The politics of institutional change in Venezuela: oil policy during the presidency of Hugo Chavez.
Wiseman, Colin ; Beland, Daniel
In December of 1998, Hugo Chavez was elected President of Venezuela
with 58% of the vote. Promising to increase social spending and reduce
state corruption, a major target of his campaign was Venezuela's
large state-owned oil company, PDVSA. Along with many other presidential
candidates, Chavez criticized PDVSA, calling it a "black box"
that operated as a "state within a state," making oil policy
decisions without concern for the Venezuelan population (Chavez 2005).
Clearly, it was time for a change. But just how would that change be
achieved? Was PDVSA strong enough to resist the influence of Chavez and
maintain its institutional autonomy and neoliberal oil policies?
The goal of this study is to explain institutional change in PDVSA
and Venezuelan oil policy since the election of Hugo Chavez. Drawing on
institutionalist theory, we argue that although PDVSA's
organizational culture represented a powerful obstacle to reform, a
growing contradiction between PDVSA culture and widely held societal
beliefs created a legitimacy problem that Chavez exploited to undermine
PDVSA's traditional power. We will show how this legitimacy issue
meshed with class politics to bring about comprehensive institutional
change in Venezuelan oil policy. Empirically, this article draws on 21
semi-structured interviews conducted in 2006 with actors involved in
Venezuelan oil policy.
The article begins with a historical discussion about the
development of PDVSA and Venezuelan oil policy and its impact on
contemporary oil politics. Then, drawing heavily on interview data, the
article discusses issues of legitimacy and organizational culture as
potential sources of institutional change within PDVSA. Lastly, the
article addresses further political factors as they relate to change in
Venezuelan oil policy before concluding that a claim to cultural
legitimacy was an important variable in Chavez's achievement of
significant institutional change.
Historical Background and Analytical Puzzle
In December 1998, Hugo Chavez was elected president of Venezuela
with 58% of the vote. Promising to increase social spending and reduce
state corruption, he made Venezuela's large state-owned oil
company, PDVSA, a major target of his campaign. Chavez, along with many
other presidential candidates, criticized PDVSA, calling it a
"black box" that operated as a "state within a
state," making oil policy decisions without concern for the
Venezuelan population (Chavez 2005). Clearly, it was a time for a
change. But just how would that change be achieved? Was PDVSA strong
enough to resist the influence of Chavez and maintain its institutional
autonomy and neoliberal oil policies? The goal of this study is to
explain institutional change in PDVSA and Venezuelan oil policy since
the election of Hugo Chavez.
Concessions to produce oil in Venezuela were first granted in the
late 1800s, but it was not until 1919 that exportation began. The first
Venezuelan oil policies provided favourable conditions for foreign
companies to operate in the country. However, a growing democratic
movement throughout the first half of the century pushed not only for
the right to democratically elect a president, but also for the
sovereign right of every Venezuelan person to the value derived from its
national subsoil in the form of petroleum revenues (Betancourt 1978;
Coronel 1983; Coronil 1997). Thus, incremental increases in royalties
were the norm in the mid 1900s as a popular movement pushed for
increased governmental control over Venezuela's oil resources.
Venezuela became a stable democracy in 1958, and by 1976 the Ley de
Nacionalizacion del Petroleo (Petroleum Nationalization Law) transferred
ownership of all oil production within the country's borders to the
state. Nevertheless, oil nationalization in Venezuelan was not as
radical as it could have been. Rather, corporate structures that existed
prior to nationalization were maintained while Article 5 of the
Nationalization Law left room for foreign involvement in the Venezuelan
oil industry as long as it was deemed to be in the interest of the
Venezuelan state. PDVSA had been created as a semi-autonomous company
charged with providing revenues for state social and economic programs.
It was owned by the state, but its operations were carried out by former
employees of the oil multinationals that controlled Venezuelan oil
production prior to nationalization. Therefore, "at midnight,
December 31, 1975, the ownership (of oil production in Venezuela)
changed, the labels changed, everything changed, and nothing changed at
the same time" (Francisco, personal interview, October 2006). The
culture and structure of multinational oil conglomerates was maintained.
In the 1980s, PDVSA embarked on a policy of
"internationalization" by expanding its operations overseas
and buying into foreign refining and distribution plants such as Veba
Oel in Germany and Citgo in the United States. (1) PDVSA continued to
build corporate strength and was increasingly a source of stability and
power in an otherwise disorganized and weakening Venezuelan state. By
the mid 1990s, under its president, Luis Giusti, PDVSA received approval
to pursue the apertura or "Oil Opening" policy and, in a move
that altered the course of Venezuelan oil policy, lowered royalties and
invited foreign capital back into Venezuela. In fact, by 1997, the
apertura "called for partial privatization of PDVSA's
activities" and the "first steps towards privatization of the
domestic distribution and retailing of oil products" (Giusti 1999,
118). Ironically, a company that had been created as a way of returning
control of the oil industry to the state was leading the push toward
privatizing the Venezuelan oil industry once again. It was the apertura
policy and its low royalties, portrayed by many as against the
"national interest," which came under fire during the 1998
Venezuelan presidential campaign. Chavez's campaign "played on
a popular discontent with the status quo" (Roberts 2003, 67),
promising to clean up corruption in the government and redesign the
Venezuelan political system. Furthermore, and important to the
discussion at hand, Chavez promised to "subordinate PDVSA to the
Venezuelan state" (Rohter 1999, C1).
