 (2009) 5-12, at 8.
(26) Ibid. 12.
(27) Richard Nielsen, "High-Leverage Finance Capitalism, the
Economic Crisis, Structurally Related Ethics Issues, and Potential
Reforms," Business Ethics Quarterly 20 (2010) 299-330.
(28) Ibid. 303-4. This was sustainable "as long as things went
well, profits increased, and inexpensive refinancing was
available." But when the economy faltered, many acquired companies
went bankrupt. "Since banks made most of the loans to PE-LBO firms,
this contributed greatly to the banks' enormous bad loan losses.
Banks have more subprime PE-LBO loans than subprime mortgage loans"
(ibid. 304).
(29) Ibid. 300, 312.
(30) Ibid. 319, quoting Michael C. Jensen, "Value
Maximization, Stakeholder Theory, and the Corporate Objective
Function," Business Ethics Quarterly 12 (2002) 235-56, at 245.
(31) Nielsen, "High-Leverage Finance" 315.
(32) Ibid. 317-24, 325-26.
(33) Lawrence R. Mishel, Jared Bernstein, Sylvia A. Allegretto, The
State of Working America 2006/2007 (Ithaca, N.Y.: ILR of Cornell
University, 2007) 357-58. By contrast, see Gregory Baum, "The
Social Economy: An Alternative Model of Economic Development,"
Journal of Catholic Social Thought 6 (2009) 253-62.
(34) In the early 2000s, wages stagnated and real median family
income fell, while the gap between income and productivity growth
increased. Mishel, et al., State of Working America 1-15. On
deteriorating workforce conditions, see Barbara Hilkert Andolsen's
typically astute The New Job Contract: Employment a Global Economy
(Cleveland: Pilgrim, 1998).
(35) "Global Wage Report: Update 2009," ILO (Geneva:
2009) 1-2, http://www.docstoc.com/docs/44165758/Global-Wage-Report. See
Joseph Stiglitz, "The Global Crisis, Social Protection and
Jobs," International Labour Review 148 (2009) 1- 13, at 1-2; ILO, A
Global Policy Package to Address the Global Crisis, Policy Brief,
International Institute for Labour Studies (Geneva, 2008) 2,
http://www.ilo.org/ public/libdoc/ilo/2008/108B09_307_engl.pdf.
(36) ILO, "Global Wage Report 2009" 1.
(37) Ibid. 2.
(38) Anna Turner, "Labor Day by the Numbers," Economic
Policy Institute, September 3, 2010,
http://www.epi.org/publications/entry/labor_day_by_the_numbers1.
(39) Detroit tragically exemplifies the "old-news" nature
of these problems for many. See Gloria Albrecht, "Detroit: Still
the 'Other' America," Journal of the Society of Christian
Ethics 29 (2009) 3-24; Michigan League for Human Services, "Labor
Day Report: Long-Term Unemployment Is at Crisis Level" (Lansing,
Mich.: September, 2010),
http://www.milhs.org/wp-content/uploads/2010/07/LaborDayReport2010.pdf.
(40) Between June 2007 and June 2010, the American Indian
unemployment rate nationally increased 7.7 percentage points to 15.2%,
an increase 1.6 times that for whites. Algernon Austin, "Different
Race, Different Recession: American Indian Unemployment in 2010,"
Economic Policy Institute, Issue Brief #289, November 18, 2010,
http://epi.3cdn.net/94a339472e6481485e_hgm6bxpz4.pdf.
(41) Heidi Shierholz, "Job Growth Improves, but Pace Leaves
Full Employment 20 Years Away," Economic Policy Institute, November
5, 2010, http://www.epi.org/publications/entry/ job_growth_improves_but
pace_leaves_full_employment 20 years away.
(42) Emily Monea and Isabel V. Sawhill, "An Update to
'Simulating the Effect of the 'Great Recession' on
Poverty,'" Brookings Center on Children and Families
Report, September 16, 2010,
http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/Files/rc/papers/
2010/0916_poverty_monea_sawhill/0916_poverty_monea_sawhill.pdf.
(43) Phillip Swagel, "The Cost of the Financial Crisis: The
Impact of the September 2008 Economic Collapse," Pew Financial
Reform Project, Briefing Paper #18, April 28, 2010, 1-19, at 18,
http://www.pewtrusts.org/uploadedFiles/wwwpewtrustsorg/Reports/
Economic_Mobility/Cost-of-the-Crisis-final.pdf?n=6727.
(44) Significant differentials in assets and wealth between U.S.
racial groups com pound the vulnerability of blacks, Hispanics, and
Native Americans during times of high unemployment. Algernon Austin
stresses "the crucial link between poverty and lack of jobs"
at decent wages, in "Three Lessons about Black Poverty,"
Economic Policy Institute, September 18, 2009,
http://www.epi.org/analysis_and_ opinion/entry/the lessons of black
poverty/.
