Market noise, investor sentiment, and institutional investors in the ADR market.
Li, DeQing ; Jin, Jongdae
ABSTRACT
This study examines the effects of market noise in the ADR market.
We find ADR return affected by noise trader risk and increases
(decreases) when investors are irrationally optimistic (pessimistic).
Our results also suggest institutional investors have engaged in stealth trading to exploit their information advantage in the noisy ADR market.
Through a Granger causality regression, we find the returns on ADR
portfolios with high institutional ownership lead the returns of those
with low institutional ownership in the low-noise period, confirming
that institutional trades reflect market information that is ultimately
incorporated into other securities. Finally, we find institutional
investors help reduce volatilities of European ADRs. However, for ADRs
of Asian and South American firms, magnitude of the stabilizing arbitrage positions taken by rational investors is insignificant.
INTRODUCTION
Fischer Black (1986) suggests that noise is as influential as
information in financial markets. Investors who trade on noise are
willing to trade even though it is better for them not to trade. They do
so because they think the noise on which they base their trading is
information.
From existing literature, we can identify three possible effects of
noise on securities trading. First, market noise leads to the existence
of noise trader risk. De Long et al. (1990) develop a noise trader risk
model which argues that when investment decisions are made based on
market noise, the decisions are irrational and unpredictable because
they are led by investor sentiment in general. Hence, noise traders
become a source of risk in the finanical markets. Second, the existence
of noise in capital markets provides an opportunity for informed
institutional investors to exploit their information advantage. Barclay and Warner (1993) show that informed institutional investors are more
likely to engage in "stealth trading" strategies in which the
institutions spread their trades gradually over time. Third, the
irrational behavior of noise traders in a noisy market may cause asset
prices to move away from their fundamental values and destabilize the
market. On the other hand, rational institutional investors would take
positions opposite to those of the noise traders and help stabilize the
market despite De Long et al. (1990) predict that institutional
investors would fail to totally encounter the irrational activities of
noise traders.
We examine the three possible effects of noise in the ADR market.
Our results show that ADR return is affected by investor sentiment in
the ADR market. ADR return increases (decreases) when investors are
irrationally optimistic (pessimistic). We also find that in the lownoise
period, ADRs with high institutional ownership exhibit autocorrelation similar to ADRs with low institutional ownership. However, in the
high-noise period, ADRs with high institutional ownership exhibit
significant higher autocorrelation than ADRs with low institutional
ownership. The result implies institutional investors may have engaged
in stealth trading to expolit a noisy market. Through a Granger
causality regression, we find returns on ADR portfolios with high
institutional ownership lead the returns of those with low institutional
ownership in the low-noise period, confirming that institutional trades
reflect market information that is ultimately incorporated into other
securities. Finally, we find that institutional investors help reduce
volatility of European ADR returns. However, for ADRs of Asian and South
American firms, the magnitude of the stabilizing arbitrage positions
taken by institutional investors is insignificant.
LITERATURE AND MOTIVATION
Financial economists have hypothesized the existence of noise
trading in stock markets (for example, Black (1986), Trueman (1988), De
Long et al. (1989), (1990), Palomino (1996)). While Black (1986) does
not give a reason why investors would rationally want to engage in noise
trading, he asserts that it must account for an important fraction of
total trading in securities markets. Trueman (1988) suggests that an
investment manager has incentive to engage in noise trading because of
the positive signal about his ability to collect private information. De
Long et al. (1990) develop a noise trader risk model in which irrational
noise trader sentiment drives security prices from their fundamental
values. The tendency of noise traders to trade according to their
sentiment renders their investment behavior totally unpredictable.
According to the model, assets subject to unpredictable changes in
investor sentiment must be underpriced in the market relative to their
fundamental values. An application of this argument is the discounts of
closed-end funds. A high level of noise trader risk is associated with
large closed-end fund discounts, and a low level of noise trader risk is
assoicated with small closed-end fund discounts. Moreover, movements in
closed-end fund discounts result primarily from individual
investors' irrational, but correlated trading patterns. Though De
Long et al. (1990) suggest that rational institutional investors will
take positions to offset the irrational tradings of individual
investors, they also predict institutional investors would fail to fully
offset the irrational behavior of individual investors.
Empirical studies providing direct evidence of noise trading have
been very few. Golec (1997) examine bond activities of retailers after
the release of weekly retail statistics by Johnson Reebok Service and
find direct evidence that bond traders indeed trade on noise. Lee,
Shleifer, and Thaler (1991) provide indirect evidence of noise trading
by showing a significant link between investor sentiment and discounts
of closed-end funds. They show that fluctuations in discounts of
closed-end funds reflect changes in investor sentiment. That is,
widening(narrowing) discounts reflect the irrational pessimism(optimism)
of individual investors. Barclay and Warner (1993) confirm the presence
of stealth trading among institutional investors and thus provide
indirect evidence of the existence of market noise.