While Chavez created a new constitution and increased social
spending through a fragmented network of social programs known as
Misiones Bolivarianos (Bolivarian Missions), Venezuelan oil policy and
PDVSA remained largely unchanged. In 2001, however, Chavez passed a
group of 49 laws by decree that increased state involvement in the
Venezuelan economy and society. Significantly, one of these laws amended
the hydrocarbons policy and called for a return to high royalties and
majority ownership for the state over all oil production in Venezuela. A
growing opposition movement viewed the 49 laws as contradictory to the
economic creed of its mostly middle and upper class members: a market
economy free of political interference. In December 2001, amidst growing
tensions between PDVSA's board of directors and Chavez, a 12-hour
strike involving members of the Confederacion de Trabajadores de
Venezuela (CTV; the Venezuelan Workers Association), the Venezuelan
Chamber of Commerce (FEDECAMARAS), and independent business owners
signified the first wave of widespread organized protest against the
Chavez administration. In April 2002, a small PDVSA managerial strike
and the firing of a handful of managers was immediately followed by a
failed military coup, which took place on the 11th. By 2 December of the
same year, an indefinite nationwide general strike was called in which
PDVSA played an important role, shutting down the majority of oil
operations and exportation from the country. Following a series of
events (see Table 1) that served to escalate the severity of the strike
within PDVSA, such as the use of violence against striking employees and
the firing of several dozen prominent managers who had joined the
strike, PDVSA--under the guidance of the small faction of Chavez
supporters who had not gone on strike--pursued a Supreme Court decision
that on 19 December allowed them to fire striking workers. By February
2003, at least 18,000 workers (almost half of PDVSA employees and most
of its managers) had been fired and the company was brought under the
control of the Chavez government.
The fact that Chavez gained control over PDVSA did not, however,
solve all of the problems faced by his government. As stated by Carlos
Baena, "Government dependence on oil revenues has characterized the
country's democratic period ... Nowhere in Latin America ... is a
government as dependent on one sector as is Venezuela on its oil
sector" (Baena 1999, 18). With increasing world oil prices during
the Chavez era, the government relied on oil revenues more than ever. In
fact, by the second week of the strike, PDVSA oil production had dipped
to just 400,000 barrels per day from 3.2 million barrels per day before
the strike, resulting in losses close to US$40 million per day (ACAN-EFE
2002). The country was crippled economically and would face the worst
recession that it had seen for 50 years (Salmeron 2003), with a 9.2%
decrease in GDP in 2003 alone (ACAN-EFE 2004) before finally rebounding
in 2004. Furthermore, Chavez would be forced to contest and win a recall
election in 2004 after a successful opposition signature drive.
Regardless, Chavez emerged from the events of 2002 with his presidency
intact and, with some help from rising world oil prices, (2) cleared the
resulting economic and political hurdles, winning another election in
2006 that should secure his rule at least until 2012.
The firing of the bulk of PDVSA's management was the
culmination of a deeply rooted ideological conflict about how the
country's oil reserves should be managed and represented a
fundamental change in direction for PDVSA and Venezuelan oil policy.
While PDVSA had been allowed to pursue a productionist policy in the
1990s under Luis Giusti, Chavez's return to a rentist strategy was
a decisive break from a policy pathway that had increasingly favoured
partnerships with private enterprise and expansion outside of
Venezuela's borders. This event raises questions as to why Chavez
was able to achieve significant institutional change in the face of a
strong and largely autonomous institution, PDVSA, which was moving
toward privatizing the Venezuelan oil industry (Giusti 1999).
Specifically, what conditions allowed Chavez to achieve change in 2002?
In addition, given that Chavez was elected promising institutional
change in PDVSA, why did it take him four years to achieve major change
in PDVSA?
To answer this question, we turn to organizational institutionalism
(e.g., Campbell 2004; Dimaggio and Powell 1991), an approach that
emphasizes "normative and cognitive ideas" (Campbell 2004, 17)
as the main source of institutional stability (or change). According to organizational institutionalism, institutional stability stems from
shared cognitive and normative ideas and, more specifically, from the
congruence between an organization's normative foundations and
broader cultural beliefs that are present throughout society. From this
perspective, tensions between an organization's norms and dominant
social and cultural ideas can lead to a legitimacy crisis and,
ultimately, institutional change within that organization. Moreover,
proponents of organizational institutionalism "maintain that,
because organizational environments are often uncertain, people's
interests are ambiguous and thus their actions are motivated more by
institutional routines, habits, rituals, cues, and scripts than
interests" (Campbell 1998, 381). Thus, normative mechanisms
operating as cognitive maps can motivate the decisions of institutional
actors.
As we argue, the reason that it took so much time for to achieve
major change in PDVSA was its embedded organization culture, which had
been developing since the 1970s. As for the conditions that allowed
Chavez to achieve major change in 2002, they largely stem from a
legitimacy issue that made PDVSA look out of touch with the popular
beliefs and demands that Hugo Chavez articulated in his political
discourse in order to increase his support among the country's
poor. From this perspective, in Venezuelan oil policy one can speak of a
strong relationship between legitimacy issues, class politics, and
institutional change.
Legitimacy, Organizational Culture, and the Politics of
Institutional Change
In the 1990s PDVSA underwent significant changes related to its
corporate policy as many of its managers became active in the Venezuelan
state. As stated by a former PDVSA economist, it was during the apertura
that PDVSA's power exceeded that of simply an oil institution.
