Taxation and Citizenship. (Notebook/Carnet).
Brooks, Neil
TAX LAW IS SHOT through with politics. Throughout history it has
been the immediate cause of countless revolutions. For the last 50
years, no other public policy issue has been so consistently at the
centre of ideological conflict over the proper role, size, and functions
of the modem welfare state. In the last few years -- in this era of
post-deficit politics -- the debate over the "need" for tax
cuts has become the defining issue of Canadian politics.
Modern political parties really define themselves by their stance
on tax issues. This should not be surprising since tax laws are the most
visible policy instrument that modern governments use to position
themselves along the two fundamental axes upon which political
ideologies have traditionally been arrayed: 1) an axis in which
political ideologies are ordered from those concerned primarily with
individualism to those concerned primarily with collectivism; 2) an axis
upon which they are arrayed from those concerned with the need for
hierarchy or elitism to those concerned primarily with achieving a high
degree of social and economic equality. To implement collective
decision-making, and thus move from concerns over individualism to
concerns about community, taxes are an important policy instrument.
Similarly, taxes are normally seen as an important policy instrument in
achieving a more egalitarian society. Taxes thus raise fundamental
questions not only about public policy but also about morality,
including the question of what is a morally acceptable distribution of
the income and wealth that members of a society collectively produce. As
such, tax laws are a particularly reliable barometer of shifts in
prevailing ideologies. The tax system has been called "a mirror of
democracy." Joseph Schumpeter, a widely admired economic historian,
observed that "nothing shows so clearly the character of a society
and of a civilization as does the fiscal policy that its political
sector adopts."
Taxes are at the centre of political debate because they are so
clearly about money. The debate over taxes is, after all, a debate over
who will pay. T.S. Adams, a prominent American economist who worked in
the US Treasury when the American income tax was being
implemented-observed that "modern taxation or tax-making in its
most characteristic aspect is a group contest in which powerful
interests vigorously endeavour to rid themselves of present and proposed
tax burdens. It is, first of all, a hard game in which he who trusts
wholly in economics, reason, and justice, will in the end retire beaten
and disillusioned. Class politics is the essence of taxation."
Louis Eisenstein, a leading American tax lawyer in the 1940s and 1950s,
and a tax commentator of uncommon brilliance and originality, was
equally blunt: "Taxes ... are a changing product of earnest efforts
to have others pay them. In a society where the few control the many,
the efforts are rather simple. Levies are imposed in response to the
preferences of the governing groups. Since their well-being is equated
with the welfare of the community, they are inclined to burden
themselves as lightly as possible. Those who have little say are
expected to pay."
A broad consensus emerged during the 1950s and 1960s about the role
of government and, therefore, the objects of public policy, including
taxation. Reflecting the major blueprints for the future advanced in the
1940s, and based upon the experience of the Great Depression and World
War II, it was widely believed that government should correct the
pervasive failures of the private market to allocate resources
efficiently, seek to stabilize the economy through macro-economic demand
management, attempt to ensure a rising real standard of living for all
citizens, guarantee workers a degree of economic security, provide open
access to those services essential to human development such as
education and healthcare, and promote social equality.
In pursuit of these objectives, governments in most western
industrialized countries substantially increased taxes: total tax
revenue as a percentage of gross domestic product (GDP) rose on average
over 10 per cent from 1965 to 1985, from 26.7 per cent to 36.9 per cent
of GDP. The development of the welfare state was premised on a theory of
citizenship. As members in a common enterprise, all citizens were
recognized as having civil, political, and social rights that would
ensure them full membership in the life of the society. Citizenship
necessarily also implied responsibilities and moral obligations.
Citizens, acting through governments, were seen as having a
responsibility to provide a decent level of services such as healthcare,
education, and welfare for everyone, regardless of ability to pay. In
addition to providing for strangers, paying for these services of
government also insured that taxpayers themselves would receive adequate
public services when they needed them. Further, the collective provision
of services was recognition of the fact that humans are intrinsically
social beings, completely dependent upon one another to realize their
full human potential.