Regarding market destablization, the traditional theoretical view
is that asset prices do not deviate significantly from their fundamental
values as a result of noise trading. It is argued that incentives exist
for skillful, rational speculators to compete against noise traders, and
that these speculators are the marginal, price-setting investors
(Friedman (1953), and Fama (1965)). However, De Long et al. (1990)
suggest that asset prices can be much more volatile than traditioanl
models would allow because rational arbitrageurs with short horizons
will not offset noisy variations in asset price today given the
self-fulling belief that asset prices will vary unpredictably with
market noise in future. As a result, the noise trader risk caused by
investor sentiment is unpredictable and renders rational arbitrages
ineffective. Palomino (1996) echos this suggestion by saying that nosie
traders are agents with unpredictable beliefs and that the willingness
of arbitrageurs to exploit noise traders' misconceptions is low in
a capital market that is less than perfect. Empirical evidence on
whether irrational (noise traders) investors destabilize financial
markets or rational (institutional investors) traders stabilize markets
in a noisy environment is, however, lacking.
While theoretical papers on noise trading are many, empirical
literature is rare and indirect. As such, this study examines the
effects of noise in the American Depository Receipts (ADRs) market. The
ADR market presents an interesting scenerio for studying this topic
because of several reasons. First of all, Kim, Szakmary, and Mathur
(2000) and Patro (2000) have shown that home-country information has a
significant impact on ADR return. Given the difficulty in getting
accurate information from foreign countries, investors in the ADR market
are likely to subject to a considerable amount of market noise. Second,
institutions are major players in the ADR market and they usually have
better access to information about foreign companies. Evidence of
stealth trading by institutional investors could therefore confirm the
presence of a noisy ADR market in which insitutional investors exploit
their information advantage. Third, the simultanoues presence of noise
and informed investors in the ADRs market allows us to investigate if
the interactions between noise traders and rational investors stabilize
or destabilize asset prices. In short, the ADR market presents an unique
environment in which we can examine the above-mentioned effects of
market noise directly and simultaneously, rather than indirectly and
separately, in a noisy environment.
DATA AND VARIABLES DEFINITIONS
Data
The sample analyzed in this study contains ADRs from 1995 to
2000.The sample period starts from 1995 because complete information
about monthly discounts of closed-end country funds is available from
the Standard and Poor's Security Owners' Stock Guide only
after 1995. Daily returns of ADRs are obtained from the Center for
Research in Security Prices (CRSP) database and converted into monthly
returns. The numbers of shares held by institutional investors and
shares outstanding are obtained from the Standard and Poor's
Security Owners' Stock Guide. The market equity capitalization is
determined by multiplying price with number of outstanding shares of the
ADR.
The ADRs are grouped into three portfolios based on their continent
of origin: Asia, Europe, and South America. Each continent's ADR
portfolio is further divided into two groups, those with high (above the
median) institutional ownership and those with low (below the median)
institutional ownership.
The following table shows the sample distribution by year:
ADR distribution by year
Number Number Number of
of Asian of European South American
Year ADRs ADRs ADRs
1995 33 75 56
1996 44 95 60
1997 46 123 72
1998 50 127 71
1999 54 129 73
2000 56 132 74
Variables definitions
Following Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler (1991), we use the change in
closed-end fund discount [DELTA] discount) to measure the amount of
noise trader risk. For our purpose, we use closed-end country funds. The
discount of each closed-end country fund is the difference between the
fund's net asset value and its price divided by the net asset
value. By grouping all the closed-end country funds in the US into
Asian, European, and South American funds, the average change in
discount [DELTA] discount) of the funds in each group serves as a proxy
for investor sentiment regarding the investment outlook of the
continent. According to Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler (1991), a widening of
the discounts implies investors are more pessimistic whereas a narrowing
of the discounts implies investors are more optimistic. De Long et al.
(1990) and Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler (1991) have used the terms
'noise trader risk' and 'investor sentiment'
interchangeably. Both noise trader risk and investor sentiment refer to
the irrational behavior of investors. Noise trader risk, however, is not
exactly the same as the market noise described by Black (1986). In the
words of Fisher Black, "I use the word "noise" in several
senses. Noise is contrasted with information. Noise is what makes our
observations imperfect. Noise is the arbitrary element in
expectations." That is, noise is something that is anti-information
and thus not investor sentiment per se.
The literature has not yet developed a proxy to measure noise in
the investment markets. In this study, we propose to use the level of
closed-end country fund discount as a proxy for market noise. Our reason
is that in a noisy market, noise trader risk is high because investor
sentiment will change more abruptly in such an environment where there
is an abundant supply of stimulus. In a less noisy market, noise trader
risk is low because there are less stimulus to cause investor sentiment
to shift suddenly. Given that the change in closed-end country fund
discount [DELTA] discount) would be higher (lower) when the level of
closed-end fund discount is high (low), it is therefore reasonable to
suggest that the level of closed-end country fund discount could serve
as a proxy for market noise of the given continent. A large discount
implies the continent's market is noisy, and a small discount
implies the continent's market is less noisy. (1) Consequently, a
year is classified as either a high-noise year or low-noise year when
the discount in that year is larger or smaller than the median. The
average discounts in the high-noise and low-noise periods for Asia,
Europe and South America are shown in the following table, and the
F-statistic is calculated to test the null hypothesis that the average
discounts in the high-noise and low-noise periods are equal.