"This [the 1990s] is when PDVSA becomes an actor that is outside of
the limits of a state owned company ... PDVSA becomes really really
powerful ... and the planning office of PDVSA had become the economic
policy decision makers in the country" (Ernesto, personal
interview, September 2006). While PDVSA had previously tried to maintain
sufficient distance from the Venezuelan state, recognizing the weakening
government and the opportunity for PDVSA to expand its institutional
power within the Venezuelan state, Giusti sent PDVSA employees to the
government and to the negotiating tables with international institutions
such as the International Monetary Fund. For instance, a former PDVSA
manager told us that, during the 1990s, "managers from PDVSA were
put inside the MEM [Ministry of Energy and Mines], in the top branch, in
order to ensure that they were in line with the policies established
here in PDVSA. So PDVSA was the real policy-making institution in
oil" (Livan, personal interview, October 2006). It is clear, then,
that PDVSA became a political actor in and of itself during the 1990s.
Using his institutional resources, Giusti, himself a product of the
neoliberal organization culture of PDVSA, (3) was able to push forward a
new pathway in oil policy with little resistance as he flexed
PDVSA's technical muscle and gained power over the government in
oil policy decision-making and beyond. Although Giusti could not
initially pursue the privatization of PDVSA, (4) he was able to pursue a
free market model in Venezuelan oil production and, paradoxically, try
to break the monopoly of his own company over Venezuelan oil production.
(5) Utilizing his political knowledge and location at the helm of a
powerful institution, Giusti was able to convert an already existing
institution into a new direction and a new role in the Venezuelan state.
(6) Thus, the actor's social location, knowledge, and institutional
assets were all important factors in his ability to achieve
institutional conversion.
It is important to note the cultural element behind Giusti's
success in pursuing privatization. In fact, there was a distinct
cultural milieu that was strategically implemented within the company.
As a manager who had been with PDVSA throughout its history told me,
"political party, or parties and politics were not present here [in
PDVSA] from 1975. But ideological politics, yes" (Livan, personal
interview, October 2006). The ideological politics that Livan is
referring to were efforts by PDVSA management to ensure that its workers
believed in the role of PDVSA as an autonomous, business-oriented
institution, as "a government company, but also as a private
company" (Juan, personal interview, August 2006), and as "an
energy consortium, able and willing to compete worldwide" (Javier,
personal interview, August 2006). This was achieved through special
courses, such as Mision Cooperativa (cooperative mission), in which
"the management talk about the company, what is their morale and so
on, to create a protocol ... it was a one-week course in Caracas ... the
Mision Cooperativa was against the government ... They said the
politicians should keep out" (Andres, personal interview, November
2006). The fact that the management of PDVSA's operational
companies was opposed to government involvement is not surprising
considering the cultural background from which PDVSA descended. When one
bears in mind that the operational companies were born from private,
multinational companies, and that the original vision stated that PDVSA
was to be free of political interference in order to allow its efficient
operation, one would expect that the management would be opposed to
government interference and that they would adopt a paradigm of
corporate business practices from the world of privatized, multinational
companies. A statement made by a former PDVSA employee, speaking of the
time shortly after nationalization, exemplifies the origins of this
mentality:
There were steps taken at that time. One, PDVSA, and I think that
was very important, PDVSA you know we have to ensure operational
continuity, financial strength, and make sure that the investments and
maintenance of our installations are kept properly. We were not
operating according to any given government policy or anything like
that; we were operating in order to ensure that we would maximize the
value of the resource, in order to fulfill commercial requirements,
fulfill environmental requirements, to make the most out of the oil that
was exported. (Javier, personal interview, August 2006)
PDVSA had been designed as an autonomous institution from the
start. A hands-off governmental policy set up with the Nationalization
Bill had produced a political legacy of institutional autonomy and
created a business-oriented culture opposed to government interference.
The bottom line was privileged above the needs of the government. It is
no wonder, then, that the paradigm adopted by its subsidiaries supported
the business mentality that the best policy was to act as a private
corporation.
With a dominant organizational culture opposed to government
involvement and a business-first mentality, Giusti was able to push
forward neoliberal policies in the 1990s. He was able to create a
"semi-private" corporation and redirect Venezuelan oil policy
and the role of the company within Venezuelan governance. His actions,
however, did not account for an essential form of institutional support:
ideological support from the Venezuelan population. While forms of
social change such as increasing poverty followed the enactment of a
host of neoliberal policies implemented by the pre-Chavez Venezuelan
government, oil policies that reduced state revenues further exacerbated
the weak fiscal position of the state and its inability to offer social
policies that could both help the poor and increase its legitimacy among
the majority of the population, especially the poor. With a legacy,
established early in the country's democratic history, of
state-sponsored public welfare and the normative claim to oil as a
sovereign right (Coronil 1997), broader Venezuelan cultural norms were
fundamentally different from PDVSA corporate culture. These cultural
tensions would come to the forefront during the Chavez presidency.
When Chavez took power in 1998 he was faced with a monumental
challenge: convert the largely autonomous and extremely powerful
state-owned (but certainly not state-run) oil company, PDVSA, into a
revenue machine for the Venezuelan state once again. Although Giusti had
succeeded in changing the direction of Venezuelan oil policy and was
pushing toward privatizing the oil industry, Chavez was able to achieve
a "re-nationalization."
As one political commentator puts it, "When Chavez came into
office he was a complete outsider" (Osmel, personal interview,
October 2006). Not only was Chavez unassociated with either of the
dominant Venezuelan political parties, AD and COPEI, (7) but he also
promised a programmatic break from past governments, such as the second
presidency of Carlos Andres Perez (1989-93) and the second term of
Rafael Caldera (1994-99), that had promoted neoliberal policies.
Specifically, Chavez's policies, while fragmented in some respects
(Gratuis 2006; The Economist 2002), rested upon an underlying
interventionist paradigm that opposed the neoliberal paradigm that had
dominated Venezuelan politics in the 1990s.
