The impact of stock options compensation on earnings and probability of bankruptcy.
Akindayomi, Akinloye ; Warsame, Hussein A.
INTRODUCTION
As the debate around excessive corporate executive compensation
heats up in the United States in the era of Troubled Asset Relief
Program (TARP) (1), the debate on the efficacy of stock options
compensation is not yet settled. The restrictions on executive salaries
and bonuses by firms that benefitted from TARP is likely to spread to
comparable companies in the US. To avoid high political costs while at
the same time keeping the option of providing incentives for managers to
optimize firm value, Board of Directors may opt to increase equity
related compensations such as stock options.
The objective of this study is to investigate the impact of stock
options compensation on earnings and probability of bankruptcy of the
firm. Hanlon, Rajgopal and Shevlin 2003 (HRS) document the incentive
alignment hypothesis of executive stock options, but the authors use
reported operating performance as the dependent measure. We argue that
the positive contributions of executive stock options to reported
earnings documented in that study could have been exaggerated if one
considers the real potentials of earnings management, and so corporate
boards and compensation committees should exercise caution in the
interpretations of HRS finding. Therefore, in part, we examine executive
stock options contributions to other measure of earnings after
controlling for earnings management using nondiscretionary earnings as a
dependent measure. While we find a positive contribution consistent with
incentive alignment, the magnitude of such contribution is substantially
lower. This suggests that nondiscretionary earnings will be a better
measure of corporate performance as a guide for executive compensation
decisions.
Prior studies have examined empirically and analytically a variety
of issues ranging from the role of taxes in the decision to grant
options (e.g., Klassen and Mawani, 2000), the choice between incentive
stock options and nonqualified options (e.g., Austin et al, 1998), the
tax deductibility of stock options (e.g., Balsam et al., 1996 &
1997; Mawani, 2003a), to the firm's disclosure behavior around the
granting of the options (e.g., Aboody and Kasznik, 2000) as well as the
tax and accounting income consideration for the cancellation of
executive stock options (e.g., Mawani 2003b). However, very few (e.g.,
HRS; Kato et al, 2005; Sanders and Hambrick, 2007) have attempted to
provide direct evidence of the impact of executive stock options on the
firm's earnings. HRS conclude that every dollar of stock options
(using Black-Scholes values) granted to the top five executives
contributes $3.71 to future operating earnings of the company over the
next five years. Kato et al. (2005), using Japanese data and an event
study methodology, also conclude that operating performance improves
with stock options. However Sanders and Hambrick (2007) have shown that
while stock options do affect CEO behaviors, their heavy use produces
more losses than gains. Other agency theorists wondered whether the
traditional ESO plans for executives are not leading to creative ways of
managing earnings while ignoring the cost of equity (Jensen, Murphy, and
Wruck, 2004).
These mixed results are manifestations that the question of whether
stock options induce mangers to take appropriate actions is still not
settled. Researchers using the incentive alignment hypothesis argue that
stock options compensation could be utilized to reduce the incentives
asymmetry between managers and shareholders (e.g., Rajgopal and Shevlin,
2002; HRS; Mawani, 2003a). However, other researchers using the rent
extraction hypothesis argue that this compensation package can be a
conduit of transferring wealth from shareholders to management/top
executives (e.g., Johnson 2003; Aboody and Kasznik, 2000; Baker,
Collins, and Reitenga, 2003).
Our study is motivated by the need to fill this important gap in
the literature with the intent to examining the impact of granting
options to top corporate executives on the firms' earnings and the
probability of bankruptcy, and by extension the value of the firm. We
build on the future operating earnings-based model used by HRS which we
believe has advantages over models using ex-post stock price performance
like that used by Kato et. (2005) Future operating earnings do not
suffer from stockholder expectation problem embedded in ex-post price
performance of shares. We adjust HRS's model for challenges
suggested by HRS and Larker (2003). We use the nondiscretionary
component of earnings to avoid problems caused by earnings management.
As HRS recognize, if some firms overstate or understate earnings the
results "might reflect earnings management as a function of ESO
grant values rather than economic payoffs" (HRS, pp 37). We also
took into account the alternative "forward-looking" research
design suggested by Larcker (2003) to address similar research questions
raised by HRS.
Furthermore, we use Altman's Z-score to test suggestions in
the literature that ESOs induce managers to take too many risks and may
cause financial distress. We use the probability of bankruptcy
represented by the Altman's Z-score as a proxy for a change in the
cost of equity. In effect, Altman's Z-score is inversely related to
the cost of equity. The higher the Altman's Z-Score, the lower is
the cost of equity. Results from our models are consistent with the
incentive alignment hypothesis and are inconsistent with the overall
conclusion of Sanders and Hambrick (2007) that stock options cause more
losses than gains. However, they are consistent with Sanders and
Hambrick (2007)'s less emphasized result that moderate levels of
stock options (20% to 50%) do actually induce executives to become more
risk neutral (less risk averse) with performance symmetrically divided
between losses and gains. The overall implication of our results is
that, at least in our sample of firms, partly compensating top
executives with stock options not only induces them to improve earnings,
it also motivates them to take moderate risks.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides the
theoretical background for the study and the hypotheses tested. Research
methodology and design are the subjects of section 3. Section 4 provides
the results and findings of the study. The final section provides a
summary and the potential limitations/constraints that this study may
face.
THEORETICAL BACKGROUND
Executive compensation constitutes a typical problem domain for
agency theory. The relationship between the shareholders and the
executives of a firm is one in which the two groups have partly
differing goals and risk preferences. Executives are thought to be more
risk averse than shareholders. This is due to the likelihood that
executives, whose incomes and reputation are tied to their firms, may
not have as many opportunities as shareholders to effect appropriate
levels of diversification for themselves (Eisenhardt, 1989).
Shareholders are more likely to be risk neutral, while executives are
more likely to be risk averse. The result would be that executives avoid
profitable projects with a probability of a downside, which may lead to
lower returns. Consistent with seminal works in agency theory (such as
Jensen and Meckling, 1976), the solution to the problem is to move the
executives' risk-averse preferences to risk-neutrality. Stock
options, not only add a feature of outcome-orientation to any salary
contract, which is primarily behavior-oriented, but they also increase
the firm ownership by executives which decreases opportunism. Basically,
any action taken by executives to reward themselves will simultaneously
reward the shareholders. This is the incentive alignment perspective
that makes some researchers (e.g. HRS; Kato et al) to argue that the
motivational potentials of stock options should motivate top executives
to act in a way that maximizes firm value.
However, the question that agency theorists were grabbling with
lately is whether the resultant executive behavior includes sensible
risk taking (Jensen et al, 2004; HRS; Sanders and Hambrick, 2007).
Researchers have shown that, while stock options have induced executives
to take more risks, there are doubts that these risks are value
enhancing. Sanders and Hambrick (2007) show that moderate levels of
stock options (20% to 50%) do induce executives to become more risk
neutral (less risk averse) with performance symmetrically divided
between losses and gains. On the other hand, more option-loaded
executives produced more big losses than big gains (Sanders and
Hambrick, 2007, p.1070). The extreme results of high option levels are
plausible given the fact that stock options bestow on holders the
opportunity to participate in the improved or enhanced share price
without directly partaking in the downside loss, if it eventually
occurs.
RESEARCH METHODOLOGY AND DESIGN
Consistent with the dictates of agency theory, the unit of analysis
for this problem domain is the contract between the shareholders
(principal) and the executives (agents). Specifically, we will look at
the impact of compensating top executives with stock options on earnings
and probability of bankruptcy of the firm. Earnings and probability of
bankruptcy have direct impact on firm value. However, instead of looking
at the value (2) of the firm directly, we will look at the accounting
return and a proxy for the risk incurred in earning that return (3). A
change in the expected earnings or a change in the rate used to discount
the future earnings or the combination of changes could cause a change
in the value of the firm. In other words, an increase (decrease) in
earnings or decrease (increase) in discount rate will lead to an
increase (decrease) in the value of the firm, all else equal.
Significant increase in the probability of bankruptcy will normally
increase the required rate of return used to discount future earnings
thus reducing the value of the firm. However, researchers are yet to
agree on whether or not the use of employee/executive stock option is
good for the shareholders and how it affects those components of firm
value [see for example, Johnson, 2003; Mawani, 2003a; HRS; Kato et al,
2005; Sanders and Hambrick, 2007). Testing for performance both in terms
of return (earnings) and in terms of risk may yield more compelling
evidence of stock option compensation efficacy.
Earnings
Earnings, in the accounting sense, are generally the difference
between revenues and expenses of operating activities. Due to the
tendencies of executives/managers to take leverage of their
discretionary powers in smoothing earnings, research in the earnings
management literature has indicated that reported earnings might not be
persistent and thus might not reflect the 'true' earnings
components. To estimate "true earnings", accounting scholars
proposed several methods to remove the effect of discretionary
components of earnings from the reported earnings (see for example,
Dechow et al, 1995; Jones, 1991; Gaver, 1995; Reitenga et al, 2002;
Baker et al, 2003; Kang and Sivaramakrishnan, 1995; Cohen and Zarowin,
2010). In this study, we follow the approaches of Dechow et al (1995) to
calculate 'nondiscretionary earnings' as a proxy for
'true' earnings. Therefore, in order to capture the effect of
our measure of earnings on the firm's value vis-a-vis executive
stock options compensation, we put forward the following two hypotheses
that relate to reported earnings ([H.sub.1]) and to nondiscretionary
(true) earnings ([H.sub.2]).
[H.sub.1]: Ceteris paribus, the higher the use of Executive stock
options, the higher the reported operating earnings of the firm.
In testing this hypothesis, we try to replicate the results of HRS
after adjusting for some missing variables suggested by Larker (2003).
Hypothesis 2 adjusts HRS for earnings management.
[H.sub.2]: Ceteris paribus, the higher the use of Executive stock
options, the higher the nondiscretionary earnings of the firm.
In hypothesis 1, the dependent measure is the reported operating
income and the estimated empirical model, using least squares
regression, is presented as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
Where:
OPINC = Operating Income before depreciation scaled by Sales of
firm i at time t.
TA = Total Assets of firm i at time t
BSO = Black-Scholes value of executive stock options granted to top
5 Executives. BSO is also squared to adjust for an observed
non-linearity in the relationship between BSO and OPINC.
R&D = Research and development expenses of firm i during the
year t - k (k = 0 - 5)
[sigma][(OPINC).sub.i,t-1] = Standard deviation of earnings
measures estimated over the prior 5 year, for firm i.
S = is the annual sales in time t.
Equation (1) above is the baseline model of HRS for examining the
incentives potential effects of executive stock options. However, this
baseline model does not control for previous firm's performance and
as argued by Larcker (2003), failure to control for previous firm's
performance ([OPINC/S.sub.i,t-1]) might be an essential omission in the
HRS baseline model. Therefore, in the spirit of Larcker (2003) argument,
we control for firm's previous performance and thus modify equation
1 as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
In order to examine the effect of earnings management vis-a-vis the
use of executive stock options, we replace OPINC/S in equation 1 and 2
with NDE/S (nondiscretionary earnings) as in
(3) and (4) below:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
All variables are as described in (1). The industry dummies are
based on a two-digit SIC code classification, unless otherwise stated,
while the year dummies represents the fiscal year when
operating/nondiscretionary is measured. All variables are scaled by
sales to control for possible size effects and the possibility of
heteroscedascticity. The standard deviation estimated over the prior 5
years is expected to control for the possible relation between firm risk
and future earnings. This is consistent with Core et al (1999)
specification (see also HRS). Other compensation related variables, such
as cash compensation and the number of exercisable options in the money,
that could simultaneously impact a firm's performance are also
controlled for in the sensitivity analysis section.