Closed-end country funds average discounts (%) in
high-noise and low-noise periods
Low-noise High-noise
Continent period period F-statistic
Asia 3.8154 11.4722 20.44 (a)
Europe 14.9132 16.1234 2.52
South America 9.737 22.4369 46.38 (a)
EFFECTS OF INVESTOR SENTIMENT AND INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS ON ADR
RETURNS
Investing in ADR provides a convenient way for diversifying
portfolio risk internationally. As a result, the ADR market has
experienced an explosive growth in the last 30 years. In 1970, there
were only 18 ADRs traded in the U.S. In the year 2000, the number of
listed ADRs had increased to 475. Although the ADR market is dominated
by institutional investors, the difficulty of obtaining accurate and
complete information from foreign countries suggests that influence of
noise can be considerable in this market.
First of all, we study the effects of investor sentiment and
institutional ownership in the ADRs market. The following regression is
performed:
Rt = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1] [R.sub.t-1] + [a.sub.2] [DELTA]
[Discount.sub.t] + [a.sub.3] [DELTA] Institutional [Ownership.sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]
where [R.sub.t] is the compounded monthly ADR portfolio return at
time t for each continent and [R.sub.t-1] is the ADR portfolio return at
time t-1. [DELTA] Discount is the change in the average discount of
close-end country fund from period t to t-1 for each continent.
According to Lee, shleifer, and Thaler (1991), when the change in
average discount ([DELTA] Discount) is positive (i.e., the average
discount widens), individual investors are more pessimistic and asset
returns would be affected negatively. Conversely, when) Discount is
negative, the individual investors are more optimistic and asset returns
would be affected positively. Thus, if investor sentiment is priced in
the ADR market, the coefficient of) Discount should be negative and
significant. Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler (1991) report a significant
negative relation between the returns of NYSE stocks and the average
[DELTA] Discount of a basket of domestic closed-end funds.
[DELTA] Institutional Ownership is the change in the ratio of
institutional ownership from month t to month t-1 for each
continent's ADR portfolio. A priori, we expect ADR return to be
positively correlated with [DELTA] Institutional ownership. That is, ADR
return would be higher or lower when institutions increase or decrease
their holdings. The [R.sub.t-1] is for controlling the effect for serial
correlation in ADR return.
The regression results for each continent are shown in Table I.
In Table I, it is shown that the coefficients of [R.sub.t-1] are
0.2470, 0.3190, and 0.3870, for Asia, Europe, and South America
respectively. The t-statistics are 2.29, 2.74, and 3.68 and all are
significant at the 5% level, implying that there is positive
autocorrelation in ADR portfolios returns. The coefficients of [DELTA]
Discount have the expected negative signs and are -0.0056 for Asia,
-0.0060 for Europe, and -0.0113 for South America respectively. All
their t-statistics are significant at the 1% level. That is, ADR return
is affected by investor sentiment in the ADR market. When investor
sentiment becomes irrationally optimistic or pessimistic, as reflected
by a narrowing or widening of the discount of closed-end country funds,
ADR return of the same continent moves higher or lower correspondingly.
The result is consistent with that of Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler (1991).
For Asian and South American ADRs, the coefficients of [DELTA]
Institutional Ownership are positive and significant, that is, there is
a positive relation between changes in institutional ownership and ADR
portfolio returns. The coefficient of [DELTA] Institutional Ownership is
also positive for Europe, though insignificant. It is possible that the
information about European countries is more accessible than that of
Asian and South American countries, the role of institutional ownership
of European ADRs is therefore less influential. This conjecture is
consistent with our earlier observation that the noise levels of the
high-noise and low-noise periods are similar for Europe.
In the noise trader risk model of DeLong et al. (1990), they
suggest that rational institutional investors may exploit irrational
behavior of noise traders by taking positions opposite to those of the
noise traders. However, the model also predicts that institutional
investors would not be completely successful because the unpredictable
noise trading will render the arbitrage activities of institutional
investors futile. The significantly negative coefficients of [DELTA]
Discount in Table I support the postulations of the noise trader risk
model of DeLong et al. (1990). That is, investor sentiment has a
significant effect even in the presence of rational institutional
investors. In other words, institutional investors are unable to
neutralize the effect of trading led by irrational investor sentiment.
Table I shows that noise trader risk is important even in the
presence of institutional investors. It would be of interest to know
then if the impacts of investor sentiment and institutional ownership on
the ADR return are different in the high-noise and low-noise periods. To
study this, we perform the previous regression on high-noise years and
low-noise years separately. Regression results are shown in Table II.
Table II shows that investor sentiment is important in determining
ADR return in both the high-noise and low-noise periods. However, change
in institutional ownership has a significant impact on the returns of
Asian and South American ADRs only during the high-noise period.
Institutional ownership is not significant at all in the low-noise
period. Conceivably, when the market is noisy (such as Asia and South
American), the information possessed by institutional investors becomes
more important. During low-noise period, the information advantage of
institutional investors may be less significant. This is probably why
institutional ownership does not play a significant role in the pricing
of European ADRs in both the high-noise and low-noise periods because
information about European markets is more accurate and readily
available to investors.