(45) Racial wages and labor-market-penalties continue. See, e.g.,
Gregory Acs and Pamela J. Loprest, "Working for Cents on the
Dollar: Racial and Ethnic Wage Gaps in the Noncollege Labor
Market," Urban Institute, March 2009,
http://www.urban.org/publications/411856.html.
(46) A January 2009 Applied Research Center Report shows that over
a 37-year period, unemployment for people of color rarely fell below
even the highest recession-level rates of white unemployment. Black
unemployment was at least double that of whites for all but five of
those years. Latinos were 1.5 times more likely to be unemployed than
whites for 28 out of 37 years. Seth Wexler, "Race and Recession:
Report 2009," Applied Research Institute Report, January 2009,
http:// arc.org/downloads/2009_race_recession_0909.pdf. See Jennifer
Wheary, Thomas M. Shapiro, and Tatjana Meschede, "The Downslide
before the Downturn: Declining Economic Security among Middle-Class
African Americans and Latinos, 2000-2006,"
http://iasp.brandeis.edu/pdfs/batfive.pdf; Jennifer Wheary, Thomas M.
Shapiro, and Tamara Draudt, "By a Thread: The New Experience of
America's Middle Class," Demos/Institute for Assets and Policy
Studies, 2007, http://www. demos.org/pubs/BaT112807.pdf.
(47) For a fine example, see Jeremy Snyder, "Exploitation and
Sweatshop Labor: Perspectives and Issues," Business Ethics
Quarterly 20 (2010) 187-213.
(48) Persefoni V. Tsaliki, "Economic Development and
Unemployment: Do They Connect?" International Journal of Social
Economics 36 (2009) 773-81. See William S. Vickery, "Chock-Full
Employment without Increased Inflation," American Economic Review
82 (1992) 341-45.
(49) Jon D. Wisman, "The Moral Imperative and Social
Rationality of Government- Guaranteed Employment and Reskilling,"
Review of Social Economy 68 (2010) 35-67.
(50) Ibid. 39.
(51) Ibid. 39-40.
(52) Ibid, 49-57, 60.
(53) See, e.g., Robert Pollin and Dean Baker,
"Reindustrializing America: A Proposal for Reviving U.S.
Manufacturing and Creating Millions of Good Jobs," New Labor Forum
19.2 (April 2010) 16-34.
(54) E.g., Benedict XVI, Caritas in veritate no. 32; and Paul VI,
Populorum progressio no. 33.
(55) David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney,
"The Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market," American Economic
Review 96 (2006) 189-94; Claudia Dale Goldin and Lawrence F. Katz,
"Long-Run Changes in the Wage Structure: Narrowing, Widening,
Polarizing," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (2007) 135-65.
"The returns to abstract skills from college and post-college
training are likely to remain high, and demand is likely to grow for the
interpersonal (soft) skills needed for in-person services .... U.S.
education and training systems must be better positioned to rapidly
increase the supply of workers with abstract and interpersonal skills. A
complementary approach to reducing labor market inequities might involve
trying to 'professionalize' the growing workforce of in-person
service workers and to develop labor market institutions to enhance
their bargaining clout" (ibid. 162).
(56) Lesley Williams Reid and Beth A. Rubin, "Integrating
Economic Dualism and Labor Market Segmentation: The Effects of Race,
Gender, and Structural Location on Earnings, 1974-2000, Sociological
Quarterly 44 (2003) 405-32. Between 1974 and 2000, while "white men
have experienced the greatest declines in employment and earnings, they
have maintained their absolute advantage over women and nonwhites,"
and despite real gains, "women and racial minorities remain
over-represented in low-paying jobs," with women (but not nonwhite
men) receiving "consistently fewer rewards for their labor in both
low-paying and high-paying jobs" (ibid. 405). Kenneth Hudson,
"The New Labor Market Segmentation: Labor Market Dualism in the New
Economy," Social Science Research 36 (2007) 286-312, presents
evidence that supports the "new labor market segmentation thesis:
"As the practice of allocating workers to inferior jobs on the
basis of race and sex has declined, employers have turned to nonstandard
work arrangements and immigrants to supply labor for low-wage jobs"
(ibid. 286).
(57) See, e.g., G. William Domhoff, "Wealth, Income, and
Power," Who Rules America? (2005; updated 2010),
http://sociology.ucsc.edu/whorulesamerica/power/ wealth.html.
(58) See Robert Pollin et al., A Measure of Fairness: The Economics
of Living Wages and Minimum Wages in the United States (Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University, 2008); and research on living wages by the Political
Economy Research Institute, http://www.peri.umass.edu/207/; Jeroen Merk
and Celia Mather, Stitching a Decent Wage across Borders: The Asia Wage
Floor Proposal (New Delhi: Asia Wage Alliance, 2009).