Nondiscretionary earnings are measured as nondiscretionary accrual plus cash flow from operations. Nondiscretionary accrual is measured
using modified Jones model as specified by Dechow et al (1995) and Gaver
et al (1995). This is calculated as:
[NDA.sub.it] = [a.sub.i] + [b.sub.1i]([DELTA][REV.sub.it] -
[DELTA][REC.sub.it]) + [b.sub.2i][PPE.sub.it] (5a)
The estimates of [a.sub.i], [b.sub.1], [b.sub.2] are generated from
the following model:
[TAC.sub.it] = [a.sub.i] + [b.sub.1i]([DELTA][REV.sub.it] -
[DELTA][REC.sub.it]) + [b.sub.2i][PPE.sub.it] + [[epsilon].sub.it] (5b)
[NDE.sub.it] = [NDA.sub.it] + [COP.sub.it] (5c)
Where:
[NDA.sub.it] = Nondiscretionary accruals;
[TAC.sub.it] = total accruals in year t for firm i, and it is
calculated as:
[TAC.sub.it] = [DELTA][CA.sub.t] - [DELTA][Cash.sub.t] -
[DELTA][CL.sub.t] + [DELTA][CM.sub.t] + [DELTA]Income Taxes
[Payable.sub.t] - Depreciation and Amortization [Expense.sub.t]
[NDE.sub.it] = Nondiscretionary earnings;
[COP.sub.it] = cash flow from operations;
[DELTA][REV.sub.it] = revenues in year t less revenues in year t -
1 for firm i;
[DELTA][REC.sub.it] = receivables in year t less receivables in
year t - 1 for firm i;
[DELTA] is the change and computed as the difference between time t
and t - 1.
[PPE.sub.it] = gross property, plant, and equipment at the end of
year t for firm i;
CA = Current Assets
CL = Current Liabilities
CM = current maturities of long term debt.
[[epsilon].sub.it] = error term for firm i;
The above baseline model (and by extension other models, excluding
5) are termed as "backward-looking" design by Larcker (2003)
and so he suggests that future research could explore the potentials of
"forward-looking" models. Taking up the challenge, and using
almost all the variables, we use an alternative model choice to the HRS
baseline model. The advantages of such "forward-looking" model
include the opportunity to efficiently maximize the sample size.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6a)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6b)
Similarly for the nondiscretionary earnings, we have:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7a)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7b)
(Definitions of variables are the same as described above.)
Measure of Risk
The probability of bankruptcy will be used to capture the
responsiveness of the firm's cost of discounting the earnings to
the use of stock options to compensating top executives. Johnson (2003)
argues that the use of stock options may encourage managers to pursue
suboptimal goals that maximize firms' earnings in the short term at
the expense of long term viability of the firm. The crest of the
argument is that, since stock options provide the executives an upside
potential without exposing them to a commensurate risk of the downside,
managers may take huge risks (Sanders and Hambrick, 2007). On the other
hand, if the claim of agency theorists that the use of stock options
ameliorates agency problems by aligning the incentives of managers to
those of the shareholders holds, then firms whose executives are
compensated more with stock options should have lower probability of
bankruptcy. As a result, the true relationship between the use of stock
options and the probability of bankruptcy becomes an empirical question.
We put forward the following hypothesis in the affirmative while
acknowledging the possibility of no or negative effect for the
aforementioned reasons.
[H.sub.3]: Ceteris paribus, the higher the use of Executive stock
options, the lower the probability of bankruptcy
We use the following equation to empirically test the effect of
stock options hypothesized in H3.
[PROBNKP.sub.it] = [[micro].sub.0] + [[micro].sub.1][BSO.sub.it] +
[[micro].sub.2][ERNVOL.sub.it] + [[micro].sub.3][SIZE.sub.it] +
[[micro].sub.4][GROWTH.sub.it] + [[micro].sub.5][LEV.sub.it] +
[[OMEGA].sub.it] (8)
Where:
[PROBNKP.sub.it] = probability of bankruptcy of firm i at time t.
This is measured using the Altman (1968) Z score.
[ERNVOL.sub.it] = earnings volatility of firm i at time t. This is
measured as the standard deviation of the firm's earnings per share
over the sample period.
[SIZE.sub.it] = size of firm i at time t. This is measured as total
assets at [sub.t-1]
[LEV.sub.it] = leverage of firm i at time t. This is measured as
the prior year long term debt to total equity capital of the firm.
[GROWTH.sub.it] = captures the market to book value over the prior
5 years.
[[OMEGA].sub.it] = error term.
Industries dummies will also be used to capture and control for the
cross sectional industry effects.
The inclusion of [BSO.sub.it] in equation (8) is only an attempt to
establish empirical relationship, not causation, between the use of
executive stock options and the failure of the firm. There are too many
reasons and potential causes of corporate failures/bankruptcy that will
prevent us from claiming causality in this regard.
There is consistent evidence in the literature that the degree of
firms' earnings volatility is an increasing function of the firms
cost of capital (see for example, Patell, 1976; Goel & Thakor, 2003;
Lacina, 2004; DeFond & Hung, 2003). ERNVOL is added to capture the
effect of earnings volatility. Earnings volatility is a decreasing
function of the quality of earnings in that the more volatile a
firm's earnings are, the noisier the investors' assessments of
such earnings with the potential consequence of diminishing the
earnings' perceived quality. As a result, before informed
investment decisions could be made, additional search costs are
implicitly imposed on investors as they will require additional sources
of information to allow for desirable interpretations and then make
informed judgments of such firm's volatile earnings. Goel and
Thakor (2003) suggest that "an increase in the volatility of
reported earnings will magnify these shareholders' trading
losses." No doubt, such additional costs will be impounded in the
required rate of returns for investment in such firms with the attendant increase in the firm's cost of capital. Alternative explanation for
the possible increase in the cost of capital as a result of a
firm's earnings volatility could be that since firms with high
volatile earnings will need to provide other types of disclosures and
information to market participants so as to mitigate the possible
negative market reactions, such contingent additional information are
not costless. (4)
LEV is expected to capture the operational uncertainty caused by
cost of debt. Ahmed et al (2002) empirically document that operational
uncertainty is one of the sources of "bondholder-shareholder
conflicts over dividend costs" and that mitigating such conflicts
could translate into the reduction in the firm's debt costs, and
thus consequently increasing the value of the firm, all else equal.
Titman and Wessels (1988) as cited by Dittmar (2004) provide evidence
that the firm's cost of debt increases the probability of a
firm's susceptibility to bankruptcy or financial distress (See Ngo,
2002; Mao, 2003).
GROWTH captures the relationship between probability of bankruptcy
and book-to-market values of firms. The extant literature shows that
firms with high probability of bankruptcy Z-score on average have low
book-to-market values (see Hahn et al, 2010; and Zaretzky & Zumwalt,
2007 for a review of this literature).
The proxy for the probability of bankruptcy (PROBNKP it), the
Altman (1968) Z score, will be calculated for individual sample firms
over the sample period as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
Generally, higher Z-score corresponds to lower probability of
bankruptcy. If a company has a Z-Score above 3, it is considered to be
healthy and, therefore, unlikely to enter bankruptcy. If the score is
lower than 1.8, the firm is in danger of bankruptcy. But if the Score is
between 1.8 and 3, it is in a grey area (Altman, 1968)
Sample Selection
This study covers all US firms with available data in the Execucomp
database as well as the Compustat tapes. The Execucomp database contains
the compensation data for the top five executives of individual firms in
the S&P 1500 (comprising those in the S&P 500 index, S&P 400
mid cap index and the S&P 600 small cap index). This data coverage
begins in 1992. We extract the necessary data regarding the
Black-Scholes value of an option from this database. For the entire
model, we start with an initial sample of 2,507 firms with 17,970 firm
years.
After interpolating and intersecting data from the two databases,
deleting missing observations and conducting other data screening
exercises, we have for the 'backward-looking' research design
858 firms with 2,579 firm-years. The forward-looking design comprises
three different model categories viz: n + 1, Sum n + 1 + 2 and Sum n + 1
+ 2 + 3 (where n is the grant year). Therefore, the first has 1,666
firms spanning 8,384 firm-years; the second has 1,476 firms with 6,666
firm-years and the third has 1,283 firms covering 5,357 firm-years (5).
We believe that the larger sample size and the longer sample period
relative to HRS better maximize the generalizability of findings in this
critically important area of compensation research in empirical
accounting.
To avoid complications caused by differences in reporting rules,
the sample firms are required to be incorporated in the US. This is
consistent with Matsunaga (1995). Also, regulated firms such as
utilities companies (SIC codes 4900-4999) and financial institutions
(SIC codes 6000-6099) are excluded so as to control for the differential
incentives and motivational situations faced by executives operating in
those regulatory environments relative to their counterparts in the
non-regulated industries.
ANALYSES AND RESULTS
In this section, we present the empirical results obtained in the
study and discus the implications of the findings for extant and future
research in the area. Commencing with the descriptive statistics for the
sampled firms in the 'backward-looking model, panel A of table 1
shows that the average firm in the sample generates annual sales worth
of 5.4 billion (median $1.7 billion) with an operating margin of
approximately 15%. The average firm in the sample has assets worth $5
billion (median $1.6 billion) with asset turnover rate of approximately
0.90. This suggests that firms in this category are fairly large and
profitable. The average value (BSO) of the executive stock options
granted to the top five executives of the sample firms is $7.758 million
(median $2.7 million). This is approximately 0.4% of operating revenues,
which is very similar to that reported in HRS.
Results
The coefficients from the regression and implied sensitivity
analyses undertaken for the respective models to estimate payoffs using
Black-Scholes values of executive stock option
Tables 2, 3 and 4, show information for firms in the
'forward-looking' models. Similar conclusion about size and
profitability of firms in the respective sample category could be
reached with the above descriptive information. Panel B of these tables
shows the correlation matrix of the individual variables of interest in
the respective models and virtually all the correlations are significant
at the conventional significance thresholds.
Regression Results
The coefficients from the regression and implied sensitivity
analyses undertaken for the respective models to estimate payoffs using
Black-Scholes values of executive stock option grants are presented in
tables 5 to 14 for both backward-looking and forward-looking models.
Discussion of the results vis-a-vis their implications are concurrently
presented as well.
Recall that due to the nonlinearity of the executive stock options
and the respective performance measures, a second order term was
introduced. BSO/S is the first order term while its square is the second
order-term. Consistent with the findings of HRS, the regression
coefficients of this second-order term was significantly negative in all
the model specifications. This significantly negative coefficient suggests concavity, meaning that executive stock option grants increase
performance at a reducing rate. Arguably, the inclusion of the
second-order term does appear to correct omitted variable bias and does
not seem to have induced our results. This is because there was no
single situation of sign-switching of any of the regression coefficients
of the primary variable of interest (which is BSO/S), the first-order
term, as a result of the inclusion of the second-order term, but
instead, the measure of goodness of fit statistic (adjusted R-Square) is
consistently improved across all models. Similarly, we include lag of
dependent measures in the respective models so as to control for prior
year performance. This is important because of the mean reverting nature
of the performance measures. Recall that HRS do not control for this in
their baseline regression model which is primarily
'backward-looking'. Therefore, as a result of the compelling
econometric justification for the inclusion of the second order term, as
well as lagged performance measures, which is consistent with
theoretical reasoning, considerable amount of our discussions will
centre on the nonlinear coefficients of both prior and current
performance measures with occasional references to the linear results
for comparison purposes, where necessary.
Backward-looking design
Tables 5 and 6 contain the regression coefficients of the lagged
design in panel A. Linear specifications of the respective models are
presented in columns 1 and 2, while their nonlinear counterparts are
contained in columns 3 and 4. There are 858 firms with 2,579 usable firm
year observations.
The coefficients of the primary variable of interest in the model
which is the additive sum of BSO/S, and perhaps the [(BSO/S).sup.2],
show positive and negative directions respectively in all the model
specifications. Looking at the nonlinear without previous performance
measures of column 3, panel A of tables 5 and 6, for reported
performance, the additive sum of these variables are respectively 0.348
and -0.171; 0.317 and -0.187 for nondiscretionary earnings. Column 4
shows the nonlinear with previous performance measures results. It shows
the additive sum coefficients for BSO/S and [(BSO/S).sup.2] as 0.408 and
-0.115, respectively in the reported performance model and 0.213 and
-0.042 in the nondiscretionary earnings model. All these coefficients
are highly significant.
The positive direction of these coefficients with respect to the
first order term (BSO/S) implies positive contributions of executive
stock options grants to both of our performance measures (reported
earnings and nondiscretionary earnings). In other words, regardless of
which earnings performance measures (reported, or 'true'
earnings), corporate use of executive stock options positively impacts
corporate performance. These findings provide extended, stronger and
corroborative support for the findings of HRS. If the coefficients on
BSO/S were to have been negative, consistent with the agency theory
literature, then there is evidence of rent extraction.
Notwithstanding the above assertion, it is important to note the
impact of introducing previous performance measures on the results.
Column 4 shows that introducing lagged dependent variable actually
increases BSO contributions for reported earnings (from 0.348 to 0.408),
but reduces same contribution with respect to nondiscretionary earnings
(from 0.317 to 0.213). We interpret these findings to mean that the
improvement in earnings attributable to the granting of stock options to
executives is not as high as implied by reported earnings when one
controls for earnings management and prior year's earnings
performance.