MARKET NOISE AND ADR RETURN AUTOCORRELATION
Table I and II confirm that noise trader risk is present in the ADR
market. If the ADR market is noisy, then the private information of
institutional investors would be valuable and it is logical that
institutional investors will exploit their informational advantage. One
possible way to do so is the use of "stealth trading"
strategies in which institutional investors spread their trades
gradually over time. According to Barclay and Warner (1993), stealth
trading would induce ADR return autocorrelation. While insitutional
investors may stealth trade frequently in the ADR market, we expect the
likelihood to be higher in the high-noise period than the low-noise
period. Thus, we expect that in the high-noise period, ADRs with high
institutional ownership would exhibit significant higher autocorrelation
than ADRs with low institutional ownership. In the low-noise period, we
expect ADRs with high institutional ownership to exhibit similar or
higher autocorrelation than ADRs with low institutional ownership. The
return autocorrelations of all the individual ADRs in the high-noise and
low-noise periods are shown in Table III.
Consistent with our expectation, panel A of Table III shows that in
the low-noise period, for both Asia and South America, ADRs with high
institutional ownership exhibit autocorrelations similar to ADRs with
low institutional ownership. For Asia, the mean daily autocorrelation
for individual ADRs with low institutional ownership and high
institutional ownership are 0.0040 and 0.0164 respectively. The
t-statistic is 0.46 and not significant. For South America, the mean
daily autocorrelation for individual ADRs with low institutional
ownership and high institutional ownership are 0.0185 and 0.0391
respectively. The t-statistic is 1.06 and not significant. For Europe,
ADRs with high institutional ownership exhibit higher autocorrelation
than ADRs with low institutional ownership.
For the high-noise period, panel B of Table III shows that ADRs
with high institutional ownership exhibit significant higher
autocorrelation than ADRs with low institutional ownership for Asia,
Europe, and South America. For Asia, the mean daily autocorrelation for
individual ADRs with low institutional ownership and high institutional
ownership are -0.0030 and 0.0504 respectively. The t-statistic is 10.6,
significant at the 1% level. For Europe, the mean daily autocorrelation
for individual ADRs with low institutional ownership and high
institutional ownership are -0.0169 and 0.0311 respectively. The
t-statistic is 16.26 and significant at the 1% level. For South America,
similar result is obtained.
In sum, the results in table III support our earlier conjecture
that institutional investors exploit their information advantage in the
noisy ADR market.
CROSS-PREDICTABILITY OF ADR PORTFOLIO RETURNS IN HIGH-NOISE AND
LOW-NOISE PERIODS
From the above, we find that noise is present in the ADR market and
institutional investors react differently in high-noise and low-noise
environments. In order to confirm that institutional trades contain
information not found in non-institutional trades, a Granger causality
regression model is used. For each continent's ADR portfolio the
following regressions are performed for the high-noise and low-noise
periods separately:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
where [R.sub.high, t] and [R.sub.low, t] are the returns at time t
for ADR portfolios with high and low institutional ownership, the
[d.sub.i, t] are dummy variables for each day of the week i, k is the
lag in days and u is the error term.
According to Brennan et al. (1993), portfolios that are first to
reflect market-wide information have a better ability to predict the
returns of portfolios that are late to reflect marketwide information
than the ability of the latter to predict the former. That is, if
institutional investors trade on information, returns on portfolios with
high institutional ownership should lead the returns of those portfolios
that have low institutional ownership. For both the low-noise and the
high-noise periods, we therefore expect returns on ADR portfolios with
high institutional ownership to lead the returns of those with low
institutional ownership if institutions trade on information. That is,
we expect [R.sub.high, t-k] to predict [R.sub.low, t] better than
[R.sub.low, t-k] to predict [R.sub.high, t]. In the Granger causality
regressions, we therefore expect [b.sub.high, k] to be larger than
[a.sub.low, k].
Panel A of Table IV shows that in the low-noise period, returns on
ADR portfolios with high institutional ownership lead the returns of
those with low institutional ownership for all three continents. For
Asia, [a.sub.low] is 0.0172, and [b.sub.high] is 0.0770. For Europe,
[a.sub.low] is -0.0104, and [b.sub.high] is 0.0351. For South America,
[a.sub.low] is -0.0290, and [b.sub.high is 0.0825. That is, for all the
three continents, [a.sub.low] is less than [b.sub.high] . The
F-statistics, Wilcoxon Z - values, and Kruskal-Wallis Chi-squares are
all significant at the 5% level. These results show that the ability of
[R.sub.high, t-k] to predict [R.sub.low, t] is much greater than the
ability of [R.sub.low, t-k] to predict [R.sub.high, t]. That is, even
though the market noise is low (relatively speaking) in the low-noise
period, ADR portfolios with high institutional ownership still reflect
market-wide information sooner than ADR portfolios with less
institutional ownership.
In the high-noise period, we observe unexpected results. The
returns of high institutional ownership ADR portfolios do not lead the
returns of those with low institutional ownership for Asia and South
America. For Asia, [a.sub.low] is 0.0031, and [b.sub.high] is 0.0213.
For South America, [a.sub.low] is 0.0385, and [b.sub.high] is 0.0807.
Despite in both cases, the size of [b.sub.high] is larger than the size
of [a.sub.low], the F-statistics, Wilcoxon Z values, and Kruskal-Wallis
Chi-squares are all insignificant. These results mean that we cannot
reject the null hypothesis that [b.sub.high] = [a.sub.low], that is, the
ability of [R.sub.high, t-k] to predict [R.sub.low, t] is not much
greater than the ability of [R.sub.low, t-k] to predict [R.sub.high, t].