Although a neoliberal paradigm with a core value of an economy free
of political interference was behind political reforms in Venezuela in
the 1990s, it also provided some of the background ideas that drove
corporate policy in PDVSA from the beginning. Linked to the idea of
freedom from government influence was the idea that PDVSA was a
semi-private company grounded in the concept of meritocracy. The concept
of meritocracy, which would become a key point of contention in 2002, is
based on the idea that promotions within the company would be made
purely on performance within the company "to make sure the people
that were contributing the most were receiving the highest positions
within the company. And making sure that [there was a] merit point
system within the organization, to make sure that the most capable were
promoted, like in any other company that you will see anywhere else in
the world" (Javier, personal interview, 16 August 2006). Based on
the model of successful multinational organizations, meritocracy was
seen as an equitable promotional policy to guarantee that only people
with the ability to successfully manage the organization would become
high-level managers within PDVSA. Further, a meritocratic corporate
policy would ensure that overtly political promotions could not be made;
it would help to ensure that PDVSA maintained its institutional autonomy
by only promoting successful managers who held the core beliefs of the
corporate culture to the highest levels of management. By ensuring that
only the best and brightest individuals were promoted based on their
performance, PDVSA would remain a competitive multinational business,
free from government influence.
When Chavez came to power, he challenged the meritocratic ideal by
appointing actors who were politically aligned with his project but had
not always come up through the ranks of PDVSA. (8) Underlying
Chavez's approach to governing PDVSA was an interventionist
paradigm that promoted direct state involvement in the Venezuelan
economy and, concurrently, PDVSA. Thus, Chavez's economic policies
and politicization of PDVSA can also be seen as a clash between two
contradictory sets of ideas, one set emphasizing corporate autonomy and
the other valuing state control over the economy.
Janet Kelly and Pedro A. Palma (2004) hold that the traditional
role of the Venezuelan state was reinforced when Chavez was elected.
"The short-lived effort to liberalize the economy between 1989 and
1993 generated deep and even violent conflict, thus reinforcing the
traditional bias toward seeking growth and income redistribution through
government action" (Kelly and Palma 2004, 202-203). Chavez's
election is also portrayed as affirmation that most Venezuelans
preferred that the government "take the lead" and that they
"distrust leaving the development to the forces of the unguided
market (i.e., neoliberalism)" (Kelly and Palma 2004, 203). Chavez
had gained power as part of a campaign that played upon the traditional
role of the state as the landlord to redistribute oil rents to the
population. Despite the fact that the neoliberal basis of the dominant
corporate culture within PDVSA was aligned with the move toward
privatization in the 1990s, it is important to note that there was an
ideational legacy in Venezuelan society that promoted the state and, in
turn, PDVSA as the provider of social and economic resources aimed at
fighting poverty and supporting the Venezuelan population at large. This
had been a key factor leading to the nationalization of the Venezuelan
oil industry and had defined the role of PDVSA at nationalization:
providing the state with funding through the extraction of rents from
its subsidiaries (Coronil 1997).
In late 1996 survey data showed that 87.8% of respondents blamed
"political elites" and the "national government" for
the crisis of poverty facing the country (Gil Yepes 2004). According to
Jose Antonio Gil Yepes (2004), this was a result of the Venezuelan
population's claim to oil as a national right. That is, because
Venezuela's wealth is tied directly to its oil reserves and the oil
wealth is owned by all of its citizens, the oil wealth should be
distributed in a way that makes all Venezuelans prosper. However,
Venezuela was experiencing extremely high poverty rates--as high as
60.94% (Weisbrot, Sandoval, and Rosnick 2006). "Thus, those who
distributed the oil wealth must have stolen it" (Gil Yepes 2004,
241) and, as a result, it was the mismanagement of oil wealth by the
government and political elites that was responsible for "the
economic and political crisis" (Gil Yepes 2004). Thus, Chavez, by
promising to clean up corruption in the government and regain control
over the national oil wealth, was playing upon deeply embedded public
sentiments about the role of the government and oil in Venezuela. A
historically embedded understanding of the state as the distributor of
oil rents (Coronel 1983; Coronil 1997; Romero 1997) was in line with
Chavez's promise to regain control over PDVSA and the national oil
wealth along with it. PDVSA's neoliberal organizational culture
spawned practices that were not in line with broader Venezuelan
normative beliefs about the proper use of the national subsoil. Despite
PDVSA's immense institutional power and endogenous support for
privatization, Chavez promised to change the direction of the company
and Venezuelan oil policy to bring it in line with public sentiments.
Chavez's vision was in line with popular sentiments as to the
legitimate role of the government in managing the national oil wealth;
the vision of PDVSA's leadership was not. Thus, a crisis of
legitimacy was manifest in the rhetoric that brought Chavez to power,
and historically established normative mechanisms played a significant
role in expediting institutional change in PDVSA.
Chavez claimed to have the popular mandate to pursue change in all
arms of the Venezuelan government, including PDVSA. However, he would
have to gain control over the highly autonomous institution. During his
campaign for the presidency, Chavez reinforced a discourse that attacked
the legitimacy of PDVSA, calling it a "state within a state"
operating with little mind to the interests of the general population
and thus creating an imperative for change. During December 2002 Chavez
further promoted a discourse that served to delegitimate PDVSA in the
public eye by arguing that the actions of PDVSA's managers went
against the interests of the Venezuelan population. Connecting PDVSA
management to an exploitative international ruling elite that had been
constructed as an enemy of the Venezuelan population since the
dictatorship of Gomez in the early 1900s, Chavez used a strategic
discourse to create what Robert H. Cox refers to as a reform imperative
(Cox 2001). For example, on 19 December, over two weeks after the
beginning of the general strike, Chavez stated that the time had come to
"clean up PDVSA" (cited in Agence France Press 2002), saying
that
PDVSA belongs to all Venezuelans ... [B]ehind the attempt to
paralyze PDVSA there is nothing but a new attempt at a coup to try to
bring down the legitimately-established government ... This petroleum
elite, which for years managed the enterprise that belongs to all
Venezuelans, has now removed its mask. Behind an alleged meritocracy
there was always hidden a deep anti-national and anti-Venezuelan
sentiment. (cited in Agence France Press 2002)
While Chavez's politicization of PDVSA had been a rallying
point for striking individuals, Chavez linked the idea of
"meritocracy" to the elite group in charge of the petroleum
wealth that should be the property of all Venezuelans, framing
PDVSA's striking management as the enemy of the Venezuelan people.
