Conservatism of the big six audit firms and going-concern modified audit reports.
Geiger, Marshall A. ; Raghunandan, K.
ABSTRACT
This study examines whether Big 6 audit farms exhibit a more
conservative reporting posture than non-Big 6 audit firms by examining
differences in "reporting errors "for going concern
uncertainties. Specifically, based on an analysis of relative error
costs, we hypothesize that Big 6 firms are more conservative in their
reporting decisions, leading to differences in error proportions for
both type 1 (companies receiving going-concern modified opinions that do
not fail) and type II (failed companies that did not receive a prior
going-concern modification) reporting errors. Evidence from samples of
companies with first-time going-concern modified opinions and bankrupt companies is generally consistent with the hypotheses. Big 6 firms were
found to have a significantly higher type I reporting error rate when
failure was defined as filing for bankruptcy or entering default on debt
payments, and a significantly lower type II reporting error rate than
non-Big 6 firms. Our findings suggest that reporting decisions are
associated with the relative magnitude of the firms' expected
losses, resulting in more conservative reporting decisions regarding the
issuance of going -concern modified audit reports for Big 6 firms.
INTRODUCTION
Prior research has addressed the existence of differences between
Big 6 and non-Big 6 (1) audit firms on a variety of dimensions,
including audit quality, audit fees, client retention and industry
concentration (DeAngelo, 1981; Palmrose, 1986; Francis & Simon,
1987; Simunic & Stein, 1996; Gul, 1999; Hogan & Jeter, 1999).
Some recent studies have also examined whether the largest audit firms
are more conservative than smaller audit firms in various settings.
Recent papers examining issues related to the market for audit services
have documented that Big 6 firms are (a) less concentrated in industries
perceived as having high litigation risk compared to those perceived as
having low litigation risk (Hogan & Jeter, 1999), (b) less likely to
accept clients where the predecessor auditor resigned (Raghunandan &
Rama, 1999), and (c) have maintained historically less risky client
portfolios than non-Big 6 auditors (Francis & Reynolds, 1999). While
these studies have examined several facets of the auditor-client
interaction, no study has examined Big 6 firms compared to non-Big 6
firms for conservatism in their resultant reporting decisions--the final
outcome of the audit process.
Audit reporting, and particularly reporting on going-concern
uncertainties, continues to remain an important issue for U. S.
legislators and the public accounting profession. This is evidenced by
the fact that the U. S. recently enacted the Private Securities
Litigation Reform Act which provides the first and only instance where a
specific auditing procedure, related to reporting on going-concern
uncertainties, has been mandated by law. This study provides additional
evidence on the conservatism of the Big 6 firms by empirically examining
reporting decisions regarding going-concern.
An analysis of an audit reporting model, developed below, suggests
that rational economic behavior on the part of Big 6 auditors would lead
to more conservative audit opinions, after controlling for other going
concern related factors. Our findings support this analysis and suggest
that Big 6 firms generally do exhibit more conservative reporting
decisions related to issuing going-concern modified reports.
Specifically, we find that type I reporting errors (defined as instances
where a company receives a going-concern modified opinion but does not
subsequently fail), as expected, were higher for the Big 6 than the
non-Big 6 firms when failure was defined as entering bankruptcy or
payment default on debt. We also find that type II reporting errors
(defined as instances where a company enters into bankruptcy without a
prior going-concern modified opinion), as expected, were significantly
lower for the Big 6 firms.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section II
presents the development of the audit reporting model and hypotheses
tested, Section III discusses the research method, Section IV presents
the results, and Section V provides a summary of the study and a
discussion of the research limitations and directions for fixture research.
DEVELOPMENT OF THE AUDIT REPORTING MODEL AND HYPOTHESES
Error Costs and Audit Reporting
Congressional hearings in the U.S. have criticized auditors for not
providing adequate early warning of impending client failures (U.S.
House of Representatives 1985, 1990). Legislators' continuing
concern with this issue is evidenced by the fact that the Private
Securities Litigation Reform Act (1995) codified into law the audit
reporting requirements related to going-concern uncertainties specified
in Statement on Auditing Standards (SAS) No. 59 (AICPA 1988). (2)
SAS No. 59 and the Reform Act require auditors to evaluate the
continuing existence of every client for a period of one year from the
date of the statements being audited. If, after considering
management's plans and mitigating circumstances, the auditor still
has substantial doubt about the ability of an entity to continue as a
going concern, then the audit report needs to be modified to reflect
such uncertainty. Thus, under current professional and legislative
reporting requirements, the going-concern assessment remains subject to
professional judgment. There are two types of errors that are relevant
in the context of audit reporting on going concern uncertainties. A
"type I reporting error" occurs when the auditor issues a
going-concern modified opinion but the client does not subsequently
fail. A "type II reporting error" occurs when a client files
for bankruptcy without a prior going-concern modified audit report. Note
that under audit reporting standards related to going concern
uncertainties (i.e., SAS No. 59), the auditor is not required to predict
the future status of the client. Auditors need only identify
circumstances that create substantial doubt about the ability of the
client to remain viable for the ensuing year based ion available
information at the time of the audit report. Consequently, the two types
of misclassifications described above are not strictly interpretable as
errors. However, as noted by McKeown et al. (1991b) and Chen and Church
(1992), clients, financial statement users and the public are likely to
perceive both a going-concern modified opinion without subsequent
failure, and a bankruptcy without a prior modification, as audit
reporting errors.