We think there are two possible reasons for these results. One reason
may be that in the high-noise period, institutions deliberately divulge
their information very slowly over time through stealth trading, making
their information advantage less useful for others to predict returns.
This is consistent with our earlier results in Table III that
insitutions stealth trade particularly in the high-noise period. The
other possible reason is that in the high-noise period risk exposure is
conceivably higher for investments in Asian and South American ADRs,
institutional investors may be affected by their risk concern such that
their ability to impound information in ADR prices is affected. Sias and
Stark (1997) suggest that if institutional investors are motivated to
trade for reasons not associated with information, then there is no
reason to expect the returns on portfolios with high institutional
ownership to lead the returns on portfolios with low institutional
ownership. For European ADRs, the risk is conceivably lower than those
of Asian and South American ADRs, returns on portfolios with high
institutional ownership lead the returns on portfolios with low
institutional ownership because institutional investors' ability to
impound information in ADR prices is less affected by risk concern. This
conjecture regarding the concern of risk by institutional investors is
consistent with the results in the following section.
INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS IN THE ADR MARKET: DESTABILIZING OR
STABILIZING?
Noise traders move ADR prices away from their fundamental values as
investment decisions are led by investor sentiment. One observable
consequence is that the ADR return volatility would be higher in the
high-noise period. The numbers in the following table confirms this;
implying noise traders destabilize financial market.
ADR Return Volatility
Low-noise High-noise T-statistic
Asia 0.0230 0.0308 -13.96 (a)
Europe 0.0232 0.0269 -14.66 (a)
South America 0.0282 0.0347 -10.81 (a)
On the other hand, De Long et al. (1990) suggest that rational
investors such as institutions will offset, though incomplete, the
irrational activities of the noise traders. Given such postulation, the
next logical question is whether institutional investors help
destabilize or stabilize volatility of the ADR market. The following
regression is performed to answer this question.
[[delta].sup.2.sub.it] = a0 + a1 [[delta].sup.2.sub.i,t-1] + a2
([DELTA] Discount)t + a3 ([DELTA] Institutional Ownership) t +
[epsilon]t
where [[delta].sup.2.sub.it] is the volatility of the ADR return in
time period t for each portfolio, and [[delta].sup.2.sub.i,t-1] is the
volatility of the ADR return in time period t-1.
Table V shows that for Europe, the coefficient of the change in
institutional ownership is -0.8370 and it is significant at the 5%
level, that is, institutional ownership is negatively related to the
volatility of the stock return. The result means that institutional
investors help stabilize the market of European ADRs. That is,
institutions have helped offset the irrational behavior of noise
traders. The coefficients of the change in institutional ownership for
Asia and South America, on the other hand, are negative but
insignificant. That is, institutional investors have no significant
effect on the volatilities of the ADRs from these two continents. This
result deserves some explanations.
In finance literature, it is well known that rational investors
arbitrage and bring prices closer to fundamental values. The
effectiveness of arbitrageurs however relies crucially on the
stabilizing powers of rational speculation. Some studies have questioned
the effectiveness of such speculation in the presence of risk aversion.
For example, DeLong et al. (1987) show that the unpredictability of
noise traders' beliefs creates a risk that deters rational
arbitrageurs from aggressively betting against them, and rational
speculation is thus less effective. Figlewski (1979) also shows that it
might take a very long time for noise traders to lose most of their
money if rational investors must bear fundamental risk in betting
against them, and such fundamental risk deters rational speculation.
Both of these two papers suggest that the magnitude of the stabilizing
arbitrage positions taken by rational investors might be limited.
Investors may regard Asia and South America as more risky when compared
with Europe, and rational investors are therefore less likely to counter
the unpredictable noise trader risk in Asia and South America. Thus, the
magnitude of the stabilizing arbitrage positions taken by rational
investors might be small and insignificant for both Asia and South
America.
The coefficients of [DELTA] Discount are all negative, though only
significant for Asia and South America. That is, noise trader risk
affects ADRs volatility. This is consistent with DeLong et al. (1990)
that noise trading is a source of risk, particularly in Asian and South
American financial markets.
We also perform the above regression for the high-noise period and
the low-noise period separately, and the results are shown in Table VI.
Results similar to those of Table V are found. Table VI shows that
for Europe, the coefficients of the change in institutional ownership
are negative and significant in both the highnoise and low-noise
periods. Again, this may be due to the lesser degree of risk aversion
among arbitragers in this market. For Asia and South America, the
coefficients of the change in institutional ownership are not
significant in either the high-noise period or the low-noise period. For
Asia and South America, the aversion to risk greatly limits rational
investors' willingness to bet against noise traders in both the
high-noise and low-noise periods.
SUMMARY
This study examines the effects of market noise in the American
Depository Receipts (ADRs) market. From existing literature, we can
identify three possible effects of noise on securities trading. First,
market noise leads to the existence of noise trader risk. Second, the
existence of noise in capital markets provides an opportunity for
informed institutional investors to exploit their information advantage
through stealth trading. Third, the irrational behavior of noise traders
in a noisy market may cause the market to destabilize, though rational
institutional investors would take positions opposite to those of the
noise traders and help stabilize the market. We examine the three
possible effects of noise in the ADR market. The ADRs market presents an
unique environment in which we can examine the above-mentioned effects
of noise directly and simultaneously in a noisy environment.