The "meritocracy" had attempted to sell the national subsoil
and was thus acting against the national interest. Chavez was there to
take it back, and, the government, allegedly acting in the name of the
Venezuelan people, did just that. Chavez linked the idea of meritocracy
to an elite group that had been segregated from Venezuelan society, and,
as such, he was able to maintain a claim to legitimacy and sufficient
popular support during the strike.
By connecting PDVSA to both national and global neoliberal
interests that were exploiting the nation's natural resource with
little regard for the "national interest," or lowering
royalties in order to promote increased production, Chavez reinforced
the idea that PDVSA's management was part of the exploitative
elite, thus making it look illegitimate. Much like during the Gomez era
and the push for nationalization, oil was depicted as a scarce resource
to be exploited to the greatest benefit of the population with the least
possible exhaustion of reserves. As the state had long been established
as the guarantor of oil wealth and the landlord who would redistribute
oil wealth to the population, Chavez played upon public sentiments that
had emerged before nationalization: the idea of oil as a symbol of
national sovereignty. When Chavez and Rodriguez redesigned oil policy to
implement production cuts and increased royalties, "the role of
PDVSA, condemned by Chavez as a ' state within a state,' was
thus redefined in line with the broader national interest" (Buxton
2003, 125). A policy that returned control of PDVSA to the state and
maximized revenues was thus framed to match public sentiments regarding
the role of oil in Venezuelan society.
While neoliberal ideas shared by the majority of PDVSA workers and
opposition groups such as FEDECAMARAS contributed heavily to the
conflict in 2002, it is also clear that there were variables specific to
PDVSA that encouraged its involvement in the events of 2002. The
meritocratic employment policy of PDVSA and the concurrent resistance to
politicization represent a programmatic reflection of a legacy of
neoliberal policies within PDVSA. While the corporation was not a
perfect meritocracy, the idea of meritocracy was deeply embedded as a
core value of PDVSA and was recruited as a political frame to create
further opposition to the Chavez government. For instance, the defense
of meritocracy was cited by the small group of managers that went on
strike before the 11 April coup, and, when PDVSA's position was
"radicalized" in the second week of the strike, it was a
result of the appointment of managers that did not abide by a
meritocratic corporate policy. Despite the fact that meritocracy had
been bypassed in the past, that there was a degree of politicization in
PDVSA before the Chavez era, and that Chavez himself only made a handful
of appointments that challenged meritocracy, the idea of PDVSA as a
meritocracy was exploited by the media and the leaders of the strike to
create further animosity between PDVSA employees and the government. The
idea of meritocracy had been a key idea cited in protest of
Chavez's actions with regards to PDVSA, and, as the strike
escalated, was recruited as a key part of the framing process that
appealed to the core beliefs of many PDVSA employees in order to create
further opposition. At a time of crisis, the value associated with
maintaining a meritocratic ideal was a catalyst in determining the
position taken by institutional actors.
Although Chavez did not achieve lasting success in effectively
reducing poverty in the first four years of his presidency, (9) he was
able to strongly associate the direction that he was taking the country
with a popular vision of public interest. An initial decrease in poverty
over the first two years of his presidency showed promise while he began
to alter the institutional organization of the Venezuelan state. The
Bolivarian Constitution--the product of the first year of Chavez's
presidency, which promised to provide a number of social services to the
Venezuelan poor--and highly publicized, albeit fragmented, social
programs known as misiones were the source of hope for Venezuela's
urban poor. By framing the perceived interest of the Venezuelan poor as
the centrepiece of his vision for Venezuela and PDVSA, Chavez garnered
the support of a constituency that comprised the majority of
Venezuela's population: the urban poor. He had originally been
elected with more support from the urban poor than middle and upper
class citizens, and even after the strike, a Mercanalisis poll conducted
toward the end of May 2003 reported that lower classes (e.g., the poor
and people living slightly above the poverty line) showed the greatest
support for Chavez at 40%, with an additional 43% "neutral" as
to whether or not they would vote for Chavez in the upcoming recall
referendum, while middle and upper classes showed a much lower level of
support (Pulgarin 2003). While Chavez pushed for increasing
redistribution of oil rents, he continued to derive his main support
from lower class, poor Venezuelans who, notably, also represented the
majority of the Venezuelan population. Thus, the direction that Chavez
wished to take Venezuelan oil policy and PDVSA was aligned with
long-held class-related beliefs about the role of the state in
Venezuelan oil production. By redistributing the oil wealth to the urban
poor through social missions, Chavez claimed, he would alleviate poverty
in the nation.