Clients do not welcome the receipt of a going-concern modified
audit report under most circumstances (Kida, 1980; Mutchler, 1984). This
is particularly true if these modified reports are viewed by the company
as unwarranted based on their continued viability. Thus, while not
strictly interpretable as an error, these companies may express
displeasure with their audit firm by taking actions such as switching to
a different auditor (Mutchler, 1984; Chen & Church, 1992; Geiger et
al., 1998). Let the perceived cost associated with this type of
reporting error (i.e., issuing a going-concern modified report when the
client subsequently does not fail) be [C.sub.I]. We assume that
[C.sub.I] increases with the magnitude of the dollar cost directly
associated with a type I reporting error, which would include, but is
not limited to, lost revenues from providing services to a client who
switches to a new auditor. (3)
When a client files for bankruptcy without a prior going-concern
modified opinion (i.e., a type II error), there may be a greater
likelihood that the auditor will face litigation related costs and
suffer a loss of reputation. Carcello and Palmrose (1994) studied
bankruptcy related lawsuits against auditors, and found that auditors
who had issued modified reports prior to client bankruptcy had the
highest dismissal rate and lowest payments, and that auditors who did
not issue prior modified reports had the highest payouts. They noted
that "overall, our evidence suggests a defensive role for timely
modified reporting" (p. 3). Let the perceived cost associated with
this type of reporting error (i.e., not issuing a going-concern modified
report when the client subsequently fails) be [C.sub.II]. We assume that
[C.sub.II] increases with the magnitude of the dollar cost directly
associated with a type II reporting error, which would include, but is
not limited to, costs associated with litigation against the auditor.
In our model, and per SAS No. 59, the audit firm compares the
likelihood of the client's ability to continue as a going concern
against a judgment threshold for "substantial doubt." Let p
represent the audit firm's assessed probability of the
client's inability to continue as a going-concern (or the
likelihood of client failure). If the indifference probability of
failure for substantial doubt is [p.sup.*], then the audit firm will
issue a going-concern modified opinion if p > [p.sup.*]. If p <
[p.sup.*], then the audit firm issues a report without the going-concern
modification. If the indifference probability ([p.sup.*]) is lower, then
the likelihood of issuing a going-concern modified report, ceteris
paribus, is higher. (4)
As noted by Raghunandan and Rama (1995), under such a reporting
model [p.sup.*] = 1 / [1 + ([C.sub.II]/[C.sub.I])]. Thus, as C increases
or as C decreases, the threshold for issuing a going-concern modified
audit report ([p.sup.*]) decreases. Hence, as C increases or as C
decreases, the likelihood of issuing a going-concern modified report
increases.
Existing audit reporting standards, however, do not specify that
[p.sup.*] is to be influenced by the relative magnitudes of an audit
firm's perceived error costs. Thus, a strict interpretation of the
standards would suggest that [p.sup.*] should be independent of either
[C.sub.II] or [C.sub.I]. However, an audit firm trying to minimize its
costs/losses would consider the relative magnitude of [C.sub.II] or
[C.sub.I] in decisions about going-concern report modifications. We now
consider the impact of audit firm size (i.e., Big 6 versus non-Big 6) on
the relative magnitude of [C.sub.II] and [C.sub.I], and hence on
[p.sub.*].
Reporting Decisions: Big 6 and Non-Big 6 Audit Firms
Previous empirical research on the relation between Big 6/non-Big 6
membership and audit quality has primarily focused on the pricing of
audit related services (e.g., Simunic, 1980; Francis & Simon, 1987;
Beatty, 1993), on auditor switching behavior (e.g., Nichols & Smith,
1983; Francis & Wilson, 1988; Johnson & Lys, 1990; DeFond,
1992), information integrity (Teoh & Wang, 1993; Francis et al.,
1999) and industry concentration (Hogan & Jeter, 1999).