Panel B and C provide corroborative evidence of the results
presented in panel A of tables 5 and 6. These panels show economic
sensitivity (following HRS) of various BSO distributions to the
performance measures. This is computed as the change in each of the
dependent measures scaled by change in BSO/S, showing the economic
impact, i.e. the dollar value, on performance measures of changing the
median BSO up or down to next quartile cutoff, which in this instance is
first and third quartile respectively. Specifically, focusing on the
reported operating income without prior performance measure, if one
moves from the quartile 1 BSO/S cutoff value of 0.0005 to the median of
0.0012, the dependent measure, OPINC/S, would increase from 0.0002 to
0.0004 indicating an implied sensitivity of 0.35. Similarly, the
equivalent sensitivity for moving from the median to the 3rd quartile
cutoff is 0.35, note that without approximating to two decimal places,
in absolute decimal terms, this value is less than 0.35. According to HRS, the small slide in the implied sensitivities due to a shift from
the median to quartile 3 of BSO/S indicates that the second-order effect
of BSO/S is "economically" inconsequential, but that failure
to consider this second-order term "appears to create a significant
omitted variable in the linear specification".
From the implied sensitivity calculations, our results show that
there is positive economic contribution of executive stock option grants
to firm performance measures. For example, without prior performance
measures, a dollar grant of executive stock options to top 5 corporate
executives increase future reported operating performance by $1.35 and
future nondiscretionary earnings by $1.32. With lagged performance
measures, future reported operating performance increases by S1.41 and
nondiscretionary earnings by $1.21 Overall, while the BSO-performance
relation is positive, there is still some evidence of earnings
management. For example, while the reported income shows $1.41 increment in BSO contribution to future operating performance, if the concept of
'true' earnings is considered as in nondiscretionary earnings,
the contribution is only $1.21 or a reduction of 14%. This reduction is
economically significant given that the average value of stock options
granted by our sample firms is $7.8m in the backward model and around
$4.5m in the forward model.
The other variable of interest in the empirical analysis is the
research and development expenditure. R&D is an investment
expenditure that should impact the future performance of the firm.
Without controlling for this type of investment capital expenditure, one
might run the risk of excessively attributing BSO performance payoffs
(which may involve overestimating or underestimating error), hence the
importance of this variable in the empirical design. Controlling for
prior performance makes a difference in the sign of the coefficients of
this variable in the operating income model. This thus implies that
while it might appear that there is a positive contribution of the
R&D expenditure to future operating performance, once prior
performance is controlled for, this might not be the case. The same
variable in HRS is positive (but HRS do not control for prior
performance) and our result in column 4 of the panel A of table 5
challenges this result. Column 4 of table 6 also portrays a similar
result. However, with respect to the nondiscretionary earnings measure,
there is a consistently positive contribution of R&D expenditure to
this future performance measure. If nondiscretionary earnings measure is
truly a measure of 'true' earnings, then we will submit that
managers do make positive net present value investment commitments in
research and development expenditure.
Forward-looking design
As Larcker (2003) appropriately noted, the
'backward-looking' design approach employed by HRS is
susceptible to quite a few limitations and criticisms and so can be
improved upon. Some of the criticisms according to Larcker include its
restrictive sample size, restrictive sample period, and the real
potential reduction in the model explanatory power (6). He therefore
suggested a 'forward-looking' research design choices.
Responding to this challenge, we will re-investigate the research
question by re-specifying the empirical models using the
'forward-looking' empirical design in the following sequence:
n + 1 (i.e. Year + 1), Sum n + 1 + 2 (i.e. SumYear + 1 + 2) and Sum n +
1 + 2 + 3 (i.e. SumYear + 1 + 2 + 3); where n is the grant year.
Year +1 Empirical Model
With this model, we estimate the option-performance payoffs of
granting executive stock options to top 5 corporate executives in year n
and the contribution of such new grants to future performance in year
n+1, after controlling for necessary variables like corporate capital
expenditures in tangible assets and research and development
expenditure, prior performance measures as well as total cash
compensation to these target executives.
There are 1,666 firms with 8,384 usable number of firm year
observations for this empirical model. The regression coefficients and
the implied sensitivity analysis for this model, is contained in tables
7 and 8.
The primary variable of interests are BSO/S and [(BSO/S).sup.2].
These variables show highly significant positive and negative
coefficients signs respectively. For the operating income dependent
measure, the coefficients are 0.373 and -0.249 without prior
performance; 0.229 and 0.172 with prior performance. Nondiscretionary
earnings measure has 0.247 and -0.124, and -0.147 and -0.078 for model
without prior performance and that with prior performance respectively.
One of the important implications of these coefficients is that the
second-order term returning negative coefficients consistently in each
of the models attests to the concavity nature of the BSO-performance
relation, meaning that while executive stock options grants to top 5
corporate executives increase future performance, such relation is at a
decreasing rate. This also attests to the nonlinear nature of the
BSO-performance relation.
Another note worthy of mention is the fact that the coefficients of
BSO/S in each of the models are consistently reduced when prior
performances are controlled for. For example, for reported earnings
dependent measure, it reduces from 0.373 to 0.229 and from 0.247 to
0.147 for nondiscretionary earnings dependent measure. This speaks to
the fact that without controlling for this important variable, apart
from the serious omitted variable bias that such exclusion might
introduce into the models, the payoff estimates attributable to the
BSO/S variable will be wrongly overestimated (7).
Similarly, it is important to mention that the coefficients of
BSO/S are highest in reported operating performance measure model (0.373
and 0.229) compared to those of nondiscretionary performance measure
model (0.247 and 0.147). This consistent trend in significant
coefficients reduction empirically supports our conjecture that
performance contributions of executive stock options grants to top 5
corporate executives as indicated in the reported operating performance
might be overestimated relative to concepts of 'true' earnings
as reflected in nondiscretionary earnings measure. However, it is
important to note that, notwithstanding the probable performance
contributions overestimations, corporate grants of executive stock
options positively impact future performance, whether it is
accrual-earnings (susceptible to earnings management) or future
performance measures that are substantially 'accrual-free'.
The results of the implied sensitivity analysis contained in panels C
and D of the respective tables corroborates the position above. This
analysis shows that a dollar grant of executive stock options to top 5
corporate executive contributes $1.37 to future operating income without
controlling for prior performance and $1.23 when prior performance is
controlled for. Similarly, $1.25 and $1.15 are contributed to
nondiscretionary earnings without and with prior performance
respectively. These dollar contribution amounts support the discussions
above concerning the need to control for prior performance on one hand,
and earnings management potentials of managers to expansively maximize
their option payoffs on the other hand. In all, consistent with HRS
evidence, our findings make it difficult to reject the incentive
alignment hypothesis of corporate executive stock option grants, as
evidence supporting rent extraction hypothesis is largely absent in our
findings.
Other variables in the various models display expected trend and
significant coefficients characteristics. The TA/S variable produces
-0.136 and -0.151 with respect to the reported operating income
dependent measure without and with prior performance measures. Also, for
the nondiscretionary earnings, the coefficients are -0.187 and -0.072
respectively for with or without controlling for prior performance. We
believe that the negative significant coefficients of this variable is
actually reflecting assets turnover characteristics and so, it might not
be inappropriate to interpret the coefficients in absolute terms as
these significant coefficients indicate that managers productively
utilize their corporate tangible assets in generating future earnings.
The coefficients of the capital expenditure on research and
development expenditure (R&D/S) also show patterns that appear
similar to productive corporate performance. The highly significant
coefficients are 0.252 and 0.072 for reported operating income dependent
measure, and 0.314 and 0.061 for nondiscretionary earnings dependent
measure without and with prior performance respectively.
In addition, the variable controlling for the total cash
compensation components of top 5 corporate executive, (TCC/S) shows
surprising coefficients signs, in the respective models. These
coefficients respectively without and with prior performance are -0.179
and -0.066, and -0.504 and -0.257 for the reported operating earnings
and nondiscretionary earnings dependent measures respectively. We
believe that it is important to control for this variable so as to
determine whether, after remunerating top 5 corporate executives with
regular salaries and cash bonuses as well as other forms of cash
compensation, executive stock options grants are still capable of
impacting positively future performance. HRS do not control for this
variable in their baseline model (8), but we consider this a potential
source of omitted variable bias and so decide to control for it in our
study, especially if one considers the analytical argument of Tian (2004) on the substitution effect of cash compensation for options. He
argues that the value or the incentive effects of an option to
executives reduces quickly as more cash pay is substituted for options.
Interestingly but surprisingly and somewhat puzzling, this variable
(TCC/S) shows highly significant negative coefficients consistently
across all the respective models. This suggests that remunerating top 5
executives with salary and other cash bonuses effectively de-motivates
them and thus reduces future performance measures. While we might agree
to a reasonable extent with the fact that top corporate executives
cannot be effectively motivated by only cash compensation in the glowing
era of executive stock options, we would have expected this variable to
be insignificant or at best less significant. But the intriguing thing
is that even recent studies in the compensation literature find (what we
will call) same anomaly significant negative coefficients (see HRS).
Matolcsy (2000) documents what he refers to as "counterintuitive findings", a significant negative relationship between CEO's
cash compensation and corporate performance. A completely different
interpretation that we can give in this instance is that if a firm uses
increasing amount of cash to compensate its top executives, investable
cash for worthy positive net present value investment opportunities
declines and this could reduce future corporate performance. Future
studies that aim at resolving this somewhat counterintuitive finding can
be a wonderful contribution to the compensation literature.
The coefficients of the previous performance measures in the
respective models exhibit expected pattern or directions, that is,
positively related to future performance measures. Findings for the
Sumyear +1 +2 and SumYear +1 +2 +3 empirical models are substantially
similar with the Year + 1 model (See tables 9 through 12), thus allowing
generalization regarding the three forward-looking models.
Overall, both the lagged model (i.e. 'backward-looking')
design and the 'forward-looking' model design findings
collectively and consistently provide strong evidence of incentive
alignment hypothesis, meaning that it is in the interests of
shareholders to remunerate top corporate executives with executive stock
options as this corporate granting behavior strongly motivates
executives towards improving future corporate performance, an action
that will be in the interest of shareholders. The evidence becomes more
compelling as the findings consistently hold if one considers not only
reported operating performance measures, but the other measure of
earnings believed to reflect the concept of 'true'
performance. The latter performance measure is devoid of managers
earnings management actions, motivations for which are stronger when
there are opportunities to maximize compensation payoffs such as one can
find in executive stock options.
Probability of bankruptcy as a proxy for cost of discounting
earnings
As explained earlier, the value of the firm can be explained by
corporate earnings and the cost of discounting the earnings. While the
above analyses, results and discussions center substantially on the
earnings components (numerator) of the concept of the value of the firm,
we will be examining the twin of this (denominator) in this section, and
this is the cost of discounting the earnings using a measure of the
probability of bankruptcy as developed by Altman Z-Score as a proxy (9).
We do not use bond rating as a measure of firms' financial
soundness for three essential reasons. First, extant research reveals
that usually, bonds attract serious analysts' attentions during
their first issuance or at infrequent extraordinary or special events,
and such attentions diminish substantially thereafter (Holthausen and
Leftwich, 1986). Second, corroborating this position, Wilson and Fabozzi
(1990) provide evidence of the discontinuous nature of bond ratings. The
final reason is the fact that Howe (1997) notes that there is usually a
delay between when the corporate conditions change and when the ratings
of the underlying bonds is actually done. Hence, bond ratings may
provide a distorting lag that can generate otherwise inappropriate
empirical findings to our research question in this instance.
Another potential alternative to the use of accounting-based
measures as ingredients in probability of bankruptcy prediction model is
stock market information. However, the challenge would be how to extract
relevant probability of bankruptcy information from stock prices (see
Beaver, 1968; Ohlson, 1980 and Cheung, 1991). This challenge becomes
compelling if one considers the fact that the stock market may be
inefficiently positioned (as it is often the case) to incorporate in a
timely fashion, all relevant and publicly available information into the
security prices (see for example, Sloan, 1996).
The results for the empirical investigation relating to this
measure is contained in table 13, where we have the descriptive
statistics and correlation matrix coefficients, and table 14 where the
regression coefficients are presented. These results are discussed in
sequence below.