Even while Chavez faced organized opposition from a significant
portion of society in 2002, he was able to delegitimate the actions of
those engaged in the attempted coup and general strike in a way that
gathered support for his presidency. In fact, in an evaluation of how
good Chavez's actions were for Venezuela, opinion polls conducted
in mid April of 2002 report a steep rise in support for Chavez while he
also received increasing support between November 2002 and February
2003--the time of the strike itself. (10)
Beyond Issues of Legitimacy
Although the timing of exogenous events in the form of oil shocks
had contributed to PDVSA's expansion into international markets in
the 1980s and economic crisis had helped PDVSA gain power and push
forward the apertura in the 1990s, Chavez benefited from external events
in his push to gain control over PDVSA as well. Particularly, rising
international oil prices that resulted from international political
instabilities and a resurgence of OPEC, among other things, allowed
Chavez to expand social spending during the early years of his
presidency, a major factor in his ability to provide the social programs
that, as discussed above, helped secure support from Venezuela's
urban poor. Thus, exogenous events provided the material conditions
needed to promote the programs essential to maintaining public support.
Therefore, the assumption of historical institutionalism that exogenous
events can ignite institutional change holds true. However, that is only
one possible factor leading to institutional change. In Venezuela as
elsewhere, endogenous institutional and ideational factors play a major
role in path-departing institutional change.
The timing of specific events during the 2002 strike was another
important factor in Chavez's success. During the strike, the
procession of a number of key events (see Table 1), such as an attack
upon Juan Fernandez, a leader of striking PDVSA workers, and on PDVSA
protestors in the first several days of the strike, and Chavez's
subsequent firing of top managers, served to escalate the strike in
PDVSA and provided the mandate to rid PDVSA of workers opposed to
Chavez's policies and vision for the company and the country. In
fact, it has been argued by some that these were strategic actions
pursued by Chavez to create the opportunity for change. For instance,
several participants in this study cited the National Guard's use
of excessive force in Plaza la Meritocracia as a strategy intended to
escalate the strike (Jaime, personal interview, September 2006; Esteban,
personal interview, September 2006; Bruno, personal interview, October
2006).
A last consideration that is important to note is the fragmented
internal politics and constant battle of ideas within PDVSA. Although we
have presented a somewhat cohesive overview of the ideational struggles
that allowed Chavez to achieve path-departing change in oil policy,
there were always competing groups and ideas within PDVSA subtly
affecting the direction of the company and its policies. (11) While the
idea of meritocracy was an important one in framing an argument against
Chavez and, ultimately, was a strong determinant in escalating the
magnitude of the 2002 strike within PDVSA, there were also people within
PDVSA that did not buy into the idea of meritocracy. Furthermore, a
group of PDVSA employees who were aligned with Chavez and who knew the
company's operational procedures were put in place as the
management of the company after the firing of top oil workers during the
strike, thus allowing production to resume during and after the strike.
For instance, a long-time manager with PDVSA explained that
We created a group. A very high high level technical group. But we
were in disagreement with the policy for the board of directors or
the authority at this moment in PDVSA. Even though President
Chavez, even though we were in the power, we have the president, we
were a minority in PDVSA. We were persecution and those in power
didn't give us opportunity and we had a meeting, I don't know what
this is in English, clandestinia ...
Interviewer: Clandestine?
Participant: Yes, clandestine, out of PDVSA into the university,
into the military facility, in order to discuss into the future how we
can take the real power of PDVSA, to put PDVSA in order to take the real
sovereignty and maximize the return to the pueblo, the people, the
Venezuelan people. We were, from 1998 until 2002, you know we have a lot
of meetings. (Inti, personal interview, November 2006)
Without this faction of the company that supported Chavez, the new
policy direction and institutional conversion that occurred would not
have be possible. Thus, it is not accurate that widely held societal
beliefs that conflicted with the dominant internal ideas of PDVSA simply
won out over PDVSA. Rather, the conflict of ideas that was apparent in
the greater Venezuelan society was also evident within PDVSA; the only
difference is that while Chavez's policies were supported largely
by the urban poor, as evidenced by the strike, his policies did not
receive a great deal of support from the PDVSA elite, and this was the
basis for a conflict between PDVSA and the Venezuelan state. The
presence of actors who held contrasting ideas about the perceived
interests of the Venezuelan population were important in determining the
direction of the company during and after the strike. Without these
actors who actively supported Chavez, institutional change might not
have been achievable. Thus, we cannot simply make the claim that PDVSA
changed because it was not in line with objective societal interests.
Rather, institutional change is a result of both shared social and
political understandings about the legitimacy of state policy and the
actions of political actors who mobilize material and ideological
resources in a way that supports what they perceive as their best course
of action.
Conclusion
Between the beginning of his presidency in 1998 and the end of the
general strike in 2003, Hugo Chavez was able to achieve significant
change in PDVSA. This was not simply a product of his personal will as
the Venezuelan president, but rather a historical legacy that produced
deeply embedded normative ideas about the role of the state in the
management and distribution of oil wealth made institutional change
possible. Specifically, a long-held popular idea of the national subsoil
as the property of the populace and a legacy of the state as the
moderator of oil wealth lent legitimacy to Chavez's claims that
PDVSA was not acting in the interests of the Venezuelan population by
favouring private interests in Venezuelan oil production. He was elected
on the idea that returning oil money to the people through
redistributive programming was the legitimate course of action. His
actions toward PDVSA only furthered an impending crisis of legitimacy in
which Chavez's government confronted the largely autonomous and
highly powerful institution and was able to regain control over the
company with, importantly, a claim to legitimacy fostered by the
sentiments of deeply embedded Venezuelan normative beliefs. Although, as
noted above, institutional change in PDVSA cannot be reduced to a
question of cultural legitimacy, it is clear that cultural norms were an
important variable in Chavez's success in gaining control over
PDVSA.
Overall, it is clear that, more than five years after the general
strike of 2002-03, major institutional change has taken place in
Venezuelan oil policy. The Chavez government has a firm hold on PDVSA
and is pushing to rebuild the company in line with the redistributive
vision that got Chavez elected in the first place. Where he takes the
company through the end of his tenure as Venezuelan president remains to
be seen.