Many prior papers have also examined issues related to audit
opinions, including the association between distressed companies, audit
opinions, and bankruptcies (e.g., Carcello et al., 1997; Mutchler et
al., 1997; Louwers, 1998; Foster et al., 1998). A recent study by Morris
and Strawser (1999) found that bank regulators act as if the believe the
Big 6 audit firms are more conservative than non-Big 6 audit firms in
their reporting decisions regarding troubled banks. However, these
studies have not specifically examined whether Big 6 conservatism
actually translates into conservative reporting with regard to troubled
and bankrupt companies. (5)
There are two reasons why audit firm size may impact going-concern
reporting decisions. The reasons are that (1) the "wealth at
risk" for the two types of firms is different, and (2) the client
risk due to portfolio diversification is different for the two types of
firms. These two arguments are discussed in turn below.
Wealth at Risk Argument
The wealth at risk argument suggests that Big 6 audit firms have
more wealth with which to pay plaintiffs in lawsuits filed against
auditors than do non-Big 6 firms. Accordingly, Big 6 firms have more
"wealth at risk" in any particular audit engagement (Simunic
& Stein, 1987, 1996; Menon & Williams, 1999). Hence, large audit
firms stand to suffer disproportionately greater losses for any given
type II error and resultant lawsuit, regardless of the audit fee
generated. This argument, then, suggests that, ceteris paribus, Big 6
firms are more likely to suffer greater lawsuit related losses for a
given type II reporting error. (6) Consequently, [C.sub.II] from a type
II reporting error may be larger for a 6 Big 6 firm for any given
client.
Conversely, with respect to a type I misclassification, the
revenues from any given client constitute a proportionately lower share
of the overall firm revenue for a Big 6 firm than for a non -Big 6 firm.
Thus, the loss of the client, or the threat of the loss of a client,
upon receipt of what is perceived as an unwarranted going-concern
report, would have a proportionately smaller adverse impact on the
wealth of a Big 6 firm than on a non-Big 6 firm. Thus, [C.sub.I] from a
type I reporting error may be proportionately smaller for a Big 6 firm
for any given client.
Together, the above discussion of the wealth at risk argument
suggests that the ratio of [C.sub.II]/[C.sub.1] would be greater for a
Big 6 firm than for a non-Big 6 firm and hence would lead to p* being
lower for a Big 6 firm. This would result in Big 6 audit firms reporting
more conservatively and issuing going-concern modified audit reports to
clients that are less likely to receive a similar opinion from a non-Big
6 audit firm. Thus, if [p.sup.*] (Big 6) < p < [p.sup.*] (non-Big
6) (where p is the assessed probability of failure for a given client),
a Big 6 firm would issue a going-concern qualified audit opinion but a
non-Big 6 firm would not issue such a modified opinion.
In the context of going concern there are two possible future
outcomes for the client-failure or non-failure. Given the reporting
decisions above, if in the future the client does not fail, then the Big
6 firm has a type I reporting error but not the non-Big 6 firm. If the
client fails, then the non-Big 6 firm has a type II reporting error but
not the Big 6 firm. It follows, then, that the wealth at risk argument
leads to the following propositions: (1) the proportion of going-concern
modified reports where the client does not subsequently fail (type I
error) will be higher for Big 6 audit firms, and (2) the proportion of
bankruptcies without a prior going-concern modified opinion (type 11
error) would be lower for Big 6 audit firms.
Portfolio Diversification Argument
Simunic and Stein (1990) suggest that an appropriate analysis of
audit risk must also consider the client portfolio of an audit firm. The
portfolio diversification argument stems from this analysis and is based
on the fact that the Big 6 firms have a larger portfolio of clients.
Hence the Big 6 firms may be able to diversify their risk related to any
one particular audit client's failure more easily than a non-Big 6
firm. A type II misclassification, with a specific magnitude of
litigation loss, can more easily lead to failure of a smaller audit firm
since the pool of clients in their portfolio may be less likely to be
sufficient to cover the lawsuit related losses. (7) Thus, the same
misclassification may be less likely to lead to the failure of the
well-diversified Big 6 firm with its large portfolio of clients.
Consequently, under the portfolio diversification argument, if the
absolute dollar cost of a type II error is the same for a Big 6 and a
non-Big 6 firm, the perceived cost [C.sub.II] may be higher for a
non-Big 6 firm than for a Big 6 firm, leading to more conservative
reporting by the non-Big 6 firms.
However, under the portfolio diversification argument, the effect
of differences in [C.sub.I] based on audit firm size works in the
opposite direction than [C.sub.II] error costs. Because the portfolio of
a Big 6 firm is much more diversified than that of a non-Big 6 firm, the
impact of lost revenues from a displeased client will have a lower
impact on a Big 6 firm than on a non-Big 6 firm. Hence, the perceived
cost [C.sub.I] may be higher for non-Big 6 firms than for Big 6 firms.
(8)
Thus, under the portfolio diversification argument, Big 6 audit
firms may be less conservative due to their ability to diversify
increased risk through a larger portfolio for clients, or may be more
conservative due to the reduced influence of a single client on the
entire firm. This is because both [C.sub.I] and [C.sub.II] are higher
for non-Big 6 firms under the portfolio diversification argument, which
in turn means that it is not possible to make a directional prediction
of conservatism regarding the differences of the Big 6 and non-Big 6
based on the portfolio diversification argument.