Our results show that the ADR return is affected by investor
sentiment (noise trader risk) in the ADR market. ADR return increases
(decreases) when investors are irrationally optimistic (pessimistic). We
also find that in the low-noise period, ADRs with high institutional
ownership exhibit autocorrelation similar to ADRs with low institutional
ownership. However, in the highnoise period, ADRs with high
institutional ownership exhibit significant higher autocorrelation than
ADRs with low institutional ownership. The result implies institutional
investors may have engaged in stealth trading. Through a Granger
causality regression, we find returns on ADR portfolios with high
institutional ownership lead the returns of those with low institutional
ownership in the low-noise period, confirming that institutional trades
reflect market information ultimately incorporated into other stocks.
Finally, we find that rational investors help stabilize ADRs market in
Europe. However, for Asia and South America, the magnitude of the
stabilizing arbitrage positions taken by rational investors is
insignificant.
ENDNOTES
Since noise and .Discount may be correlated and cause selection
bias, we perform tests for difference in means of [DELTA] Discount
between the high-noise and low-noise periods for each portfolio. All the
test statistics are insignificant, showing no selection bias.
REFERENCES
Black, Fischer, (1986), Noise, Journal of finance 41, 529-543.
Barclay, M.J, Warner, J.B, (1993). Stealth trading and volatility:
which trades move price? Journal of Financial Economics 34, 281-305.
Brennan, M.J., Jegadeesh, N. & Swaminathan, B., (1993),
Investment Analysis and The Adjustment Of Stock Prices To Common
Information, Review Of Financial Studies 6, 799-824. Brett Trueman,
(1988), A theory of noise trading in securities markets, Journal of
Finance 43, 83-95.
De Long, J. Bradford, A. Shleifer, L. H. Summers & R.J.
Waldmann, (1989), Positive Feedback Investment Strategies And
Destabilizing Rational Speculation, Journal of Finance 45, 379-395. De
Long, J. Bradford, A. Shleifer, L. H. Summers & R. J. Waldmann,
(1990), Noise trader risk in financial markets, Journal of political
economy, 703-38.
Fama, E.,(1965), "The behavior of stock market prices,'
Journal of business, 34-105.
Figlewski, Stephen, (1979), Subjective information and market
efficiency in a betting market, Journal of political economy 87, 75-88.
Friedman, Milton, (1953), The case for flexible exchange rates, in
Essays in positive economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Golec, J., (1997), Herding on noise: the case of Johnson
Redbook's weekly retail sales data, Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 32, 367-381.
Kim, Minho, Szakmary, A.C. & Ike Mathur, (2000), Price
transmission dynamics between ADRs and their underlying foreign
securities, Journal of Banking and Finance 24, 1359-1382.
Lee, Charles, Andrei Shleifer & Richard H. Thaler, (1991),
Investor sentiment and the closed end funds puzzle, Journal of finance,
75-109.
Palomino, F., (1996), Noise trading in small markets, Journal of
finance, 1537-50.
Patro, Dilip Kumar, (2000_. Return behavior and pricing of American
depository receipts. Journal of international financial markets,
institutions and money 10, 43-67.
Shleifer, Andrei & Lawrence H. Summers, (1990),The noise trader
approaches to finance, Journal of economic perspectives, Vol 4, Spring,
19-33.
DeQing Diane Li, University of Maryland Eastern Shore
Jongdae Jin, University of Maryland Eastern Shore
TABLE I: Effects of Investor Sentiment and Institutional
Investor on ADR return
Each year, all ADRs are grouped into three portfolios
based on their country of origin: Asia, Europe, and
South America. Rt is the ADRs portfolio return at time
t for each continent and Rt-1 is the ADR portfolio
return at time t-1 for each continent. We also group
all the closed-end country funds in US into Asian,
European, and South American funds. The discount
is the difference between the fund's net asset value
and its price divided by the net asset value. The
discount of each continent is the average discount of
the funds in each group, and [DELTA] Discount is the
difference of discount between month t and month t-1
for each continent. [DELTA] Institutional Ratio is
the change of the average institutional ownership
between month t and month t-1 for each continent.
Model: [R.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][R.sub.t-1]
+ [a.sub.2][DELTA] [Discount.sub.t] +
[a.sub.3] [DELTA] Institutional [Ownership.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
[DELTA]
Intercept [R.sub.t-1] Discount
All 0.0043 0.3110 -0.0075
ADRs (0.92) (5.02 (a)) (-9.19 (a))
Asia -0.0166 0.2470 -0.0056
(-1.23) (2.29 (b)) (-4.93 (a))
Europe 0.0094 0.3190 -0.0060
(1.79) (2.74 (a)) (-4.48 (a))
S. 0.0058 0.3870 -0.0113
America (0.67) (3.68 (a)) (-6.46 (a))
[DELTA]
Institutional Adjusted
Ownership R-square
All 1.2690 0.3020
ADRs (2.01 (b))
Asia 3.5100 0.2910
(2.10 (b))
Europe 0.7130 0.2410
(1.28)
S. 4.4090 0.3820
America (1.67 (c))
(a) Significant at the 1% level.
(b) Significant at the 5% level.
(c) Significant at the 10% level.