(59) C. Melissa Snarr, "Waging Religious Ethics: Living Wages
and Framing Public Religious Ethics," Journal of the Society of
Christian Ethics 29 (2009) 69-86, at 80-81.
(60) Ibid. 81.
(61) See Marvin Mich's study of Catholics' ambivalent
engagement in living wage ordinance campaigns: "The Living Wage
Movement and Catholic Social Teaching," Journal of Catholic Social
Thought 6 (2009) 231-52.
(62) Snarr, "Waging Religious Ethics" 84.
(63) Heidi Schierholz, "Fix It and Forget It: Index the
Minimum Wage to Growth in Average Wages," Economic Policy Institute
Briefing Paper #251, December 17, 2009,
http://epi.3cdn.net/91fd33f4e013307415_rum6iydua.pdf; see also Heather
Boushey and Shawn Bermstad, "The Wages of Exclusion: Low-Wage Work
and Inequality," New Labor Forum 17.2 (Summer 2008) 9-19. Favoring
nonfederal solutions is Andrew Abela, "Subsidiarity and the Just
Wage: Implications of Catholic Social Teaching for the Minimum-Wage
Debate," Journal of Markets and Morality 12.1 (Spring 2009) 7-17.
(64) See, e.g., David Neumark, "Living Wages: Protection For
or Protection From Low-Wage Workers?" Industrial and Labor
Relations Review 58 (2004) 27-51; and responses to Neumark in Pollin et
al., Measure of Fairness, part 5.
(65) Caritas in veritate no. 33; see John Paul II, Sollitudo rei
socialis nos. 38-40.
(66) Sally J. Scholz, Political Solidarity (University Park:
Pennsylvania State University) insightfully parses solidarity's
diverse forms and includes CST in its purview.
(67) Debra Figart, "Social Responsibility for Living
Standards," Review of Social Economy 65 (2007) 391--405, at 395.
See also Ingeborg Wick, "Women Working in the Shadows: The Informal
Economy and Export Processing Zones," Siidwind e.V.-Institut for
Okonomie und Okumene, 2010, http://www.suedwind-institut.de/
downloads/2010-03 SW Women-Working-in-the-Shadows.pdf.
(68) Figart, "Living Standards 394-95. See also Maylin
Biggadike, "An Eco- Feminist Response to the True Wealth
Project," in True Wealth 31940. Brian Czech, "Ecological
Economics," in Animal and Plant Productivity, ed. Robert J. Hudson,
in Encyclopedia of Life Support Systems (EOLSS), Eolss Publishers,
Oxford, UK (2009) 10, http://steadystate.org/wp- content/uploads/
Czech_Ecological_Economics.pdf.
(70) Ibid. 2. See Herman E. Daly and Joshua Farley, Ecological
Economics, 2nd ed. (Washington: Island, 2011).
(71) Ibid. 21.
(72) See Benedict XVI, Caritas in veritate nos. 48-51; Lucia A.
Silecchia, "Discerning the Environmental Perspective of Pope
Benedict XVI," Journal of Catholic Social Thought 4 (2007) 227-69;
Walter E. Grazer, "Catholic Social Teaching and the Environment
Pastoral Challenge and Strategy," ibid. 211-25; and Woodeene
Koenig-Bricker, Ten Commandments for the Environment: Pope Benedict XVI
Speaks Out for Creation and Justice (Notre Dame, Ind: Ave Maria, 2009).
(73) Czech, "Ecological Economics" 18.
(74) Peter Soderbaum, "Politics and Ideology in Ecological
Economics," Internet Encyclopedia of Ecological Economics
(September 2004) 2, http://www.ecoeco.org/pdf/politics_ideology.pdf.
CHRISTINE FIRER HINZE received her Ph.D. from the University of
Chicago and is professor of Christian ethics and director of the Francis
and Ann Curran Center of American Catholic Studies at Fordham
University. Her areas of special interest are Christian social ethics,
Catholic social thought, and topics in economy, work, gender, and
family. Her recent publications include: "The Drama of Social Sin
and the [Im]Possibility of Solidarity: Reinhold Niebuhr and Catholic
Social Thought," Studies in Christian Ethics 22.4 (2009); and
"Reconsidering Little Rock: Hannah Arendt, Martin Luther King, Jr.,
and Families' Role in the Struggle for Justice," Journal of
the Society of Christian Ethics 29.1 (2009). In progress is a monograph
entitled "Radical Sufficiency: The Legacy and Future of the
Catholic Living Wage Agenda"; and a case-based study of solidary
civic engagement among contemporary U.S. Catholics sponsored by the
Democracy, Culture, and Catholicism International Research Project,
Loyola University Chicago.