Although there was obviously some disagreement about the ways in
which state power should be exercised, Keynesian liberals rallied strong
support around the development of the welfare state until the mid-1970s.
Then, following the oil shocks, as productivity growth declined,
inflation accelerated, and unemployment rates remained high, this
consensus about the role of government, and therefore taxes, quickly
became unglued. Political debate shifted dramatically from social
policies and their efficacy in achieving economic security and equality
to the increasing size of the public sector and its harmful effect on
economic efficiency. The precise causes of the backlash against the
development of the welfare state remain contentious; there is, however,
little doubt that by the early 1970s business interests had become
concerned about the threat of a strong, active state to their power and
privileges, and that in response they quite deliberately orchestrated
and channeled the ensuing disenchantment with the welfar e state and
consequent high taxes.
The intense ideological assault that was launched on the welfare
state by business interests, right-wing economists, and neo-conservative
governments around this time continues unabated. All fronts of the
welfare state have come under attack. Government programs are alleged to
be futile, to result in often perverse effects, and to jeopardize widely
held interests and values. Democratic decision-making itself is asserted
to be rife with pathologies due to incompetent and self-interested
bureaucrats, greedy politicians, and the influence of powerful special
interest groups. All instruments of government policy are denigrated
including state-owned enterprises, government provision, monetary
policy, regulation, spending programs, credit controls, trade and
foreign investment policy, and moral suasion. However, the most
sustained campaign has been waged against taxes. The point of this
campaign was first to reduce the progressivity of the tax system in
order to disable it as a policy instrument that could be used to
redistribute income and wealth and then to introduce tax cuts in order
to defund the welfare state.
In the United States the attack on taxes was pioneered by
businessman Howard Jarvis and embodied in the anti-tax movements that
started in California and spread across a dozen states in the late
1970s. The crusade went national as Ronald Reagan made tax cuts the
centrepiece of his successful drive for the presidency. The tax revolt
quickly spread to other countries. Initially, the state proved
surprisingly resilient to attack. One obvious explanation is that
citizens in most countries valued the social equality, community
cohesion, economic security, and other more tangible benefits that their
taxes purchased. Taxes continued to increase in all but three
industrialized countries throughout the 1980s: in the average OECD country total tax revenue as a percentage of GDP increased by over three
per cent during this decade. Nevertheless, the sustained attacks on
taxes as instruments of government policy slowly started having an
effect. The level of taxes as a percentage of GDP stabilized in the
first half of the 1990s and in many countries declined. In the latter
half of the 1990s, not only have higher taxes, and therefore new
government programs, been ruled politically off the agenda in most
countries, but also existing spending programs are being dismantled or
retrenched in order to finance lower taxes.
A bewildering array of arguments have been employed to justify tax
reductions. Many of these arguments are economic in character. The
supply-side arguments about the debilitating effects of taxation on the
desire to work and save are still in vogue, although the exaggerated
claims made about the effect of tax reductions on economic growth and
government revenues in the early 1980s have been considerably toned
down. The widespread concern over the lack of job creation in many
countries over the past decade has lead tax-cutters to add the adverse
effect of taxes on employment to their arsenal of arguments. Then, as a
supposed knock-down argument, it is commonly alleged that the forces of
globalization have placed a definitive cap on higher taxes. New
production technologies, electronic commerce, the information
revolution, and the dismantling of protectionist barriers have greatly
increased the mobility of financial and investment capital and
high-skilled labour. These resources can now rapidly seek their highe st
after-tax rate of return anywhere on the globe. Economic arguments of
this kind have undoubtedly softened up the electorate for tax
reductions, however, they appear to have had less force than their
proponents anticipated. Perhaps they have not carried much political
weight since they have found little support in the mainstream economic
literature and are contradicted by most people's experience and
common sense.