Hypotheses
Ex-ante we believe that the wealth at risk argument would dominate
the portfolio diversification argument, resulting in a more conservative
reporting posture by the Big 6 audit firms. This is consistent with
Menon and Williams (1999) and Morris and Strawser (1999) who argue that
litigation risk plays an important role in the audit firm's
decisions, and that Big 6 firms face a higher type II error cost than
non-Big 6 firms, leading them to make conservative decisions. The
empirical evidence in Hogan and Jeter (1999) and Raghunandan and Rama
(1999), indicating that Big 6 auditors are less likely to accept risky
clients, also support the suggestion that Big 6 firms are more
conservative and that the wealth at risk argument may dominate the
portfolio diversification argument. Accordingly, with respect to audit
opinions, we expect that the wealth at risk of the Big 6 firms will lead
to more conservative going-concern reporting by the Big 6 firms compared
to the non-Big 6 firms, which leads to our hypotheses:
[H.sub.01]: Type I error rates are higher for going-concern opinion
decisions of Big 6 firms.
[H.sub.02]: Type II error rates are lower for bankrupt clients of
Big 6 firms.
METHOD
Hypothesis One
Research Design
Hypothesis one is concerned with the resolution of going concern
uncertainties for companies receiving going-concern modified opinions,
and examines whether subsequent failure rates are different for clients
of Big 6 and non-Big 6 audit firms. We would expect that if Big 6 firms
are more conservative with respect to their reporting decisions, that
they would experience higher type I reporting errors due to their
increased propensity to issue modified reports to less stressed
companies.
A set of companies receiving first-time going-concern modified
audit reports was identified to test hypothesis one. Kida (1980) and
Mutchler (1984) have documented the reluctance of audit firms to both
issue a going-concern modification, and then to remove the modification
once it has been rendered to a specific client. Mutchler and Williams
(1990) noted that "the fact that the company already has the
qualification becomes a variable in the auditor's decision model,
and thus, these observations represent a different type of decision for
the auditor. In addition, it can be argued that auditors risk
preferences are different for these companies, i.e., the auditor may no
longer have to consider the risk of losing the client if a going-concern
opinion is issued". Hence, we consider only companies receiving
first-time going-concern opinion modifications to test hypothesis one.
Companies in greater financial stress may be more likely to fail or
enter into bankruptcy than non-stressed companies. Hence, we use level
of financial stress as a control variable. There are many 0different
financial distress models in the accounting literature. In this study,
we use the probability of bankruptcy (PRB) calculated from
Zmijewski's (1984) model as a surrogate for financial stress in
evaluating hypothesis one, because (a) it has been used widely in a
variety of auditing contexts (Bamber et al., 1993; Chen & Wei, 1993;
Wheeler et al., 1993; Carcello et al., 1995, 1999), (b) it is
parsimonious, which means fewer observations have to be deleted for lack
of available data, and (c) it is free of some statistical problems
associated with other models.
Prior research suggests that company size influences the
going-concern modified audit opinion decision, and that companies in
default may be more likely to receive a going-concern modified audit
opinion, even after controlling for financial stress (McKeown et al.,
1991a; Chen & Church, 1992). Although we are assessing subsequent
failure of firms receiving a first-time going -concern modified report
and not the reporting decision itself, we use company size, as measured
by the natural log of sales, and default status as control factors in
the analysis.
Carcello et al. (1999) examined going-concern modified reporting
and partner compensation plans and found a significant positive effect
for the implementation of SAS No. 59 on audit reporting decisions. Since
our data include going-concern modified opinions from the period before
and after the required implementation of SAS No. 59, we also include
reporting time period (pre-or post-SAS No. 59) as a control factor in
our analysis.
The relationship between subsequent failure and the factors
discussed above is examined using a logistic regression to estimate the
coeffcients in the following model:
[GC.sub.BANK] = b0 + b1 * PRB + b2 * dft + b3 * LNSL + b4 * TIME +
b5 * BIG6
where
[GC.sub.BANK] = Bankrupt (1 if yes, 0 if not) given a first-time
going-concern modified opinion,
PRB = Probability of bankruptcy, calculated from Zmijewski's
(1984) model,
DFT = 1 if in default, 0 otherwise,
LNSL = Natural log of sales (in thousands of dollars),
TIME = 1 if post-SAS No. 59 time period, 0 otherwise, and
BIG6 = 1 if a Big 6 firm, 0 otherwise.