Descriptive statistics
Here, we present the descriptive statistics of the sample relating
the use of executive stock options to remunerate top 5 corporate
executives and the probability of corporate failure, as measured by the
Altman's Z-Score. In this sample, we have 1,507 firms with firm
year observations totaling 8,217. The firms that on the average granted
approximately $4.3 million (median $1.7 million) in executive stock
options to its top 5 executives, measured by the Black-Scholes option
value as reported by the Execucomp data base,, are considered large,
profitable and employ sizeable amount of long term debt components in
their capital structures, as measured by the size of their assets,
earnings per share composition and the leverage status respectively.
Large number of firms in the sample also shows promising growth status
as measured by the market-to-book value ratio.
On the average, the firms in the sample made approximately $4
billion (median $1.2 billion) in revenue with $3.668 billion (median
$1.0 billion) in tangible assets, and carrying long term debt of a
little above 30% (median 29%) of their invested capital. On the average,
the firms in the sample have approximately 4.79 (median 3.47) Z-Score
suggesting a relatively low probability of bankruptcy. According to the
bankruptcy prediction model of Atman (1968), if the model returns a
value less than 1.81, there is a high probability of bankruptcy and if a
value greater than 3.0 is produced, then there is low probability of
bankruptcy. The values between 1.81 and 3 are in grey areas. The firms
in the sample on the average have lower probability of corporate
failure.
Regression results of the probability of bankruptcy model
The results for the regression coefficients are presented in table
14. The variables contained in the model are BSO/S, SIZE, TCC/S, ERNVOL,
GROWTH and LEV. As was done in the testing of the effect on earnings, we
scaled these variables mainly to minimize heteroscedascticity effects on
the models as well as allowing for cross-sectional pooling of sampled
firms with varying scale levels. The adjusted R-Square of the empirical
model is 0.213. The primary variable of interest in the model is the
BSO/S and as shown in Table 14, its coefficient is highly significant.
This coefficient and its positive sign suggest that a point increase in
the use of executive stock options to remunerate top 5 corporate
executives leads to 0.046 point increase in the Altman Z-Score
statistic, thus implying lower probability of corporate failure. This
result corroborates the earnings components results discussed above.
The variable that captures earnings volatility (ERNVOL) appears to
support the above comments. This variable has a positive coefficient of
0.032. This coefficient is significant (t-value of 3.04) suggesting that
companies with higher earnings volatility have lower probability of
corporate failure as a point increase in the volatility measure
increases the Z-score by 0.032. However, the relationship between the
use of stock options and corporate earnings volatility is worth
mentioning. Empirically, there is a positive relationship between the
use of this form of compensation package and the measure of earnings
volatility. This means that the more the options used to remunerate top
5 corporate executives, the more volatile are corporate earnings.
In other words, granting stock options encourages managers to
increase corporate volatility as the value of the options increase,
among others, in the volatility of underlying stock returns, implying
that stock options presage future volatility. Similarly, larger firms
(captured by SIZE) have lower volatile returns and that companies with
high volatile earnings are less levered, as such companies may not be
attractive debtor-customers to lenders. Also, note that the relationship
between the volatility variable and the corporate growth status is
positive, suggesting that high growth firms are more likely to
experience high earnings volatility. Cui and Mak (2002) document that
this category of firms faces substantial operating uncertainty and
business risk and that these usually lead in the direction of
"significant variation in their profit rate, making accounting
figures less informative about managerial performance", all of
which will likely translate into corporate volatility.
Notwithstanding Cui and Mark (2002) position, the data here produce
empirical results consistent with the original rationale for granting
options which is to encourage managers into aggressive but profitable
risk-taking behavior. The quality of such risk taking activities of
executives (as empirically shown in this paper) is reflected in the fact
that the volatility of corporate earnings does not result into increased
chances of corporate failure. In fact, it actually reduces it.
Overall, the message here is that granting stock options presages
future volatility and thus can increase the potential of corporate
failure, consequently leading to high probability of bankruptcy
especially in high growth firms with considerable high earnings
volatility. We must admit that this conclusion is based on the fact that
financial indicators determine corporate chances of bankruptcy. However,
research in strategic management and related literature suggests that
financially sound and economically worthy corporations can file for
bankruptcy for strategic reasons (see for example, Moulton and Thomas,
1993; Shrader and Hickman, 1993; Bell, 1994; Tavakolian, 1995; Daily,
1996; Foust, 2000; Bhattacharya et al, 2007). Rose-Green and Dawkins
(2002) distinguish between "financial bankruptcies" and
"strategic bankruptcies", claiming that firms in the former
categories are more likely to exhibit unimpressive financial indices
than firms in the latter group. They conjecture and find that the market
reaction to corporate bankruptcy situation discriminates between these
two bankruptcy motivations and appropriately penalizes those firms that
are compelled into bankruptcy by financial reasons more than those who
choose to be strategically 'bankrupt'. Therefore, on the
strength of these findings, the rationale for bankruptcy is not a
first-order concern for our study as the market appropriately sees
through this and reacts accordingly.
Sensitivity Analysis
Robustness checks are conducted to subject the sensitivities of the
empirical findings presented and discussed above to alternative scalar choice, intensity of the research and developments expenditure as well
as varied sample period. Unreported results indicate that findings are
substantially comparable with those of the main analysis.
In order to control for possible firm specific effects, i.e.
firm-specific shocks that are constant over time, we run fixed effect
regression using the STATA statistical software. The magnitudes of the
coefficients closely approximate those presented earlier. For example,
for the Year + 1 empirical model, the coefficients of the primary
variables of interest i.e. BSO/S and [(BSO/S).sup.2] in the new
regression are 0.231 and - 0.176 respectively for the reported earnings
after controlling for prior performance. These were respectively 0.229
and -0.172 in the main regressions. In both instances, these
coefficients are significant at 1% significance level, although the
adjusted R-Squared is slightly higher in the fixed effects regression
(0.552 as against 0.536).
Further, since almost half of the companies in the Compustat
database have missing values for R&D, we assign zero to many firms
in our sample for the R&D variable. As indicated earlier, this is
consistent with the approach maintained in the prior literature.
Notwithstanding, we subject our empirical findings to a sensitivity test
with regard to R&D variable by considering the research and
development-only-firms in order to rule out the possibility that this
variable could have driven the empirical results. For the Year + 1
forward-looking model, firm year observations reduces from 8,384 to
4,256 and the number of firms in the sample drops to 874 from 1,666. The
coefficients of BSO/S and [(BSO/S).sup.2] in the new regression are
0.329 (0.244) and - 0.254 (-0.143) respectively for the reported
earnings (nondiscretionary earnings) after controlling for prior
performance. The dollar contributions of the reported earnings
(nondiscretionary earnings) are $1.33 ($1.24) albeit an increase over
the full sample of $1.23 ($1.15) respectively. These findings suggest a
consistent positive contribution pattern in the performance benefits of
executive stock option grants.
In addition, in order to address the concerns of potential
confounding effects of the relatively scanty 1992 executive compensation
data in our sample since 1992 was the first year Execucomp Database
emerges, we remove observations for that year resulting into a shortened
sample size. For Year + 1 empirical model, this exercise results into a
loss of 250 firm year observations of only seven firms, producing 8,134
instead of 8,384 firm year observations and 1,659 instead of 1,666 firms
contained in the full sample. BSO/S and [(BSO/S).sup.2] have
coefficients of 0.228 (0.147) and -0.172 (-0.078) respectively for
reported earnings (nondiscretionary earnings). The dollar contribution
is exactly the same amount with the main analysis, i.e. $1.23 ($1.15).
In order to investigate whether the empirical findings are
sensitive to alternative scalar choices, we restate the model using
current year value of total assets. We consider this analysis worthwhile
more importantly because the coefficient of the variable TA/S is
consistently negative in virtually all empirical models in the main
analyses. Recall that we interpreted this to mean that the variable is
actually exhibiting the asset turnover relations in the models,
considering the fact that it is scaled with sales. Therefore, in order
to further examine this, we scale this variable and other variables in
the model by total asset and the coefficient sign of the variable TA/S
becomes positive in all the models in addition to the variables of
interests displaying consistent coefficients in signs and magnitude. For
example, for a Year + 1 model, reported performance (nondiscretionary
earnings) after controlling for prior performances produces BSO/S and
[(BSO/S).sup.2] equal to 0.201 (0.150) and -0.094 (0.090) respectively.
It must be noted that the pattern of consistent results of the
sensitivity analyses with the main analyses holds across the all the
empirical models be it 'backward-looking-design or
'forward-looking-design'.
Overall, the theme or tenor of the findings remains substantially
unaffected as a result of these sensitivity and additional analyses.
Notwithstanding, it is important to mention that like any other research
endeavor especially of empirical nature, certain caveats could weaken or
impact the conclusions or inferences from the findings of this study.
For example, the sample selection criteria may induce survivorship bias,
even though such criteria appear reasonable and acceptable in the domain
of empirical accounting research. Also, one cannot completely rule out
the potential bias of correlated omitted variables as it will be
extremely difficult, if not impossible to envisage and account for all
relevant variables in a model. Bearing in mind that it is always tricky to appropriately foretell the direction, level and magnitude of any bias
if it exists; noting these caveats is considered appropriate. In
addition, we must mention that there is the real concern about the
potential problem(s) of endogeneity, and that the tenor of our empirical
results may change if appropriate instrumental variables are found in
this setting. This is another promising area for future research efforts
in this area of compensation research.
Similarly, the total generalizability of this study's findings
cannot be guaranteed. This is because, we only consider a somewhat short
time-series of new executive stock option grants, spanning only 10 years
(i.e. 1992-2001), and performance measures of only 12 years (i.e.
1993-2004) (10). This thus speaks to the generalizability of the
empirical findings reported in this study beyond this time frame. Also
it should be recalled that this study uses executive stock options value
measured by the Black-Scholes option pricing model. This model is not
immune from criticisms among academics, compensation consultants and
practitioners alike, as they have consistently pointed to its
shortcomings. Therefore, the findings of this study can only be as good
as this option pricing model. Finally, there could be measurement error
in the variables of choice and this could limit the interpretations of
the findings of this study.
Notwithstanding the potential limitations highlighted above, the
theme of this study and its findings contribute to the compensation
literature and empirical accounting studies in significant dimensions.
For example, the findings of this study provide some of the first
evidence and probing insights into the option-performance relation
within the dynamics of corporate earnings and the cost of discounting
such earnings. In this study, we exclude financial firms and other firms
in regulated industries. It could be a fruitful future research effort
to examine the option-payoffs relations in these industries. The
starting point for such studies would be to take care of or control for
the peculiarities of these industries vis-a-vis the unique agency
relationship and earnings management incentives that subsist in them. In
addition, given the relatively short sample period of this study,
subsequent studies could evaluate the robustness and thus, the
generalizability of this study's findings to longer time periods
and by extension, larger cross-section of sample firms.
CONCLUSION
Granting stock options is a strategic corporate activity aimed at
achieving certain corporate objectives, theoretically in the overall
shareholders' ultimate interests. Executive stock options
compensation has continued to remain an increasingly substantial
component of management compensation packages.
Not many studies have provided direct evidence of the impact of
executive stock options on the primary components of firm value which
include earnings and cost of discounting the earnings. A notable
exception is the study of Hanlon, Rajgopal and Shevlin, 2003 (HRS) which
examined the executive stock options vis-a-vis future earnings of the
firm. However, our findings extend HRS findings by showing in part that
nondiscretionary measure could be a more appropriate guide to
compensation committees and corporate boards when making executive
compensation decisions. In fact, our findings could have potential
public policy implications and ramifications giving the contemporariness
of executive compensations in the debates surrounding current global
economic turmoil. Generally, studies on employees/executive stock
options appear to assume that the value of the firm is impacted by the
use of this compensation package and thus build the focus of their
investigations on this premise (see for example Akindayomi, 2010 for a
review of relevant literature). While such an assumption could be well
placed, it is yet sufficiently unclear which component of the firm value
is individually or jointly impacted by the use of stock options to
compensate executives. Therefore, this study is motivated by the need to
fill this important gap (and generally the taken-for-granted view) in
the literature, with the intent to examining the impact of granting
options to top corporate executives on the firms' earnings, cost of
capital and by extension the value of the firm.
The concept of accounting earnings and the cost of discounting such
earnings are central to the value of the firm. Theoretically, therefore,
the effect of using stock options to compensate executives should be
reflected in those two major components of the firm value i.e. the
earnings component and the cost of capital or discount rate associated
with the earnings. Thus, central to this study is the firms' cost
of discounting earnings, as well as the various measures of earnings.