Consequently, in the most recent round of tax-bashing, the
arguments have shifted from those that are factually based to conceptual
and normative arguments. Despite the essential functions that taxes play
in a democratic society, they have been reconceptualized in a way that
makes them appear as illegitimate and inherently undesirable. They are
frequently characterized as "impositions" over which taxpayers
have no control, "burdens" from which they derive no benefit,
and as purchasing "luxuries" that in these difficult economic
times are no longer affordable. Normatively, taxes are implied to
enslave taxpayers until they have worked enough months in the year to
finance their annual tax liabilities, to restrict their personal
choices, and to constitute an unjustified interference with their
private property. Moreover, reducing taxes will allow the deserving to
be rewarded, revitalize civic society, foster fairness for families, and
renew the nation. The prevailing anti-tax rhetoric suggests that
lowering taxes is not only a cost-free thing to do, but also the moral
and liberating thing to do.
In the ongoing battle to shape public opinion about the obligations
of citizenship, those who oppose taxes have been able to gain control
over public discussions by very cleverly misconceptualizing taxes and by
making moralistic assertions about taxes that, while sounding plausible,
rest upon highly contentious moral judgments. By the use of such
rhetoric, to an astonishing degree, the tax-cutters have been able to
impose their vocabulary on the public discussion of tax issues. All
words and phrases assume a set of understandings or shared meanings, of
course. Thus when people adopt a particular vocabulary to discuss a
public policy issue they often unconsciously find themselves unable to
imagine or at least easily discuss alternatives.
This tax-cutting agenda is profoundly wrong. In the long run it
will increase social inequality, result in national economies being less
productive, result in civil societies being less flourishing, and it
will ultimately lead to social disintegration and a loss of a sense of
connectedness between people. None of the pressing social and economic
problems facing most industrialized countries, such as the burgeoning
number of people living in poverty, the increasing inequality in the
distribution of market income and wealth, stagnating family incomes,
reduced rates of productivity growth, or fragmented labour markets, will
be solved by persons acting individually through markets, families, or
the voluntary sector. They will only be solved by citizens acting
collectively through democratically controlled institutions. What is
ultimately at stake over the issue of whether more or less taxes should
be collected, and thus whether people should rely more or less on public
ordering processes in the pursuit of their a spirations, is the question
of who will exercise power in society.
Reducing the role of government and increasing the emphasis on
private markets necessarily involves making those who exercise power in
the private sector more powerful, and those who benefit from the
distribution of market forces richer. There is no question that taxes
and government transfers leave working people more secure, healthier,
better educated, and more protected against business threats; therefore,
more able to win their fair share of national income in the long run.
That is to say, taxes and government expenditures not only change the
way that national income is distributed in the short-run, but also they
change the relative balance of power between workers and business
interests in the long run, in a way that reduces at least slightly the
economic power that business has over workers. Consequently, as taxes
are reduced, power is shifted from the majority of citizens where it is
exercised through democratically elected public institutions to a small
number of rich and powerful people where it is e xercised through
private markets.
When conservative governments introduce dramatic tax cuts, even
though they are opposed by the majority of citizens, government
spokespersons are fond of saying that if individual taxpayers do not
want the tax reductions they can give their money to a charity, a
church, or some other group that they wish to support. But such a
suggestion misconceives the problem of collective action. No one person,
or even no large group of persons, can solve the social problems facing
Canada and its provinces. By attempting to characterize taxes as
impositions, burdens, unaffordable, restrictions on freedom and choice,
and an interference with private property, business interests and others
who exercise power through "private" markets have attempted to
persuade individuals to give up on one another as citizens and go it
alone as consumers. This may work for the rich, but it will greatly
reduce the quality of life for the average family. In the longer run it
will tear the social fabric. Taxes are one of the most important way s
that, as a community of citizens engaged in a common project,
individuals discharge their mutual responsibilities to one another, to
the benefit of everyone.