Filing for bankruptcy is a stringent definition of company failure
(Carcello & Palmrose, 1994). Mutchler and Williams (1990) use an
alternative definition of failure by also including companies that enter
into payment default on debt during the period subsequent to the receipt
of their going-concern report. Thus, an additional definition of
failure, based on bankruptcy filing or entering into payment default
(BAD), was also used to assess these first-time going-concern modified
report recipients. Accordingly, we also test hypothesis one by using
this broader definition of failure, for the sub-sample of companies not
already in payment default at the time of the receipt of the
going-concern modified audit report. (10)
Data Collection
A sample of companies receiving first-time going-concern reports is
needed to test hypothesis one. It is possible that industry
characteristics could influence the relative threshold ([p.sup.*]) for
going -concern modified audit reports. In particular, audits of
companies in sectors such as banking, other financial services and real
estate have been considered to be particularly risky for all audit
firms. In addition, prior researchers examining issues related to
going-concern modified audit reporting have typically excluded such
firms, as well as those in other regulated industries (Mutchler, 1985;
McKeown et al., 1991a). Consequently, we limited our analyses to
manufacturing firms (SIC codes 20 through 39).
Compact Disclosure (CD)-SEC was our source for identifying all
manufacturing companies with first-time going-concern modified reports
during the period 1987 through 1994. Financial and default data were
obtained from CD-SEC, and from annual reports and 10-ks on Laser
Disclosure and LEXIS-NEXIS.. We excluded companies with fiscal year-ends
in 1989, however, because audit firms exhibited anomalous reporting
behavior in the SAS No. 59 transition period (Carcello et al., 1997) and
there were differences in the timing of the adoption of SAS No. 59 by
different audit firms (Spires & Williams, 1990).
The following sources were used to identify the subsequent year
resolutions of going concern uncertainties faced by the firms in our
sample: 1) Wall Street Journal Index, 2) CD-SEC, 3) Bloomberg Financial
Services, 4) Predicast's Index of Corporate Change, 5) LEXIS-NEXIS,
and 6) a list of public company bankruptcies obtained from New
Generation Research Inc., publishers of the yearly Bankruptcy Almanac.
Only firms for which subsequent financial statements were found, and not
in bankruptcy, were designated as non-failed firms. Based on these data
requirements, our sample consisted of 533 companies with first-time
going-concern modified reports.
As noted earlier, we also examined hypothesis one by using an
expanded definition of failure that includes bankruptcy and entering
into payment default on debt (BAD). Since our initial sample includes
companies that were in payment default at the time they received their
initial going-concern modified report, we eliminated these 98 companies
for this test. Accordingly, this analysis was performed on the 435
companies not in payment default at the time they received their
first-time going-concern modified report.
Hypothesis Two
Research Design
Hypothesis two is concerned with the proportion of bankruptcies
with prior going-concern modified reports. We would expect that if Big 6
firms were more conservative in reporting on going concern that they
would have fewer type II errors than non-Big 6 firms due to issuing more
going-concern modified opinions prior to bankruptcy. To test this
hypothesis, a set of bankrupt companies was identified. Again, to
control for other audit reporting related factors, a multivariate
logistic regression was used.
Prior research suggests that a going-concern modified audit report
is more likely when (1) there is greater financial stress, (2) there is
debt default, (3) the bankruptcy lag (time period from audit report date
to bankruptcy date) is smaller, (4) the audit reporting lag (time period
from fiscal year end to audit report date) is larger, and (5) the
company is smaller (McKeown et al., 1991a; Chen & Church, 1992;
Raghunandan & Rama, 1995; Mutchler et al., 1997). Hence, these
variables are included as control factors. In summary, to test
hypothesis two we estimate the coefficients in the following logistic
regression:
[BANK.sub.GC] = b0 + b1 * PRB + b2 * DFT + B3 * BKLAG * b4 * REPLAG
+ b5 * LNSL + b6 * BIG6,
where
[BANK.sub.GC] = 1 if audit report prior to bankruptcy is
going-concern modified; else 0,
PRB = Probability of bankruptcy, calculated from Zmijewski's
(1984) model,
DFT = 1 if company was in default at the time of opinion; 0
otherwise,
BKLAG = Time, in square root of days from audit report date to
bankruptcy date,
REPLAG = Time, in square root of days from fiscal year end to audit
report date,
LNSL = Natural log of sales (in thousands of dollars), and
BIG6 = 1 if the auditor was a Big 6 firm, 0 otherwise.
Data Collection
To test hypothesis two, a fist of public company bankruptcies was
obtained from New Generation Research Inc. Relevant financial statement
and auditor data were obtained from CD -SEC, and from annual reports and
10-k filings (on Laser Disclosure). We deleted companies in the banking,
other financial, real estate and regulated industries. This is because
such companies have unique financial characteristics and are not
amenable to the measure of financial stress used in our analyses, and/or
the error costs for auditors could be different in regulated industries
compared to other industries. We were able to obtain complete data for
247 companies which entered into bankruptcy over the period 1991-1995.