The volatility of the firm's earnings and the probability of
bankruptcy are used to capture the responsiveness of the firm's
cost of capital to the use of stock options to compensating top
executives, while the measures of earnings employed are the reported
operating earnings and 'nondiscretionary' earnings. Overall,
both the lagged model (i.e. 'backward-looking') design and the
'forward-looking' model design findings collectively and
consistently provide strong evidence of incentive alignment hypothesis,
meaning that it is in the interests of shareholders to remunerate top
corporate executives with executive stock options as this corporate
granting behavior strongly motivates executives towards improving future
corporate performance, an action that will be in the interest of
shareholders. The evidence becomes more compelling as the findings
consistently hold if one considers not only reported operating
performance measures, but the other measure of the earnings believed to
reflect the concept of 'true' performance as such a
performance measure is devoid of managers earnings management actions,
motivations for which are stronger when there are opportunities to
maximize compensation payoffs like one can find in executive stock
options. In other words, we could not find support for the competing
rent extraction hypothesis, as executive stock option grants improve
future corporate performance as measured by the earnings measures.
Corroboratively, the empirical findings in relation to the proxy of
cost of discounting earnings as measured by the Altman Z-Score statistic
of bankruptcy probability also reinforce the earnings components
findings, even as volatility increases in executive stock option grants.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The authors acknowledge helpful comments by Amin Mawani and Steven
Balsam on the earlier version of this paper, as well as feedback by
colleagues in University of Calgary and University of Texas - Pan
American, the participants of the AAA Southeastern 2008 meeting in
Birmingham, Alabama, and the participants of Canadian Academic
Accounting Association (CAAA) 2009 meeting in Montreal. This paper was
nominated for best paper award in the AAA Southeastern 2008 meeting in
Birmingham, Alabama. It then received the "Distinguished Research
Award" from the Academy of Accounting and Financial Studies.
Akindayomi A, also likes to thank members of his dissertation committee
as this piece is a part-product of his doctoral dissertation at
University of Calgary. The authors will also like to acknowledge the
research grant by the CGA Alberta Faculty Fellowship.
REFERENCES
Aboody, D., & R. Kasznik (2000). CEO stock option awards and
the timing of corporate voluntary disclosures. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 29(1), 73-100.
Ahmed, A. S., B. K. Billings, R. M. Morton & M. S. Harris
(2002). The role of accounting conservatism in mitigating
bondholder-shareholder conflicts over dividend policy and in reducing
debt costs. The Accounting Review, 77(4), 867-890.
Akindayomi, A. (2010). Executive stock options and firm valuation:
A literature review and research framework. International Journal of
Business Excellence, 3(4), 470-493.
Altman, E. I. (1968). Financial ratios, discriminant analysis, and
the prediction of corporate bankruptcy. Journal of Finance, 23(4),
589-609.
Antle, R., & A. Smith (1986). An empirical investigation of the
relative performance evaluation of corporate executives. Journal of
Accounting Research, 24(1), 1-39.
Austin, J. R., J. J. Gaver, & K. M. Gaver (1998). The choice of
incentive stock options vs. nonqualified options: A marginal tax rate perspective. Journal of the American Taxation Association, 20(2), 1-21.
Baker, T., D. Collins & A. Reitenga (2003). Stock option
compensation and earnings management incentives. Journal of Accounting,
Auditing and Finance, 18(4), 557.
Balsam, S., & D. H. Ryan (1996). Response to tax law changes
involving the deductibility of executive compensation: A model
explaining corporate behavior. Journal of the American Taxation
Association, 18(Supplement), 1-11.
Balsam, S., R. Halperin & H. A. Mozes (1997). Tax costs and
nontax benefits: The case of incentive stock options. Journal of the
American Taxation Association, 19(2), 19-37.
Beaver, W. (1968). Market prices, financial ratios, and the
prediction of failure. Journal of Accounting Research, 6(2), 179 -192.
Bell, T. (1994). Discussion of auditor litigation and modified
reporting on bankrupt clients. Journal of Accounting Research,
32(Supplement), 1-31.
Bernard, V. L. (1995). The Feltham-Ohlson framework: implications
for empiricists. Journal of Accounting Research, 11(2), 733-747.
Bhattacharya, N., M. Dawkins & L. Bamber (2007). Systematic
share price fluctuations after bankruptcy fillings and the investors who
drive them. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42(2),
399-420.
Clement, M., R. Frankel, & J. Miller (2003). Confirming
management earnings forecasts, earnings uncertainty, and stock returns.
Journal of Accounting Research, 41(4), 653-679.
Chen, K. C., & K. C. Wei (1993). Creditors' decisions to
waive violations of accounting-based debt covenants. The Accounting
Review, 68(2), 218-232.
Cheung, J. (1991). A review of option-pricing theory in accounting
research. Journal of Accounting Literature, 10, 51 -84
Cohen, D.A., & P. Zarowin (2010). Accrual-based and real
earnings management activities around seasoned equity offerings. Journal
of Accounting and Economics, 50(1), 2-19.
Core, J., R. Holthausen & D. Larcker (1999). Corporate
governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance.
Journal of Financial Economics, 51(3), 371-406.
Cui, H. & Y. T. Mak (2002). The relationship between managerial
ownership and firm performance in high R&D firms. Journal of
Corporate Finance, 8(4), 313-336.
Daily, C. (1996). Governance patterns in bankruptcy
reorganizations. Strategic Management Journal, 17(5): 355-375.
Dechow, P.M., R. Sloan & A.P. Sweeney (1995). Detecting
earnings management. The Accounting Review, 70(2), 193-225
DeFond, M. L. & M. Hung (2003). An empirical analysis of
analysts' cash flow forecasts. Journal of Accounting and Economics,
35(1), 73-100.
Dittmar, A. (2004). Capital structure and corporate spin-offs.
Journal of Business, 77(1), 9-54.
Eisenhardt, K. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review.
Academy of Management Review, 14(1), 57-74.
Feltham, G.A. & J.A. Ohlson (1995). Valuation and clean surplus
accounting for operating and financial activities. Contemporary
Accounting Research, 11(2), 689-731.
D. Foust (2000, March). Chapter 11 never looked so good, Business
Week, 44.
Gaver, J K., J. Gaver & J.R. Austin (1995). Additional evidence
on bonus plans and income management. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 19(1), 3-28.
Goel, A.M. & A. V. Thakor (2003). Why do firms smooth earnings?
The Journal of Business, 76(1), 151-192.
Hahn, T., M. O'Neil & J. Swisher (2010). What does
book-to-market proxy: Risk or investor sentiment. Academy of Accounting
and Financial Studies Journal, 14(3), 85-100.
Hanlon, M., S. Rajgopal & T. Shevlin (2003). Are executive
stock options associated with future earnings? Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 36(1-3), 3-43.
Holthausen, R. & R. Leftwich (1986). The effect of bond rating
changes on common stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 7(1),
57-89.
Howe, J. (1997). Credit analysis for corporate bonds: The handbook
of fixed income securities (pp. 371-404). Chicago, IL: Irwin
Professional Publishing.
Jensen, M. C. & W. H. Meckling (1976). Theory of the firm:
Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of
Financial Economics, 3(4), 305-360.
Jensen, M. C., K. J. Murphy & E. G. Wruck (2004). Remuneration:
Where we've been, how we got to here, what are the problems, and
how to fix them. Harvard NOM Working Paper No. 04-28; ECGI - Finance
Working Paper No. 44/2004. Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=561305 or DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.561305.
Johnson, C. H. (2003). Stock and stock option compensation: A bad
idea. Canadian Tax Journal, 51(3), 1259-90.
Jones, J. (1991). Earnings management during import relief
investigations. Journal of Accounting Research, 29(2), 193-228.
Kang, S. & K. Sivaramakrishnan (1995). Issues in testing
earnings management and an instrumental variable approach. Journal of
Accounting Research, 33(2), 353-367.
Kato, H. .K., M., Lemmon, M., Luo & J. Schallheim (2005). An
empirical examination of the cost and benefits of executive stock
options: Evidence from Japan. Journal of Financial Economics, 78(2),
435-461
Klassen, K. J. & A. Mawani (2000). The impact of financial and
tax reporting incentives on option grants to Canadian CEOs. Contemporary
Accounting Research, 17(2), 227-62.
Lacina, M. J. (2004). Characteristics of firms that voluntarily
issue a revenue forecasts with no accompanying earnings forecast.
American Business Review, 22(1), 124-131.
Larcker, D. F. (2003). Discussion of: Are executive stock options
associated with future earnings? Journal of Accounting and Economics,
36(1-3), 91-103.
Mao, C.X. (2003) Interaction of debt agency problems and optimal
capital structure: Theory and evidence. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 38(2), 399-437.
Matolcsy, Z. P. (2000). Executive cash compensation and corporate
performance during different economic cycles. Contemporary Accounting
Research, 17(4), 671-692.
Matsunaga, S. R. (1995). The effects of financial reporting costs
on the use of employee stock options. The Accounting Review, 70(1),
1-26.
Mawani, A. (2003a). Tax deductibility of employee stock options.
Canadian Tax Journal, 51(3), 1230-58.
Mawani, A. (2003b). Cancellation of executive stock options: Tax
and accounting income considerations. Contemporary Accounting Research,
20(3), 495-517.
Moulton, W. N. & H. Thomas (1993). Bankruptcy as a deliberate
strategy: Theoretical consideration and empirical evidence. Strategic
Management Journal 14(2), 125-135.
Ngo, M. V. (2002). Agency costs and the demand and supply of
secured debt and asset securitization. Yale Journal on Regulation,
19(2), 413-471.
Ohlson, J. (1980). Financial ratios and the probabilistic
prediction of bankruptcy. Journal of Accounting Research, 19(1), 109-131
Ohlson, J. A. (1995). Earnings, book values, and dividends in
equity valuation. Journal of Accounting Research, 11(2), 661-687.
Patell, J. (1976). Corporate forecasts of earnings per share and
stock price behavior: Empirical tests. Journal of Accounting Research,
246-76.
Rajgopal, S. & T. Shevlin (2002). Empirical evidence on the
relation between stock option compensation and risk taking. Journal of
Accounting and Economics, 33(2), 145-171.
Reitenga, A., S. Buchheit & T. Baker (2002). CEO bonus pay, tax
policy, and earnings management. Journal of the American Taxation
Association, 24(2), 1-23.
Rose-Green, E. & M. Dawkins (2002). Strategic bankruptcies and
price reactions to bankruptcy filings. Journal of Business Finance and
Accounting, 29 (9&10), 1319-1335.
Sanders, W. G. & D. C. Hambrick (2007). Swinging for the
fences: The effects of CEO stock options on company risk taking and
performance. Academy of Management Journal, 50(5), 1055-1078.
Sloan, R. G. (1996). "Do stock prices fully reflect
information in accruals and cash flows about future earnings? The
Accounting Review, 71(3): 289-315.
Shrader, M. & K. Hickman (1993). Economic issues in bankruptcy
and reorganization. Journal of Applied Business Research, 9(3), 110-118.
Tavakolian, H. (1995). Bankruptcy: An emerging corporate strategy.
S.A.M. Advanced Management Journal, 60(2): 18-22.
Tian, Y. S. (2004). Too much of a good incentive? The case of
executive stock options. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28(6),
1225-1245.
Titman, S. & R. Wessels. (1988). The determinants of capital
structure choice. Journal of Finance, 43 (1), 1-19.
Wilson, R. & F. Fabozzi (1990). The New corporate bond market.
Chicago, IL:
Zaretzky, K. & J. K. Zumwalt (2007). Relation between distress
risk, book-to-market ratio and return premium. Managerial Finance,
3(10), 788-97.
Akinloye Akindayomi, University of Texas-Pan American
Hussein A. Warsame, University of Calgary
ENDNOTES
(1.) Our assertion is informed by the fact that many firms that
participate in TARP have been under intense scrutiny of the regulators
and the congress such that the congress insists that the firms must pay
back their TARP obligations before paying out the usual big cash
compensation to executives. For more on TARP, see the Emergency Economic
Stabilization Act of 2008, and Public Law 110-343.
(2.) Value of the firm can be demonstrated using the framework of
firm valuation model as developed by the Feltham-Ohlson, 1995
(hereinafter referred to as FO).