Works Cited
ACAN-EFE. 2002. Opposition says Venezuela's oil production
near standstill. 14 December.
--. 2004. Venezuelan economy to grow over 12 percent due to high
oil prices. 6 October.
Agence France Presse. 2002. Venezuela's Chavez says revolution
must "clean up" PDVSA. 19 December.
Alvarez, Angel E. 1996. La crisis de hegemonia de los partidos
politicos venezolanos. In El sistema politico venezolano: Crisis y
transformaciones, edited by Angel E. Alvarez, 131-154. Caracas:
Universidad Central de Venezuela.
Baena, Cesar E. 1999. The policy process in a petro-state: An
analysis of PDVSA s (Petroleos de Venezuela SA 's)
internationalisation strategy. Brookfield, VT: Ashgate.
Betancourt, Romulo. 1978. Venezuela, oil, andpolitics. Boston, MA:
Houghton Mifflin.
Buxton, Julia. 2003. Economic policy and the rise of Hugo Chavez.
In Venezuelan politics in the Chavez era: Class, polarization &
conflict, edited by Steve Ellner and Daniel Hellinger, 113-130. Boulder,
CO: Lynne Rienner.
Campbell, John L. 1998. Institutional analysis and the role of
ideas in political economy. Theory and Society 27: 3 77-409.
--. 2004. Institutional change and globalization. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Chavez Frias, Hugo. 2005. Understanding the Venezuelan revolution:
Hugo Chavez talks to Marta Harnecker. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Coronel, Gustavo. 1983. The nationalization of the Venezuelan oil
industry. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Coronil, Fernando. 1997. The magical state: Nature, money, and
modernity in Venezuela. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Cox, Robert H. 2001. The social construction of an imperative: Why
welfare reform happened in Denmark and the Netherlands but not in
Germany. World Politics 53: 463-498.
Crisp, Brian F. 2000. Democratic institutional design: The powers
and incentives of Venezuelan politicians and interest groups. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University Press.
Dimaggio, Paul, and Walter W. Powell, eds. 1991. The new
institutionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Economist. 2002. Once again, oil workers are joining a general
strike. Will the army follow? 5 December.
Gil Yepes, Jose Antonio. 2004. Public opinion, political
socialization, and regime stabilization. In The unraveling of
representative democracy in Venezuela, edited by Jennifer L. McCoy and
David J. Myers, 231-260. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Giusti, Luis E. 1999. La Apertura: The opening of Venezuela's
oil industry. Journal of International Affairs 53.1: 117-128.
Gratuis, Susanne. 2006. Venezuela. In Strategies for democratic
change: Assessing the global response, edited by Ted Piccone and Richard
Youngs, 123150. Washington, DC: Democracy Coalition Project.
<http://demcoalition. org/2005_html/activ_publi.html>. Accessed 20
March 2008.
Grindle, Merilee S. 2000. Audacious reforms: Institutional
invention and democracy in Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press.
Hillman, Richard S. 1994. Democracy for the privileged: Crisis and
transition in Venezuela. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Kelly, Janet, and Pedro A. Palma. 2004. The syndrome of economic
decline and the quest for change. In The unraveling of representative
democracy in Venezuela, edited by Jennifer L. McCoy and David J. Myers,
202-230. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
McCoy, Jennifer L., and David G. Myers, eds. 2004. The unraveling
of representative democracy in Venezuela. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press.
Pulgarin, Wilfer. 2003. Mercanalisis poll results show situation
for Chavez, allies deteriorating. El Nacional, 25 June.
Roberts, Kenneth. 2003. Social polarization and the populist resurgence in Venezuela. In Venezuelan politics in the Chavez era:
Class, polarization & conflict, edited by Steve Ellner and Daniel
Hellinger, 55-72. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Rohter, Larry. 1999. Venezuela tightens grip on state petroleum
company. New York Times, 17 April 17: C1.
Romero, Anibal. 1997. Rearranging deck chairs on the Titanic: The
agony of democracy in Venezuela. Latin American Research Review 32.1:
7-36.
Salmeron, Victor. 2003. Venezuelan economy plunges 18.5 percent. El
Universal, 3 September.
Weisbrot, Mark, Luis Sandoval, and David Rosnick. 2006. Poverty
rates in Venezuela: Getting the numbers right. Center for Economic and
Policy Research, Washington, DC.
<http://www.cepr.net/publications/venezuelan_
poverty_rates_2006_05.pdf>. Accessed 20 March 2008.
World Bank. 2006. Venezuela, RB at a glance. 13 August.
<http://devdata. worldbank.org/AAG/ven_aag.pdf>. Accessed 20 March
2008.
Notes
(1) This expansion was based on the argument that securing
downstream outlets for Venezuelan oil was important to establishing
stable supply networks, especially in times of crisis.
(2) Riding on high oil prices, Venezuela's GDP rose by 17.9%
in 2004 and 9.3% in 2005 (World Bank 2006). Chavez was able to use
increasing oil revenues to significantly increase social spending, and,
while poverty spiked in 2004, by the end of 2005 poverty rates were down
to 43.7% of the population. While that may seem like a large number, it
represents a 6% decrease from the poverty rate of 49.99% recorded when
Chavez took power in 1999; see Weisbrot et al. (2006).
(3) Giusti had risen through the ranks of the Shell-descended
division of PDVSA, Maraven, and was himself a product of the
competitive, productionist ranks of PDVSA's operational
subsidiaries.