(11)
RESULTS
Hypothesis One
Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for the sample of companies
with first-time goingconcern modified reports that were also used to
test hypothesis one. The Big 6 audited 343 companies in our sample,
compared to 190 audited by the non-Big 6. As seen in the table, only
12.4 percent (66 of 533) of the companies that received a first-time
going-concern modified opinion entered into bankruptcy in the subsequent
year. This finding is consistent with the survival rates found in prior
studies examining going-concern modified report recipients (Altman,
1982; Mutchler & Williams, 1990). The mean PRB scores for clients of
Big 6 and non-Big 6 auditors were 0.66 and 0.73, respectively. The
proportions of companies in default at the time they received their
first-time going-concern opinion were 45.8 percent for the Big 6 and
26.8 percent for the non-Big 6. In addition, the LNSL values for clients
of Big 6 and non-Big 6 auditors were 9.48 and 7.71, respectively.
Fifty-one of the 343 companies (14.8 percent) receiving a first-time
going-concern modified audit report from a Big 6 firm entered into
bankruptcy within one year. The corresponding bankruptcy proportion for
the 190 clients of non-Big 6 firms was 7.9 percent (15 companies).
The last two columns of Table 1 provide descriptive information on
the companies not in payment default when they received their initial
going-concern audit report that were used in the BAD analysis. Of the
435 initial non-payment-default companies, 24.8 percent (85 companies)
entered into either bankruptcy or payment default within one year.
Forty-seven of the 271 companies (17.3 percent) audited by the Big 6
entered bankruptcy or payment default, while 38 of the 164 companies
(23.2 percent) audited by the non-Big 6 entered into bankruptcy or
payment default within one year.
Results from the logistic regression for bankruptcy are presented
in Table 2. The overall bankruptcy regression is significant (chi-square
= 34.25 with 5 d.f., significant at p<.0001) and the c-statistic,
measuring the extent of association between predicted probabilities and
observed responses, is 0.71. In the regression, the coefficients on the
PRB and LNSL variables are in the expected directions and are
statistically significant. The coefficient for the DFT variable is in
the expected direction but is not significant for this group of already
financially stressed companies. The coefficient for the TIME variable
(for pre-post-SAS No. 59) is positive and significant, consistent with
the findings of Carcello et al. (1999). The Big 6 variable, however, is
not significant in this analysis of company failure defined as
subsequently filing for bankruptcy.
Results of the logistic regression considering BAD status (entering
bankruptcy or payment default) as the definition of company failure for
the reduced sample of 435 companies is also reported in Table 2. As seen
in the table, the model chi-square of 39.28 is significant at p <
.0001 with 4 d.f, and has a c-statistic of 0.71. In addition, and
consistent with the bankruptcy analysis, all of the remaining control
variables are positive and significant at p-values below .05. Using BAD
as a definition of company failure, the BIG6 variable was negative and
significant (p = .0061). This result indicates that the Big 6 audit
firms had a lower proportion of going-concern report recipients who
entered bankruptcy or payment default, and thus had a higher proportion
of type I errors. Thus, when failure is defined as entering into
bankruptcy or newly entering into payment default, type I errors are
higher for Big 6 audit firms relative to non-Big 6 audit firms. This
finding is consistent with hypothesis one and suggests that the Big 6
audit firms have higher type I error rates than non-Big 6 firms for this
broader definition of company failure. (12)
Hypothesis Two
Table 3 provides descriptive statistics about the set of bankrupt
companies used in this study. As seen in the last row of Table 3, 57
percent (121 of 211) of the bankrupt companies with a Big 6 auditor
received a prior going-concern modified audit report, and 42 percent (15
of 36) of the bankrupt companies with a non-Big 6 auditor received a
prior going-concern modified audit report.
Table 4 provides the results from the logistic regression with
audit report type as the dependent variable. The overall model is
significant (chi-square = 156.0, with 6 d.f., significant at p <
.0001) and the c-statistic is 0.91. The coefficients for financial
distress, default status, bankruptcy lag, and company size are in the
expected directions and are significant. These results indicate that
auditors were more likely to have issued prior going-concern modified
reports for companies in greater financial stress, companies in default,
companies with a shorter bankruptcy lag and smaller companies. The
coefficient for the BIG6 variable is significant (p = .031), which
supports the second hypothesis. Big 6 audit firms were more likely than
non-Big 6 firms to have issued a prior going-concern modified report for
companies that subsequently declared bankruptcy. (13)
Additional Analyses
ANCOVA Model
If the Big 6 firms are more conservative, and hence more likely to
issue a going-concern modified audit opinion (i.e., exhibit a lower
[p.sup.*]), then it is likely that firms receiving a first-time
going-concern modified audit opinion would, on average, exhibit lower
financial stress. To examine if companies receiving a going-concern
modified opinion from Big 6 and non-Big 6 firms may be different with
respect to their level of financial stress, we performed an unbalanced
ANCOVA analysis on the sample of firms receiving a first-time
going-concern modified audit opinion. The dependent variable was the
probability of bankruptcy (PRB), Big 6 classification was the
independent class variable, and the log of sales (LNSL) and default
status (DFT) were used as two covariates.