[P.sub.t] = [bv.sub.t] + [[infinity].summation over
([tau]=1)][R.sup.-[tau].sub.f][E.sub.t][[x.sup.a.sub.t+[tau]]]
Where:
[P.sub.t] = market value of the firm's equity, at time t
[bv.sub.t] = book value of the firm's equity at time t
[R.sub.f] = the firm's cost of capital or the discounting rate
of the earnings. FO suggests that [R.sub.f] be calculated as one plus
the risk-free interest rate.
[x.sup.a] = the abnormal earnings; Et = the expectation operator
(3.) Clement et al (2003) used a variation of the firm valuation
model viz: [P.sub.t] = k x [[infinity].summation over
(t=1)][E.sub.t]/[(1+r).sup.[tau]]. However, one of the implicit
inferences in FO framework is that in order to determine the value of
the firm, one does not necessarily have to forecast future dividends, a
view Bernard (1995) applauds and describes as taking accounting
researcher's away from the "traditional mainstream view";
notwithstanding, some researchers still use it as a starting point in
evaluating the effect of the primary components of the firm values viz
earnings and cost of capital which are still relevant even in the FO
framework. But in order to reflect the distinctive relevance of
accounting numbers to the value of the firm, this study will align with
the conceptual inferences of the FO valuation model.
(4.) For example, DeFond and Hung (2003) identify cash flow
forecasts as one of the information sources that have to be released to
the market by firms with high volatile earnings so that "market
participants could identify the persistent components in earnings."
(5.) The discrepancies in the number of firms and firm-years
between and within the backward and forward looking models are mainly
due to the stronger data requirement constraints imposed by their
underlying characteristics, as the final sample in each of these
categories contains only firms and firm-year observations with required
compensation and financial data. Also note that we use firm-years and
not firm-quarters or other potentially usable periods because the
Execucomp which is the source of our stock options data is available on
annual basis.
(6.) We must admit that the lagged design results presented above
are effectively challenged by Larcker's observations on the
research design choice. We therefore, re-examine the research question
using the 'forward-looking' design below.
(7.) For more on this, see our discussions surrounding this
relation in the section on the lagged results above.
(8.) Instead, they do so as part of their sensitivity analysis,
while they mention that their results remain qualitatively similar, we
strongly believe, that the performance contribution attributed to
executive stock options in their baseline model might be somehow
overstated.
(9.) For example, Chen and Wei (1993) documented that firms with
less likelihood of becoming bankrupt (i.e. with lower probability of
bankruptcy) are more likely to enjoy waiver opportunity from creditors.
This suggests that the cost of debt and by extension the cost of
operations of such firms is likely to be lower relative to firms with
high probability of bankruptcy.
(10.) HRS considered an eight-year and a three-year of time-series
of option grants and payoffs relations respectively.
TABLE 1: {BACKWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS AND CORRELATION MATRIX
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
N = 2,579: F = 858
Variables Mean Std. Median Q1 Q3
deviation
OPINC ($billion) 0.845 2.028 0.239 0.091 0.717
NDE ($billion) 0.322 1.009 0.082 0.024 0.259
SALES ($billion) 5.395 11.151 1.737 0.730 4.977
BSO grants (Smillion) 7.758 18.819 2.684 0.865 7.512
ASSETS ($billion) 5.050 12.382 1.564 0.654 4.611
OPINC/S 0.149 0.206 0.140 0.087 0.206
NDE/S 0.070 0.190 0.060 0.020 0.110
TA/S 1.083 0.794 0.887 0.621 1.281
BSO/S 0.004 0.009 0.001 0.0005 0.003
R&D/S 0.043 0.181 0.004 0.000 0.037
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables OPINC/S NDE/S TA/S BSO/S R&D/S
OPINC/S 1
NDE/S 0.435 1
TA/S 0.343 0.290 1
BSO/S 0.303 0.514 0.382 1
R&D/S 0.202 0.536 0.522 0.491 1
Note on Panel A:
The 'backward-looking' design model is estimated using 2,579 firm-year
observations for a total of858 firms with no missing data. The firm y
span through 1998 to 2001. OPINC is annual operating income; NDE is
nondiscretionary earnings; Sales is annual sales, BSO is Black-Sch
value of options grants to top 5 corporate executives as per Execucomp,
ASSETS is year-end balance sheet value of total assets (TA) and R&D is
research and development expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to
zero.
Note on Panel B:
Variables are as described above scaled by sales. All correlations are
significant at conventional thresholds except otherwise indicated
superscript NS
TABLE 2: {FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN} {YEAR + 1}
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS AND CORRELATION MATRIX
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
N = 8,384: F = 1,666
Variables Mean Std. Median Q1 Q3
deviation
OPINC (Sbillion) 0.611 1.650 0.160 0.058 0.467
NDE (Sbillion) 0.236 0.872 0.034 -0.007 0.167
SALES (Sbillion) 4.089 10.057 1.216 0.494 3.497
BSO grants (Smillion) 4.428 11.171 1.673 0.645 4.263
ASSETS (Sbillion) 3.805 10.983 0.991 0.384 2.952
OPINC/S 0.150 0.148 0.140 0.080 0.020
NDE/S 0.020 0.145 0.030 -0.010 0.070
TA/S 1.010 0.921 0.820 0.590 1.180
BSO/S 0.003 0.004 0.001 0.0004 0.004
R&D/S 0.030 0.071 0.001 0.000 0.033
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables OPINC/S NDE/S TA/S BSO/S TCC/S
OPINC/S 1
NDE/S 0.670 1
TA/S 0.117 -0.120 1
BSO/S 0.201 0.065 0.190 1
TCC/S 0.020NS -0.320 0.301 0.434 1
R&D/S 0.256 0.196 0.279 0.360 0.375
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
N = 8,384: F = 1,666
Variables
OPINC (Sbillion)
NDE (Sbillion)
SALES (Sbillion)
BSO grants (Smillion)
ASSETS (Sbillion)
OPINC/S
NDE/S
TA/S
BSO/S
R&D/S
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables R&D/S
OPINC/S
NDE/S
TA/S
BSO/S
TCC/S
R&D/S 1
Note on Panel A:
The 'forward-looking' design model {Year + 1} is estimated using 8,384
firm-year observations for a total of 1,666 firms with no missing data
Firm years span through 1992 to 2001. OPINC is annual operating income
following the year of grant; NDE is nondiscretionary earnings following
the year of grant; following the year ofgrant, Sales is annual sales,
BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end balance sheet value of
total assets (TA), TCC is cash compensation for top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp, and R&D is research and development
expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero.
Note on Panel B:
Variables are as described above scaled by sales. All correlations are
significant at conventional thresholds except otherwise indicated as a
superscript NS.
TABLE 3: {FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
{SUMYEAR + 1 + 2}
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS AND CORRELATION MATRIX
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
N = 6,666: F = 1,476
Variables Mean Std. Median Q1 Q3
deviation
OPINC1 ($billion) 1.335 3.554 0.357 0.135 1.050
NDE1 ($billion) 0.516 1.754 0.078 -0.013 0.367
SALES ($billion) 9.034 22.517 2.707 1.089 7.720
BSO grants ($million) 4.687 10.677 1.811 0.703 4.564
ASSETS ($billion) 3.984 11.302 1.020 0.401 3.165
OPINC1/S 0.150 0.121 0.140 0.090 0.020
NDE1/S 0.020 0.112 0.030 -0.010 0.070
TA/S 0.480 0.393 0.390 0.280 0.560
BSO/S 0.002 0.004 0.001 0.0002 0.002
R&D/S 0.009 0.014 0.002 0.000 0.014
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables OPINC1/S NDE1/S TA/S BSO/S TCC/S
OPINC1/S 1
NDE1/S 0.662 1
TA/S 0.225 -0.065 1
BSO/S 0.121 -0.059 0.154 1
TCC/S 0.060 -0.351 0.213 0.442 1
R&D/S 0.356 0.312 0.036 0.204 0.175
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
N = 6,666: F = 1,476
Variables
OPINC1 ($billion)
NDE1 ($billion)
SALES ($billion)
BSO grants ($million)
ASSETS ($billion)
OPINC1/S
NDE1/S
TA/S
BSO/S
R&D/S
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables R&D/S
OPINC1/S
NDE1/S
TA/S
BSO/S
TCC/S
R&D/S 1
Note on Panel A:
The 'forward-looking' design model {SumYear + 1 + 2} is estimated
using 6,666 firm-year observations for a total of 1,476 firms with no
missing data. Firm years span through 1992 to 2001. OPINC1 is sum of
operating income for two years following the grant year; NDE1 is sum
of nondiscretionary earnings for two years following the grant year;
Sales is annual sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants
to top 5 corporate executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end
balance sheet value of total assets (TA), TCC is cash compensation for
top 5 corporate executives as per Execucomp, and R&D is research and
development expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero.
Note on Panel B:
Variables are as described above scaled by sales. All correlations are
significant at conventional thresholds except otherwise indicated as a
superscript NS.
TABLE 4: {FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
{SUMYEAR + 1 + 2 + 3}
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS AND CORRELATION MATRIX
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
N = 5,357: F = 1,283
Variables Mean Std. Median Q1
deviation
OPINC2S ($billion) 2.061 5.402 0.546 0.197
NDE2 ($billion) 0.840 2.711 0.128 -0.021
SALES ($billion) 12.866 29.887 3.943 1.587
BSO grants ($million) 5.065 12.627 1.587 0.748
ASSETS ($billion) 3.660 8.358 1.015 0.396
OPINC22/S 0.150 0.099 0.140 0.100
NDE2/S 0.020 0.116 0.030 -0.010
TA/S 0.285 0.107 0.267 0.199
BSO/S 0.001 0.004 0.000 0.0002
R&D/S 0.010 0.013 0.004 0.000
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables OPINC2/S NDE2/S TA/S BSO/S
OPINC2/S 1
NDE2/S 0.709 1
TA/S 0.275 0.074 1
BSO/S 0.152 -0.004 NS 0.140 1
TCC/S 0.078 -0.408 0.137 0.364
R&D/S 0.489 0.367 0.293 0.237
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
N = 5,357: F = 1,283
Variables Q3
OPINC2S ($billion) 1.587
NDE2 ($billion) 0.607
SALES ($billion) 11.265
BSO grants ($million) 4.727
ASSETS ($billion) 2.993
OPINC22/S 0.200
NDE2/S 0.070
TA/S 0.353
BSO/S 0.001
R&D/S 0.014
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables TCC/S R&D/S
OPINC2/S
NDE2/S
TA/S
BSO/S
TCC/S 1
R&D/S 0.257 1
Note on Panel A:
The 'forward-looking' design model {SumYear + 1 + 2 + 3} is estimated
using 5,357firm-year observations for a total of 1,283 firms with no
missing data. Firm years span through 1992 to 2001. OPINC2 is sum of
operating income for three years following the grant year; NDE2 is sum
of nondiscretionary earnings for three years following the grant year;
Sales is annual sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to
top 5 corporate executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end balance
sheet value of total assets (TA) and R&D is research and development
expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero.
Note on Panel B:
Variables are as described above scaled by sales. All correlations are
significant at conventional thresholds except otherwise indicated as a
superscript NS.
TABLE 5: {BACKWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 2,579; F= 858}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients}
LINEAR
1 2
Variable {Dependent: OPINC/S} Coefficient Coefficient
TA/S 5 0.07 *** -0.127 ***
[5.summation over (k=0)] 0.191 *** 0.218 ***
[[alpha].sub.2,k]
[(BSO/S).sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)]
[[alpha].sub.3,k]
[(BSO/S).sup.2.sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)] -0.091 *** -0.137 ***
[[alpha].sub.4,k]
[(R&D/S).sub.i,t-k]
[sigma][(OPINC/S).sub.it-1] 0.034 0.088 ***
[(OPINC).sub.t-1]/S 0.634 ***
Adj. [R.sup.2] without dummies 0.274 0.49
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.448 0.574
{N= 2,579; F= 858}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients}
NONLINEAR
3 4
Variable {Dependent: OPINC/S} Coefficient Coefficient
TA/S 5 0.094 *** -0.113 ***
[5.summation over (k=0)] 0.348 *** 0.408 ***
[[alpha].sub.2,k]
[(BSO/S).sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)] -0.171 *** -0.115 ***
[[alpha].sub.3,k]
[(BSO/S).sup.2.sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)] 0.067 *** -0.07 ***
[[alpha].sub.4,k]
[(R&D/S).sub.i,t-k]
[sigma][(OPINC/S).sub.it-1] -0.032 0.06 ***
[(OPINC).sub.t-1]/S 0.627 ***
Adj. [R.sup.2] without dummies 0.326 0.513
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.475 0.59
Panel B: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{without previous performance}
LINEAR
BSO/S Effect on Implied
Distribution Cutoff OPINC/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0001 0.19
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0002 0.19
THIRD 0.0033 0.0006
NONLINEAR
BSO/S Effect on Implied
Distribution Cutoff OPINC/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0002 0.35
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0004 0.35
THIRD 0.0033 0.0012
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{with previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
OPINC/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0001 0.22
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0003 0.22
THIRD 0.0033 0.0007
NONLINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
OPINC/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0002 0.41
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0005 0.41
THIRD 0.0033 0.0014
Note on Panel A:
***, ** and * represent significance levels at 0.01, 0.05 and 0.10
respectively.