(4) PDVSA was responsible for providing the national wealth and
would leave the Venezuelan government without the shaky economic footing
that it already stood on. Furthermore, PDVSA's role in the country
was clear, and the government still held nominal power to reverse
decisions made by PDVSA. A move toward privatization against the
government's will could still be met with government intervention.
(5) It is reasonable to assume that, as he has stated, Giusti
believed privatization would benefit the Venezuelan population in the
long run, based on neoliberal assumptions that increased production and
increased economic exchange lead to increased economic prosperity for
all. See Giusti (1999).
(6) This confirms John Campbell's idea that the social and
political location of institutional reformers can help them promote
institutional change. See Campbell (2004).
(7) The Pact of Punto Fijo had established a power sharing
agreement in 1958 in which the two dominant political parties, AD
(Democratic Action) and COPEI (Christian Democratic Party), had agreed
to respect each other's interests as well as that of private
enterprise and other sources of political and economic power within
Venezuela in the name of democratic stability. See Buxton (2003);
Hillman (1994); Crisp (2000); Grindle (2000); Baena (1999); McCoy and
Myers (2004). As argued by Angel Alvarez, this system of "pacted
democracy" had also worked to minimize the emergence of formalized class politics in Venezuela, as the dominant parties both took a
moderate stance and engaged in little ideological or programmatic
debate. See Alvarez (1996).
(8) It is important, however, to note that Chavez was not the first
president to appoint political actors to the board of PDVSA. For
instance, one participant in this study reported that as early as the
"late '80s, early '90s, instead of promoting people from
the ranks, they started naming political appointees" (Rafael,
personal interview, 19 September 2006). In fact, Giusti himself was not
next in line when he was appointed as president in 1993. His promotion
"was seen by the highest ranking people in PDVSA first as a
violation of meritocracy" (Ernesto, personal interview, 15
September 2006). Thus, Giusti himself had bypassed the meritocracy in
his promotion to president.
(9) While poverty rates initially fell during Chavez's
presidency, instabilities, particularly those brought on by the
attempted coup and general strike of 2002, saw the percentage of the
population living below the poverty line climb from 45.38% in the second
half of 2001 to 62.09% in the second half of 2003 (Weisbrot et al.
2006).
(10) When asked "How would you evaluate the actions taken by
Hugo Chavez Frias for the welfare of the country?" 44.7% of those
surveyed from a stratified sample of 1,300 in April 2002 said he was
doing moderate to good, good, or very good, up from 34.4% the month
before. Furthermore, between November 2002 and February 2003, those
responding "moderate to good," "good," or "very
good" increased from 32.6% to 35.1%. While still a minority, it
does display a rise in public evaluation of Chavez even while the
country was experiencing an economic and political crisis that crippled
the nation's economy (Gil Yepes 2004).
(11) Competing corporate cultures existed in PDVSA from the very
beginning. As a long-time employee of a multinational corporation
explains, nationalization was done in such a way that the cultures of
the different companies working in Venezuela were respected. For
instance, the Exxon affiliate was represented in the local company
called Lagoven. So Lagoven, which was an affiliate of PDVSA, maintained
all the corporate culture that Exxon brought to Venezuela in their
previous affiliate, Creole Petroleum Corporation. So Creole, actually
Lagoven, was almost an extension of Creole, as Maraven was an extension
of Shell, with the same management, same standards, and same corporate
culture (Rafael, personal interview, 19 September 2006). For instance,
Luis Giusti, as an employee of Maraven, had support from a faction of
the company that believed in his business strategy while others were
opposed. When Roberto Mandini was assigned as president of PDVSA in
2000, he came from one of these competing cultures; he had worked for
Corpoven before the merger in 1997 and had been an open critic of
Giusti's policies during Giusti's period at the helm of the
company (Bruno, personal interview, 18 October 2006). Thus, PDVSA did
not present a united front; to speak of PDVSA as a cohesive and unified
organization ignores internal divisions that we must be aware of when
discussing institutional change.
COLIN WISEMAN
University of Calgary
DANIEL BELAND
University of Saskatchewan
TABLE 1
Oil Policy and Protest under Hugo Chavez (1998-2003)
1998 Hugo Chavez is elected President of Venezuela,
promising to return the oil to the people.
August 2001 Chavez passes 49 laws by decree, including a new
Hydrocarbons Law designed to increase state control
over oil production.
December 2001 PDVSA joins business interests in a short general
strike to protest the 49 laws.
7 April 2002 A small managerial strike in PDVSA results in the
public dismissal of seven of the striking workers.
11 April 2002 Chavez is removed from office by a military coup.
Pedro Carmona, president of the national business
lobby FEDECAMARAS, takes over as president of the
country. The coup fails, and Chavez is back in
office by April 14.
2 December 2002 A nationwide general strike is called in which
PDVSA plays a major role, shutting down oil
operations.
3 December 2002 Juan Fernandez, the unofficial leader of the PDVSA
opposition, is attacked in his home by unknown
assailants.
4 December 2002 PDVSA protestors are attacked by the National Guard
in Plaza la Meritocracia (Meritocracy Plaza).
8 December 2002 Carlos Ortega, president of the Venezuelan Worker's
Union, announces that the strike will continue
indefinitely.
12 December 2002 Oil Minister Ali Rodriguez is granted the power to
replace striking PDVSA managers by an Executive
decree. The government begins to contract workers
to reopen oil refineries.
27 December 2002 Juan Fernandez admits that PDVSA was no longer
under control of the striking managers.
3 February 2003 The opposition declares an end to the strike. At
least 18,000 workers had been fired by PDVSA, and
PDVSA is restructured with members of the Ministry
of Energy and Mines assuming leadership positions
in the company. The strike has failed.