TABLE II: Effects of Investor Sentiment and Institutional
Investor on ADR return
Model: [R.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][R.sub.t-1]
+ [a.sub.2] [DELTA] [Discount.sub.t] + [[alpha].sub.3]
Institutional [Ownership.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
A: Low-noise period:
[DELTA]
[Discount.
Intercept [R.sub.t-1] sub.t]
All ADRs -0.0003 0.2990 -0.0056
(-0.01) (3.41 (a)) (-5.33 (a))
Asia -0.0022 0.4710 -0.0029
(-0.15) (3.20 (a)) (-2.38 (a))
Europe 0.0159 0.4050 -0.0037
(0.39) (2.69 (a)) (-2.14 (a))
S.America 0.0132 0.4320 -0.0110
(0.98) (2.88 (a)) (-4.25 (a))
B: High-noise period:
[DELTA]
[Discount.
Intercept [R.sub.t-1] sub.t]
All ADRs -0.0092 0.1880 -0.0080
(-1.24) (2.15) (b) (-5.79 (a))
Asia -0.0343 0.0456 -0.0072
(-1.59) (0.72) (-3.61 (a))
Europe 0.0039 0.2500 -0.0060
(0.50) (1.52) (-3.22a)
S.America -0.0242 0.0686 -0.0094
(-1.54) (0.36) (-3.05 (a))
A: Low-noise period:
[DELTA]
Institutional Adjusted
Ownership R-square
All ADRs 1.5230 0.25
(1.60)
Asia 2.1500 0.22
(1.16)
Europe 0.7800 0.28
(1.09)
S.America 7.6920 0.39
(1.36)
B: High-noise period:
[DELTA]
Institutional Adjusted
Ownership R-square
All ADRs 1.8460 0.25
(1.98 (b))
Asia 5.5660 0.30
(2.01 (b))
Europe 0.4590 0.19
(0.61)
S.America 8.0250 0.24
(2.02 (b))
(a) Significant at the 1% level.
(b) Significant at the 5% level.
Table III: Return Autocorrelations of ADRs
The mean daily return autocorrelations for individual ADRs
in both the high-noise period and the low-noise period are
reported. The t-statistic is calculated to test the null
hypothesis that the mean daily return autocorrelation of
individual ADRs with high institutional ownership is equal
with the mean daily return autocorrelation of individual
ADRs with low institutional ownership.
A: Autocorrelation of individual ADRs in the low noise period
Low High
institutional institutional
ownership ratio ownership ratio t-statistic
Asia 0.0040 0.0164 0.46
Europe -0.0215 0.0419 20.42 (a)
South
America 0.0185 0.0391 1.06
B. Autocorrelation of individual ADRs in the high noise period:
High
Low institutional institutional
Ownership ratio ownership ratio t-statistic
Asia -0.0030 0.0504 10.61 (a)
Europe -0.0169 0.0311 16.26 (a)
South
America 0.0383 0.0767 5.68 (a)
(a) Significant at the 1% level.
TABLE IV: Cross-Predictability of ADR Portfolio Return
Each year, all ADRs are grouped into three portfolios based
on their country of origin: Asia, Europe, and South America.
Each continent's ADR portfolio is further divided into those
with high institutional ownership and those with low
institutional ownership. We also group all the closed-end
country funds in US into Asian, European, and South American
funds. The discount is the difference between the fund's net
asset value and its price divided by the net asset value. The
discount of each continent is the average discount of the
funds in each group. We further classify the years in which
the discount is larger than the median as high-noise years
and those years in which the discount is smaller than the
median as low-noise years for each continent. The daily
return of each continent portfolio with high (low) institutional
ownerships is regressed on its own previous five returns and the
previous five returns for the same continent portfolio with low
(high) institutional ownerships in both the high-noise period
and the low-noise period. The sums of the coefficients are reported
below. The F-statistic is calculated to test the null hypothesis
that the ability of the lagged return on the high institutional
portfolio to predict the return on the same continent portfolio
with low institutional ownership is the same as the ability of
the lagged return on the low institutional portfolio to predict
the return on the high institutional portfolio of the same
continent in both the high-noise period and the low-noise period.
Wilcoxon Z value and Kruskal-Wallis Chi-square are also shown in
Table IV.
TABLE IV: Cross-Predictability of ADR Portfolio Return
[R.sub.hight] =[5.summation over (i=1)] [a.sub.i][d.sub.i,t]
+ [5.summation over (k=1)] ([a.sub.hightk][R.sub.hight-k] +
[a.sub.lowk] [R.sub.lowt-k]) + [u.sub.hight], (1)
[R.sub.hight] =[5.summation over (i=1)] [b.sub.i][d.sub.i,t]
+ [5.summation over (k=1)] ([b.sub.hightk][R.sub.hight-k] +
[b.sub.lowk] [R.sub.lowt-k]) + [u.sub.hight], (2)
A: Low-noise period:
[R.sub. [R.sub.
Dependent Variable high,t-k] low,t-k]
(Independent Variable)
Asia [R.sub.high,t] 0.0500 0.0172
Asia [R.sub.low,t] 0.0770 -0.0247
Europe [R.sub.high,t] 0.0458 -0.0104
Europe [R.sub.low,t] 0.0351 -0.0316
S.Am [R.sub.high,t] 0.0518 -0.0290
S.Am [R.sub.low,t] 0.0825 -0.0555
B: High-noise period:
[R.sub. [R.sub.
