Robert C. Allen, Farm to Factory: A Reinterpretation of the Soviet Industrial Revolution.
Clarke, Simon
Robert C. Allen, Farm to Factory: A Reinterpretation of the Soviet
Industrial Revolution (Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press
2003)
THE ISSUE of the economic performance of the Soviet Union is hardly
any less controversial today than it was at the height of the Cold War.
While specialists continue to debate the precise figures, the consensus
today is that under Stalin the Soviet economy grew rapidly, though at
enormous human cost, and that economic growth was not translated into
commensurately rising living standards. Moreover, revisionists have
argued that the Russian Revolution aborted what would have been a
capitalist economic take-off which would have allowed Russia to join the
ranks of the leading capitalist powers. Those who find anything positive
in the Soviet experience risk demonization as apologists for Stalin.
Bob Allen is a distinguished economic historian who has only
recently ventured into the minefield of Soviet economic history and in
this book he seeks systematically to clear a path through it, arguing
that Russian capitalism before the revolution was not poised for
take-off. He recognizes that collectivization and terror imposed
economic, as well as human, costs but argues that the economic gains of
Stalinist industrialization had neutralized those costs by the end of
the 1930s. Finally, he argues that the slowdown of the Soviet economy
after 1970 was not, as today's consensus has it, inherent in the
Soviet system of economic planning, but was primarily the result of
major planning mistakes. Robert Allen does not reach his conclusions as
an apologia for Stalinism, but on the basis of computer simulations
based on traditional, though now unfashionable, models from development
economics.
Allen argues that pre-revolutionary Russia lacked what are
generally considered to be the institutional prerequisites for
capitalist development so that its development prospects were not good.
Although economic growth in the 50 years before the Revolution was
relatively rapid, by the Revolution the sources of growth had been
exhausted. Agriculture had reached North American levels of productivity
before wheat prices collapsed after 1914. The expansion of the railroads
had run its course and there was no prospect of protected light industry
becoming internationally competitive. Moreover, Russian capitalist
development had brought little if any benefit to the urban and rural
working class, intensifying the class conflicts that erupted in
Revolution. The appropriate comparators for the prospects for Russian
capitalism in the 20th century are not Japan but Argentina or even
India.
Following War Communism, the New Economic Policy (NEP) sought to
develop the Russian economy within a quasi-capitalist framework.
However, the institutional and structural barriers to Russian economic
development were now compounded by the unfavourable circumstances of the
world economy, so that there was no prospect of export-led development,
while low domestic incomes provided only a limited market for domestic
industry. Without a state-coordinated investment programme, the Soviet
economy would be caught in the low-income trap typical of the
underdeveloped world.
The Soviet Union had a massive rural surplus population with little
scope for increasing agricultural productivity, other than through the
consolidation of excessively fragmented holdings. The obvious
development strategy, as Soviet economists were well aware, was to
transfer the surplus rural population to industrial employment in the
cities. The key issue was how to achieve this. Stalin achieved it by a
brutal policy of collectivization, forced migration, compulsory
requisitions, and heavy rural taxation. Allen believes that the
continuation of the NEP policy of encouraging market forces in
agriculture, alongside state-sponsored industrialization, could have
achieved almost the same result at much less human cost as the surplus
population was attracted to industrial employment in the city and those
who remained increased their sales of produce. Allen argues that a
capitalist economy would not have created the industrial jobs required
to employ the surplus labour, since capitalists would only employ labour
so long as the marginal product of labour exceeded the wage.
State-sponsored industrialization faced no such constraints, since
enterprises were encouraged to expand employment in line with the
demands of the plan.
Allen's simulations of alternative strategies in the 1930s
suggest that a capitalist development strategy would have provided very
slow growth and high unemployment, but that the Stalinist
collectivization strategy soon overcame the disasters of
collectivization to outperform a hypothetical continuation of the NEP
policy alongside rapid industrialization by the end of the 1930s,
although not by very much. The other positive feature of the Stalinist
strategy was that the rapid expansion of education and growth of
employment reduced the fertility rate and saved the Soviet Union from
the population explosion that has plagued much of the Third World.
The strong performance of the NEP strategy might seem surprising,
since the turn to forced collectivization was made at the end of the
1920s precisely because the NEP was not working: the peasants were not
increasing their sales sufficiently to feed the urban population.
However, Allen's finding is primarily due to his assumption that
without collectivization farm output would have grown steadily, so that
under his NEP simulation farm output is 51 per cent greater than under
collectivization and it is still 16 per cent higher in 1939 (234): the
food supply to the cities comprises a much lower proportion of total
agricultural production than under collectivization.
Soviet industrialization was not only based on forced
collectivization, but also on the massive allocation of resources to
heavy industry and the military at the expense, Stalin's critics
have argued, of the living standards of the population. Allen uses
simulations of Feldman's classic Soviet growth model to show that
an investment strategy focused on heavy industry is quite compatible
with rising consumption and re-analyses the best available data to show
that, after the catastrophe of collectivization, living standards indeed
rose rapidly.
Bob Allen shows that the Stalinist strategy worked, in strictly
economic terms, until around 1970, when growth slowed dramatically. He
explains the downturn in terms of the failure of the system to adapt to
the ending of the labour surplus, but the failure was not so much that
of the system as of the decision-making at the top. A growing proportion
of investment resources was wasted by diversion to the military; by
expanding energy production instead of economizing on consumption; by
investing heavily in Siberia; and by retooling old plants rather than
closing them down and building new facilities. However, we might ask
whether these faulty decisions were just subjective errors or whether
they did not perhaps have deeper systemic roots. The decisions may have
been economically irrational, but there were good reasons for them, as
for so many other economically irrational decisions, in the rationality
of the Soviet system.
Bob Allen's book convincingly establishes the superiority of a
planned over a capitalist economy in conditions of labour surplus (which
is the condition of most of the world most of the time). However, his
findings should not divert attention from the well-documented
deficiencies of the Soviet economic system that provided perverse
incentives at every level and led to grotesque levels of inefficiency
and waste. His book is testimony to the astonishing achievements of
Soviet workers, whose efforts produced such impressive results despite
their bad management and often appalling living and working conditions.
The big question raised by Bob Allen's book is whether it is
possible to reconcile the benefits of central planning with democracy
and microeconomic efficiency. Gorbachev believed that it was, but his
attempts at democratization and economic liberalization led to the
collapse of central planning, so that the Russian people merely
exchanged the irrationality of the Soviet system for the irrationality
of global capitalism. The failure of the Soviet Union to achieve its
proclaimed socialist aims surely does not mean that it is impossible for
humanity to make a better world.
Bob Allen has written a thought-provoking book, packed with
stimulating insights and supported by rigorous analysis, that merits
reading and re-reading.
Simon Clarke
University of Warwick.