The 'backward-looking' design model is estimated using 2,579 firm-year
observations for a total of 858 firms with no missing data. The firm
years span through 1998 to 2001. OPINC is annual operating income;
Sales is annual sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants
to top 5 corporate executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end
balance sheet value of total assets (TA) and R&D is research and
development expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero. All
variables are scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t and firms by i,
time and industry dummies are suppressed for expositional convenience.
Panel A contains regression coefficient estimates. Columns 1 and 3
contain coefficients without previous performance while columns 2 and
4 cover estimates with previous performance. Columns 1 to 2 and
columns 3 to 4 are for linear and nonlinear models respectively.
Note on Panel B and C:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel B and C refer to the change
in OPINC/S scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 6: {BACKWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 2,579; F = 858}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients}
LINEAR NONLINEAR
1 2 3
Variable {Dependent: NDE/S} Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient
TA/S 5 -0.181 *** -0.084 *** -0.136 ***
[5.summation over (k=0)] 0.288 *** 0.128 *** 0.317 ***
[[alpha].sub.2,k]
[(BSO/S).sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)] -0.187 ***
[[alpha].sub.3,k]
[(BSO/S).sup.2.sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)] 0.171 *** -0.017 *** 0.363 ***
[[alpha].sub.4,k]
[(BSO/S).sub.i,t-k]
[sigma][(NDE/S).sub.it-1] 0.523 *** -0.281 *** 0.266 ***
[(NDE).sub.t-1]/S 1.091 ***
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.697 0.781 0.733
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.730 0.794 0.756
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients}
NONLINEAR
4
Variable {Dependent: NDE/S} Coefficient
TA/S 5 -0.072 ***
[5.summation over (k=0)] 0.213 ***
[[alpha].sub.2,k]
[(BSO/S).sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)] -0.042 ***
[[alpha].sub.3,k]
[(BSO/S).sup.2.sub.i,t-k]
[5.summation over (k=0)] 0.104 ***
[[alpha].sub.4,k]
[(BSO/S).sub.i,t-k]
[sigma][(NDE/S).sub.it-1] 0.325 ***
[(NDE).sub.t-1]/S 0.993 ***
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.794
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.804
Panel B: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{without previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0001 0.29
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0004 0.29
THIRD 0.0033 0.0033
NONLINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0002 0.32
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0004 0.32
THIRD 0.0033 0.0010
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{with previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0001 0.13
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0002 0.13
THIRD 0.0033 0.0004
NONLINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0005 0.0001
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0003
THIRD 0.0033 0.0007
Note on Panel A:
***, ** and * represent significance levels at 0.01, 0.05 and 0.10
respectively.
The 'backward-looking' design model is estimated using 2,579 firm-year
observations for a total of 858 firms with no missing data. The firm
years span through 1998 to 2001. NDE is nondiscretionary earnings;
Sales is annual sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to
top 5 corporate executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end
balance sheet value of total assets (TA) and R&D is research and
development expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero. All
variables are scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t and firms by i,
time and industry dummies are suppressed for expositional convenience.
Panel A contains regression coefficient estimates. Columns 1 and 3
contain coefficients without previous performance while columns 2 and
4 cover estimates with previous performance. Columns 1 to 2 and
columns 3 to 4 are for linear and nonlinear models
respectively.
Note on Panel B and C:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel B and C refer to the change in
NDE/S scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 7: {FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
{YEAR + 1}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 8,384; F= 1,666}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients without Previous Performance}
1 2 3
Variable {Dependent: OPINC/S} Coefficients t-statistic p-value
TA/S -0.138 -12.28 .000
BSO/S 0.131 12.18 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.243 21.28 .000
TCC/S -0.170 -15.63 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without dummies 0.100
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.316
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients without Previous Performance}
4 5 6
Variable {Dependent: OPINC/S} Coefficients t-statistic value
TA/S -0.136 -12.21 .000
BSO/S 0.373 13.39 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.249 -9.40 .000
RD/S 0.252 22.07 .000
TCC/S -0.179 -16.47 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without dummies 0.115
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.323
Panel B: {with previous performance}
TA/S -0.152 -16.35 .000
BSO/S 0.062 6.90 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.065 6.57 .000
TCC/S -0.059 -6.40 .000
[(OPINC).sub.t-1]/S 0.567 62.08 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without dummies 0.478
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.533
TA/S -0.151 -16.28 .000
BSO/S 0.229 9.90 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.172 -7.83 .000
RD/S 0.072 7.29 .000
TCC/S -0.066 -7.15 .000
[(OPINC).sub.t-1]/S 0.563 61.76 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without dummies 0.483
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.536
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{without previous performance}
LINEAR NONLINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied Effect on
Cutoff OPINC/S Sensitivity BSO/S OPINC/S
FIRST 0.0004 0.0001 0.13 0.0004 0.0002
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0002 0.13 0.0012 0.0004
THIRD 0.0035 0.0005 0.0035 0.0013
NONLINEAR
Distribution Implied
Cutoff Sensitivity
FIRST 0.37
MEDIAN 0.37
THIRD
Panel D: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{with previous performance}
LINEAR NONLINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied BSO/S Effect on
Cutoff OPIN/S Sensitivity OPINC/S
FIRST 0.0004 0.0000 0.06 0.0004 0.0001
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0001 0.06 0.0012 0.0003
THIRD 0.0035 0.0002 0.0035 0.0008
NONLINEAR
Distribution Implied
Cutoff Sensitivity
FIRST 0.23
MEDIAN 0.23
THIRD
Notes on Panels A & B:
The 'forward-looking' design model {Year + 1} is estimated using 8,384
firm-year observations for a total of 1,666 firms with no missing data.
Firm years span through 1992 to 2001. OPINC is annual operating income
following the year of grant {the dependent measure}; Sales is annual
sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end balance sheet value of
total assets (TA), TCC is cash compensation for top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp and R&D is research and development
expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero. All variables are
scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t and firms by i, time and
industry dummies are suppressed for expositional convenience. Panel A
is with respect to estimates without previous performance while Panel
B covers estimates with previous performance. Columns 1 to 3 and
columns 4 to 6 are for linear and nonlinear models respectively in
both panels.
Note on Panel C and D:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel C and D refer to the change
in OPINC/S scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 8: {FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN} {YEAR + 1}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 8,384; F = 1,666}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients without Previous Performance}
1 2 3
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE/S}
TA/S -0.188 -16.81 .000
BSO/S 0.128 11.91 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.310 27.26 .000
TCC/S -0.500 -46.14 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.250
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.324
4 5 6
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE/S}
TA/S -0.187 -16.76 .000
BSO/S 0.247 8.90 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.124 -4.67 .000
RD/S 0.314 27.57 .000
TCC/S -0.504 -46.43 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.256
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.325
Panel B: {with previous performance}
1 2 3
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE/S}
TA/S -0.072 -7.49 .000
BSO/S 0.072 7.86 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.058 5.44 .000
TCC/S -0.254 -25.07 .000
(NDE)t-1/S 0.543 57.27 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.498
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.515
4 5 6
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE/S}
TA/S -0.072 -7.47 .000
BSO/S 0.147 6.22 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.078 -3.45 .001
RD/S 0.061 5.72 .000
TCC/S -0.257 -25.30 .000
(NDE)t-1/S 0.541 57.15 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.500
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.516
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{without previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0004 0.0001 0.13
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0002 0.13
THIRD 0.0035 0.0004
NONLINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0004 0.0001 0.25
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0003 0.25
THIRD 0.0035 0.0009
Panel D: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution {with
previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0004 0.0000 0.07
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0001 0.07
THIRD 0.0035 0.0002
NONLINEAR
Distribution Cutoff BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0004 0.0001 0.15
MEDIAN 0.0012 0.0002 0.15
THIRD 0.0035 0.0005
Notes on Panels A & B:
The 'forward-looking' design model {Year + 1} is estimated using 8,384
firm-year observations for a total of 1,666 firms with no missing data.
Firm years span through 1992 to 2001. NDE is nondiscretionary earnings
following the year of grant {the dependent measure}; Sales is annual
sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end balance sheet value of
total assets (TA), TCC is cash compensation for top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp and R&D is research and development
expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero. All variables are
scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t and firms by i, time and
industry dummies are suppressed for expositional convenience. Panel A
is with respect to estimates without previous performance while Panel
B covers estimates with previous performance. Columns 1 to 3 and
columns 4 to 6 are for linear and nonlinear models respectively in
both panels.
Note on Panel C and D:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel C and D refer to the change in
NDE scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 9
{FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
{SUMYEAR + 1 + 2}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 6,666; F = 1,476}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients without Previous Performance}
1 2 3
Variable {Dependent: Coefficients t-statistic p-value
OPINC1/S}
TA/S 0.016 1.32 .187
BSO/S 0.045 4.00 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.347 26.42 .000
TCC/S -0.084 -7.32 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.175
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.380
4 5
Variable {Dependent: Coefficients t-statistic
OPINC1/S}
TA/S 0.013 1.12
BSO/S 0.210 9.51
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.174 -8.67
RD/S 0.339 25.86
TCC/S -0.104 -8.91
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.187
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.386
Panel B: {with previous performance}
1 2 3
Variable {Dependent: Coefficients t-statistic p-value
OPINC1/S}
TA/S -0.193 -17.06 .000
BSO/S 0.049 4.97 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.204 17.18 .000
TCC/S -0.067 -6.72 .000
(OPINC)t-1/S 0.502 45.48 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.427
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.528
4 5
Variable {Dependent: Coefficients t-statistic
OPINC1/S}
TA/S -0.193 -17.17
BSO/S 0.180 9.32
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.138 -7.88
RD/S 0.199 16.76
TCC/S -0.083 -8.17
(OPINC)t-1/S 0.498 45.29
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.434
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.532
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO
distribution {without previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff OPINC1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.05
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0000 0.05
THIRD 0.0015 0.0001
NONLINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff OPINC1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.21
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0001 0.21
THIRD 0.0015 0.0003
Panel D: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO
distribution {with previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff OPINC1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.05
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0000 0.05
THIRD 0.0015 0.0001
NONLINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff OPINC1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.18
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0001 0.18
THIRD 0.0015 0.0003
Notes on Panels A & B:
The 'forward-looking' design model {SumYear + 1 + 2} is
estimated using 6,666 firm-year observations for a total
of 1,476 firms with no missing data. Firm years span
through 1992 to 2001. OPINC1 is sum of operating income
for two years following the grant year {the dependent
measure}; OPINC is annual operating income, Sales is annual
sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to top
5 corporate executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end
balance sheet value of total assets (TA), TCC is cash
compensation for top 5 corporate executives as per Execucomp
and R&D is research and development expenditure. Missing
values of R&D are set to zero. All variables are scaled by
sales. Years are indexed by t and firms by i, time and
industry dummies are suppressed for expositional convenience.
Panel A is with respect to estimates without previous
performance while Panel B covers estimates with previous
performance. Columns 1 to 3 and columns 4 to 6 are for linear
and nonlinear models respectively in both panels.