Results of the ANCOVA indicate that the overall model is
significant (p<.01), along with both covariates, and that the mean
covariate adjusted PRB score for clients of the Big 6 firms (.666) was
significantly lower than that for clients of non-Big 6 firms (.720) (p
< .05). Thus, these results provide further evidence indicating that,
ceteris paribus, Big 6 firms were generally more conservative and had
lower indifference probabilities ([p.sup.*]) than non-Big 6 firms with
respect to companies receiving their first-time going-concern modified
audit report.
Strategic Bankruptcies
Our analysis for hypothesis two includes all bankruptcies,
irrespective of the nature of the bankruptcy. It is possible that some
bankruptcies may be strategic, and not as a result of financial
distress. To ensure that the results are not being driven by such
strategic bankruptcies, we deleted companies which did not have at least
one of the following indicators of financial stress: (1) negative net
income, (2) negative working capital and (3) negative stockholder's
equity. (14) When the analysis was performed with this sub-sample, the
BIG6 variable continued to remain significant (p < .05), and the
significance of the other variables was substantively similar to the
results presented in Table 4.
SUMMARY AND DISCUSSION
This study examined whether the Big 6 audit firms in the U. S. are
more conservative than non-Big 6 firms in their reporting decisions
regarding going concern. An analysis of the subsequent viability status
of 533 first-time going-concern recipient companies indicates that when
client failure is defined as bankruptcy only, there was no significant
difference in type I error rates between Big 6 and non-Big 6 firms.
However, when client failure is defined as bankruptcy or entering into
payment default, the Big 6 firms had significantly higher type I error
rates. Results from the analysis of 247 bankrupt firms indicates that,
after controlling for financial and reporting factors, Big 6 audit firms
were more likely to have issued a prior going-concern modified opinion.
(15) Additional analyses also found that the mean levels of financial
distress were lower for companies receiving a first-time going-concern
modified opinion from a Big 6 firm than from a non-Big 6 firm.
Together, our results suggest that the Big 6 audit firms are
generally more conservative than non-Big 6 firms in their audit report
decisions regarding going-concern modifications and the related
differences in reporting errors were empirically consistent with the
hypotheses. Our results also support the conclusions of Morris and
Strawser (1999) that financial regulators in the U.S. behave as if the
Big 6 audit firms report more conservatively than the non-Big 6 firms
when issuing modified reports to troubled companies.
The interpretation of our results is subject to the following
limitations. First, we only examine differences between the Big 6 and
non-Big 6 firms. While this is consistent with the approach taken by
many previous auditing researchers, we do not examine the overall size
effects of audit firms by using a continuous audit firm size measure, or
whether there exist differences between national non-Big 6 firms (i.e.,
second-tier firms) and local/regional firms. Second, the support for the
first hypotheses is dependent on the definition of firm failure. Some
might suggest that a move from non-default status to default status is
more serious than the move from default to bankruptcy, because entering
default could lead to many adverse consequences (such as initial loss of
control or re-negotiation of debt on adverse terms). However, since
bankruptcy is the most extreme manifestation of possible adverse
consequences, others would suggest that the move to bankruptcy (from
default status) is more serious than the move to default (from clean
status). Given that our results indicate significance for only one of
these two definitions of company failure, our results should be
interpreted as offering modest support for the first hypothesis.
The results presented in this paper generally support the wealth at
risk argument, which suggests that the Big 6 firms would be more
conservative because of their greater wealth at risk in an audit of any
given client. Our findings are consistent with those of prior
researchers who have found evidence that the Big 6 firms are more
conservative than non-Big 6 firms in a variety of auditor-client
interactions. Together the extant research suggests that the Big 6 firms
in the U.S. generally appear to be (1) more conservative in their client
selection and retention decisions and (2) more conservative in their
reporting decisions on those clients.
One reason for the dominance of the wealth at risk argument and the
conservative posture of the Big 6 may be the litigation environment in
the U.S. In particular, as reflected by the large magnitude of judgments
in some recent litigation involving audit firms, very few lawsuits may
be sufficient to cause the failure of even a large audit firm. In other
words, the catastrophic nature of litigation losses may overwhelm the
benefit of client portfolio diversification.
In the context of initial public offerings, Clarkson and Simunic
(1994) show that the different litigation environments of the U.S. and
Canada lead to significant differences in the market for audit services.