Dependent Variable high,t-k] low,t]-
(Independent Variable)
Asia [R.sub.high,t] 0.0474 0.0031
Asia [R.sub.low,t] 0.0213 0.0088
Europe [R.sub.high,t] 0.0369 -0.0030
Europe [R.sub.low,t] 0.0561 -0.0092
S.Am [R.sub.high,t] 0.0713 0.0385
S.Am [R.sub.low,t] 0.0807 0.0183
A: Low-noise period:
Wilcoxon
Dependent Variable F-statistic Z-value
Asia [R.sub.high,t] 4.46 (b) 1.87 (b)
Asia [R.sub.low,t]
Europe [R.sub.high,t] 5.20 (b) 2.10 (b)
Europe [R.sub.low,t]
S.Am [R.sub.high,t] 5.47 (b) 1.74 (b)
S.Am [R.sub.low,t]
B: High-noise period:
Wilcoxon
Dependent Variable F-statistic Z-value
Asia [R.sub.high,t] 0.44 0.71
Asia [R.sub.low,t]
Europe [R.sub.high,t] 3.81 (b) 1.52 (c)
Europe [R.sub.low,t]
S.Am [R.sub.high,t] 0.62 0.21
S.Am [R.sub.low,t]
A: Low-noise period:
Kruskal-Wallis
Dependent Variable Chi-square
Asia [R.sub.high,t] 3.58 (b)
Asia [R.sub.low,t]
Europe [R.sub.high,t] 4.50 (b)
Europe [R.sub.low,t]
S.Am [R.sub.high,t] 3.11 (c)
S.Am [R.sub.low,t]
B: High-noise period:
Kruskal-Wallis
Dependent Variable Chi-square
Asia [R.sub.high,t] 0.53
Asia [R.sub.low,t]
Europe [R.sub.high,t] 2.36 (c)
Europe [R.sub.low,t]
S.Am [R.sub.high,t] 0.05
S.Am [R.sub.low,t]
(a) Significant at the1% level.
(b) Significant at the 5% level.
(c) Significant at the 10% level.
Table V: Effect of Institutional Investors on ADR Return Volatilities
The volatility of the return for time t for each continent's ADR
portfolio is then regressed on the volatility of the return for time
t-1, the difference of discount between month t and month t-1
([DELTA] Discount), and the change of the institutional ownership
between month t and month t-1 ([DELTA] Institutional Ratio).
[[delta].sup.2.sub.it] = a0 + a1 [[delta].sup.2.sub.i,t-1] + a2
([DELTA] Discount)t + a3 ([DELTA] Institutional Ownership)t +
[[epsilon].sub.t]
Intercept [[delta].sup. [DELTA]
2.sub.i,t-1] Discount
Asia 0.0518 0.4750 -0.0033
(3.48) (4.72 (b)) (-3.76 (a))
Europe 0.0569 0.5090 -0.0011
(4.43) (4.71 (a)) (-1.40)
S.America 0.1210 0.3960 -0.0027
(1.82) (3.60 (a)) (-2.53 (a))
[DELTA] Adjusted
Institutional R-square
Ownership
Asia 1.8900 0.3270
(1.43)
Europe -0.8370 0.3870
(-1.98 (b))
S.America -1.1090 0.1790
(-0.58)
(a) Significant at the 1% level.
(b) Significant at the 5% level.
(c) Significant at the 10% level.
Table VI: Effect of Institutional Investors on ADR Return Volatility
The volatility of the return for time t for each continent's ADR
portfolio is regressed on the volatility of the return for time t -1,
the difference of discount between month t and month t-1 ([DELTA]
Discount), and the change of the institutional ownership between month
t and month t-1.
[[delta].sup.2.sub.it] = a0 + a1 [[delta].sup.2.sub.i,t-1] + a2
([DELTA] Discount) t + a3 ([DELTA] Institutional Ownership)t +
[[epsilon].sub.t]
A: Low-noise period:
Intercept [[delta].sup. [DELTA]
2.sub.i,t-1] Discount
Asia 0.0270 0.5650 -0.0037
(1.24) (4.07 (b)) (-3.17 (a))
Europe 0.0593 0.5460 -0.0005
(3.06) (3.35 (a)) (-0.68)
S.America 0.0342 0.7200 -0.0022
(1.97) (5.50 (a)) (-2.18 (a))
[DELTA] Adjusted
Institutional R-square
Ownership
Asia 2.5890 0.42
(1.46)
Europe -1.4290 0.33
(-2.12 (b))
S.America 1.9590 0.49
(0.78)
B: High-noise period:
Intercept [[delta].sup. [DELTA]
2.sub.i,t-1] Discount
Asia 0.0804 0.3290 -0.0035
(3.93) (2.06 (b)) (-2.31 (b))
Europe 0.0788 0.3100 -0.0014
(4.01) (1.83 (c)) (-1.37)
S.America 0.1180 0.2240 -0.0032
(4.46) (1.36) (-1.83 (c))
[DELTA] Adjusted
Institutional R-square
Ownership
Asia 1.9100 0.19
(0.87)
Europe -1.7020 0.46
(-2.58 (a))
S.America 1.6620 0.13
(0.63)
(a) Significant at the 1% level.
(b) Significant at the 5% level.
(c) Significant at the 10% level.