Note on Panel C and D:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel C and D refer to the
change in OPINC1/S scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 10: {FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
{SUMYEAR + 1 + 2}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 6,666; F = 1,476}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients without Previous Performance}
1 2 3
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE1/S}
TA/S -0.065 -5.26 .000
BSO/S 0.039 3.32 .001
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.400 29.29 .000
TCC/S -0.475 -39.93 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.270
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.330
4 5 6
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE1/S}
TA/S -0.067 -5.43 .000
BSO/S 0.167 7.26 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.135 -6.46 .000
RD/S 0.394 28.82 .000
TCC/S -0.491 -40.55 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.277
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.334
Panel B: {with previous performance} TA/S
1 2 3
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE1/S}
TA/S -0.076 -7.38 .000
BSO/S 0.042 4.30 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.187 15.37 .000
TCC/S -0.307 -29.21 .000
(NDE)t-1/S 0.513 52.51 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.512
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.528
4 5 6
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: NDE1/S}
TA/S -0.078 -7.57 .000
BSO/S 0.158 8.17 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.122 -6.94 .000
RD/S 0.182 14.94 .000
TCC/S -0.321 -30.10 .000
(NDE)t-1/S 0.512 52.59 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.516
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.531
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{without previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff NDE1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.04
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0000 0.04
THIRD 0.0015 0.0001
NONLINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff NDE1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.17
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0001 0.17
THIRD 0.0015 0.0003
Panel D: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{with previous performance}
LINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff NDE1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.04
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0000 0.04
THIRD 0.0015 0.0001
NONLINEAR
Distribution BSO/S Effect on Implied
Cutoff NDE1/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.16
MEDIAN 0.0016 0.0001 0.16
THIRD 0.0015 0.0002
Notes on Panels A & B:
The 'forward-looking' design model {SumYear + 1 + 2} is
estimated using 6,666 firm-year observations for a total
of 1,476 firms with no missing data. Firm years span
through 1992 to 2001. NDE1 is sum of nondiscretionary
earnings for two years following the grant year {the
dependent measure}; NDE is nondiscretionary earnings,
Sales is annual sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of
options grants to top 5 corporate executives as per
Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end balance sheet value of
total assets (TA) and R&D is research and development
expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero. All
variables are scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t and
firms by i, time and industry dummies are suppressed for
expositional convenience. Panel A is with respect to
estimates without previous performance while Panel B
covers estimates with previous performance. Columns 1 to
3 and columns 4 to 6 are for linear and nonlinear models
respectively in both panels.
Note on Panel C and D:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel C and D refer to the
change in NDE1/S scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 11
{FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
{SUMYEAR + 1 + 2 + 3}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 5,357; F = 1,283}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients without Previous Performance}
1 2 3
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: OPINC2/S}
TA/S 0.055 4.33 .000
BSO/S 0.055 4.68 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.405 28.15 .000
TCC/S -0.096 -7.93 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.264
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.395
4 5
Variable Coefficients t-statistic
{Dependent: OPINC2/S}
TA/S 0.055 4.33
BSO/S 0.148 7.35
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.105 -5.68
RD/S 0.395 27.28
TCC/S -0.109 -8.90
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.267
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.398
Panel B: {with previous performance}
1 2 3
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: OPINC2/S}
TA/S -0.118 -10.41 .000
BSO/S 0.073 7.32 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.193 14.77 .000
TCC/S -0.050 -4.87 .000
(OPINC)t-1/S 0.548 45.76 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.502
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.567
4 5
Variable Coefficients t-statistic
{Dependent: OPINC2/S}
TA/S -0.118 -10.36
BSO/S 0.130 7.61
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.064 -4.10
RD/S 0.187 14.31
TCC/S -0.059 -5.59
(OPINC)t-1/S 0.546 45.53
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.503
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.568
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{without previous performance}
Distribution LINEAR
Cutoff
BSO/S Effect on Implied
OPINC2/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.06
MEDIAN 0.0004 0.0000 0.06
THIRD 0.0011 0.0001
Distribution NONLINEAR
Cutoff
Effect on Implied
BSO/S OPINC2/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.15
MEDIAN 0.0004 0.0001 0.15
THIRD 0.0011 0.0002
Panel D: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{with previous performance}
Distribution LINEAR
Cutoff
BSO/S Effect on Implied
OPINC2/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.07
MEDIAN 0.0004 0.0000 0.07
THIRD 0.0011 0.0001
Distribution NONLINEAR
Cutoff
Effect on Implied
BSO/S OPINC2/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.13
MEDIAN 0.0004 0.0001 0.13
THIRD 0.0011 0.0001
Notes on Panels A & B:
The 'forward-looking' design model {SumYear + 1 + 2 + 3} is estimated
using 5,357 firm-year observations for a total of 1,283 firms with no
missing data. Firm years span through 1992 to 2001. OPINC2 is sum of
operating income for three years following the grant year {the
dependent measure}; OPINC is annual operating income, Sales is annual
sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end balance sheet value of
total assets (TA), TCC is cash compensation for top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp and R&D is research and development
expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero. All variables are
scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t and firms by i, time and
industry dummies are suppressed for expositional convenience. Panel
A is with respect to estimates without previous performance while
Panel B covers estimates with previous performance. Columns 1 to 3
and columns 4 to 6 are for linear and nonlinear models respectively
in both panels.
Note on Panel C and D:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel C and D refer to the change in
OPINC2/S scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 12
{FORWARD LOOKING DESIGN}
{SUMYEAR + 1 + 2 + 3}
ESTIMATION OF PAYOFFS USING BLACK-SCHOLES VALUES OF BSO GRANTS
{N= 5,357; F = 1,283}
Panel A: {Regression Coefficients without Previous Performance}
Variable 1 2 3
{Dependent: NDE2/S}
Coefficients t-statistic p-value
TA/S -0.035 -2.93 .003
BSO/S 0.068 6.08 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.450 33.15 .000
TCC/S -0.589 -51.74 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.411
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.462
Variable 4 5
{Dependent: NDE2/S}
Coefficients t-statistic
TA/S -0.035 -2.96
BSO/S 0.167 8.81
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.112 -6.46
RD/S 0.438 32.18
TCC/S -0.603 -52.21
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.417
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.466
Panel B: {with previous performance} TA/S
Variable 1 2 3
{Dependent: NDE2/S}
Coefficients t-statistic p-value
TA/S -0.066 -6.82 .000
BSO/S 0.083 9.13 .000
[(BSO/S).sup.2]
RD/S 0.166 13.54 .000
TCC/S -0.373 -36.98 .000
(NDE)t-1/S 0.547 52.52 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.63
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.647
Variable 4 5
{Dependent: NDE2/S}
Coefficients t-statistic
TA/S -0.066 -6.84
BSO/S 0.152 9.87
[(BSO/S).sup.2] -0.078 -5.56
RD/S 0.160 12.99
TCC/S -0.384 -37.45
(NDE)t-1/S 0.544 52.36
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.633
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.649
Panel C: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{without previous performance}
Distribution LINEAR
Cutoff
Effect on Implied
BSO/S NDE2/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.07
MEDIAN 0.0004 0.0000 0.07
THIRD 0.0011 0.0001
Distribution NONLINEAR
Cutoff
BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE2/S Sensitivity
0.0002 0.0000 0.17
0.0004 0.0001 0.17
FIRST 0.0011 0.0002
MEDIAN
THIRD
Panel D: Economic effects sensitivity of various BSO distribution
{with previous performance}
Distribution LINEAR
Cutoff
Effect on Implied
BSO/S NDE2/S Sensitivity
FIRST 0.0002 0.0000 0.08
MEDIAN 0.0004 0.0000 0.08
THIRD 0.0011 0.0001
Distribution NONLINEAR
Cutoff
BSO/S Effect on Implied
NDE2/S Sensitivity
0.0002 0.0000 0.15
0.0004 0.0001 0.15
FIRST 0.0011 0.0002
MEDIAN
THIRD
Notes on Panels A & B:
The 'forward-looking' design model {SumYear + 1 + 2 + 3} is estimated
using 5,357 firm-year observations for a total of 1,283 firms with
no missing data. Firm years span through 1992 to 2001. NDE2 is sum of
nondiscretionary earnings for three years following the grant year {the
dependent measure}; NDE is annual operating income, Sales is annual
sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS is year-end balance sheet value of
total assets (TA), TCC is cash compensation for top 5 corporate
executives as per Execucomp and R&D is research and development
expenditure. Missing values of R&D are set to zero. All variables are
scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t and firms by i, time and
industry dummies are suppressed for expositional convenience. Panel
A is with respect to estimates without previous performance while
Panel B covers estimates with previous performance. Columns 1 to 3
and columns 4 to 6 are for linear and nonlinear models respectively
in both panels.
Note on Panel C and D:
Implied sensitivity analyses in panel C and D refer to the change in
NDE2/S scaled by change in BSO/S.
TABLE 13
{PROBABILITY OF BANKRUPTCY DESIGN}
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS AND CORRELATION MATRIX
{N= 8,217; F= 1,507}
Panel A: Descriptive Statistics
Variables Mean Std. Median Q1 Q3
deviation
SALES ($billion) 4.052 9.888 1.234 0.505 3.515
BSO grants 4.333 10.707 1.670 0.646 4.230
($million)
ASSETS ($billion) 3.668 9.151 1.001 0.393 2.960
PROBNKP 4.790 6.356 3.470 2.310 5.340
EPS (ERNVOL) 0.640 5.976 0.870 0.290 1.550
LEV 30.670 94.262 29.140 9.770 44.580
GROWTH 4.440 11.577 2.760 1.850 4.460
SIZE /S 1.010 0.912 0.820 0.590 1.117
BSO/S 0.003 0.004 0.001 0.0004 0.003
Panel B: Correlation Matrix
Variables ZSCORE/S TA/S BSO/S TCC/S EPS/S
PROBNKP/S 1
SIZE/S 0.002 (NS) 1
BSO/S 0.204 0.158 1
TCC/S 0.338 0.271 0.439 1
EPS/S 0.036 -0.048 0.014 (NS) -0.002 (NS) 1
GROWTH/S 0.305 0.066 0.173 0.363 -0.005
LEV/S -0.096 0.130 0.108 0.332 0.001
Variables MV/S DTC/S
PROBNKP/S
SIZE/S
BSO/S
TCC/S
EPS/S
GROWTH/S 1
LEV/S 0.070 1
Note on Panel A:
The probability of bankruptcy design is estimated using 8,217 firm-year
observations for a total of 1,507 firms with no missing data. Sales(S)
is annual sales, BSO is Black-Scholes value of options grants to top 5
corporate executives as per Execucomp, ASSETS (a measure of SIZE) is
year-end balance sheet value of total assets (TA), PROBNKP is the
Altman Z-score, EPS is earnings per share before extraordinary items
and discontinued operations, the standard deviation of which is used to
measure firm's volatility (ERNVOL), TCC is cash compensation for top 5
corporate executives as per Execucomp, LEV is long term debt to total
capital and GROWTH is Market to Book value ratio.
Note on Panel B:
Variables are as described above scaled by sales. All correlations are
significant at conventional thresholds except otherwise indicated as a
superscript NS.
TABLE 14
{PROBABILITY OF BANKRUPTCY DESIGN}
REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS ESTIMATES
{N= 8,217; F= 1,507}
Panel A: Prior 5 Year Growth Status
Variable Coefficients t-statistic p-value
{Dependent: PROBNKP}
SIZE/S -0.082 -7.02 .000
BSO/S 0.046 4.00 .000
TCC/S 0.327 25.55 .000
ERNVOL/S 0.032 3.04 .002
GROWTH/S 0.196 18.08 .000
LEV/S -0.216 -20.53 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.206
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.213
Panel B: Current Year Growth Status SIZE/S
SIZE/S -0.081 -6.92 .000
BSO/S 0.041 3.60 .000
TCC/S 0.317 24.91 .000
ERNVOL/S 0.031 3.02 .003
GROWTH/S 0.225 20.81 .000
LEV/S -0.211 -20.19 .000
Adj. [R.sup.2] without 0.215
dummies
Adj. [R.sup.2] overall 0.233
The probability of bankruptcy design is estimated using 8,217 firm-year
observations for a total of 1,507 firms with no missing data. Firm
years span through 1992 to 2001. Sales is annual sales, BSO is
Black-Scholes value of options grants to top 5 corporate executives as
per Execucomp, ASSETS (a measure of SIZE) is year-end balance sheet
value of total assets (TA), TCC is cash compensation for top 5
corporate executives as per Execucomp, PROBNKP is the Altman Z-score,
ERNVOL/S, measuring volatility is the standard deviation of earnings
per share before extraordinary items and discontinued operations,
LEV/S) is long term debt to total capital and GROWTH is Market to Book
value ratio. While the growth measure in Panel A is the average prior
5 year period, the corresponding measure in Panel B is the year t
measure. All variables are scaled by sales. Years are indexed by t
and firms by i, time and industry dummies are suppressed for
expositional convenience.