Specifically, they find that large auditors were more likely to serve as
auditors for initial public offerings involving riskier clients in
Canada but not in the U.S. Thus, an interesting area for future research
is to examine differences in audit reporting in countries where auditors
are subject to a less hostile litigation environment.
REFERENCES
American Institute of Certified Public Accountants. (1988).
Statement on Auditing Standards No. 59, The Auditor's Consideration
of an Entity's Ability to Continue as a Going Concern. New York:
AICPA.
Altman, E. I. (1982). Accounting implications of failure prediction
models. Journal of Accounting Auditing and Finance, (Fall), 4-19.
Bamber, M., L. Bamber & M. Schoderbek. (1993). Audit structure
and other determinants of audit report lag: An empirical analysis.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, (Spring), 1-23.
Beatty, R.P. (1993). The economic determinants of auditor
compensation in the initial public offerings market. Journal of
Accounting Research,(Autumn), 294-302.
Carcello, J., D. Hermanson & F. Huss. (1995). Temporal changes
in bankruptcy-related reporting. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and
Theory, (Fall), 133-143.
Carcello, J., D. Hermanson & F. Huss. (1997). The effect of SAS
No. 59: How treatment of the transition period influences results.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, (Spring), 114-123.
Carcello, J., D. Hermanson & F. Huss. (1999). Going-concern
opinions: The effects of partner compensation plans and client size.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, (forthcoming).
Carcello, J. & Z. Palmrose. (1994). Auditor litigation and
modified reporting on bankrupt clients. Journal of Accounting Research,
(Supplement): 1-30.
Chen, K. C. W. & B.K. Church. (1992). Default on debt
obligations and the issuance of goingconcern opinions. Auditing: A
Journal of Practice and Theory, (Fall), 30-49.
Chen , K. C. .W. & Wei. (1993). Creditors' decisions to
waive violations of accounting-based debt covenants. The Accounting
Review, (April), 218-232.
Chow, C. W. & S. Rice. (1982). Qualified Audit Opinions and
Auditor Switching. The Accounting Review, (April), 326-335.
Clarkson, P. & D. A. Simunic. (1994). The association between
audit quality, retained ownership and firm-specific risk in US vs.
Canadian IPO markets. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 17, 207-228.
DeAngelo, L. E. (1981). Auditor size and audit quality. Journal of
Accounting and Economics, 3, 183-199.
DeFond, M. L. (1992). The association between changes in client
firm agency costs and auditor switching. Auditing: A Journal of Practice
and Theory, (Fall), 16-31.
Foster, B.P., T.J. Ward & J. Woodroof. (1998). An analysis of
the usefulness of debt defaults and going-concern opinions in bankruptcy
risk assessment. Journal of Accounting, Auditing, and Finance, (Summer),
331-371.
Francis, J. R. (1984). The effect of audit firm size on audit
prices: A study of the Australian market. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, (August), 133-151.
Francis, J. R. & D. T. Simon. (1987). A test of audit pricing
in the small client segment of the U.S. audit market. The Accounting
Review, (January), 145-157.
Francis, J. R. & E.R. Wilson. (1988). Auditor changes: A joint
test of theories relating to agency costs and auditor differentiation.
The Accounting Review, 63 (October), 663-682.
Francis, J. R. & J. K. Reynolds. (1999). Evidence on risk-based
client screening by Big Six audit firms. Working paper, University of
Missouri-Columbia.
Francis, J. R., E. L. Maydew & H. C. Sparks. (1999). The role
of Big 6 auditors in the credible reporting of accruals. Auditing: A
Journal of Practice and Theory, (Fall), 17-34.
Geiger, M. A., K. Raghunandan & D. V. Rama. (1998). Cost
associated with going-concern modified audit opinions: An analysis of
auditor changes, subsequent opinions, and client failures. Advances in
Accounting, 16, 117-139.
Gul, F. A. (1999). Audit prices, product differentiation and
economic equilibrium. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory,
(Spring), 90-100.
Hopwood, W., J. McKeown & J. Mutchler. (1989). A test of the
incremental explanatory power of opinions qualified for consistency and
uncertainty. The Accounting Review, (January), 28-48.
Hogan, C. E. & D. C. Jeter. (1999). Industry specialization by
auditors. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, (Spring), 1-17.
Johnson, W. B. & T. Lys. (1990). The market for audit services:
Evidence from voluntary auditor changes. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, (January), 281-308.
Kasznik, R. & B. Lev. (1995). To warn or not to warn:
Management disclosures in the face of earnings surprise. The Accounting
Review, (January), 113-134.
Louwers, T. (1998). The relation between going-concern opinions and
the auditor's loss function. Journal of Accounting Research,
(Spring), 143-156.
McKeown, J. C., J. F. Mutchler & W. Hopwood. (1991a). Towards
an explanation of auditor failure to modify the audit opinion of
bankrupt companies. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory,
(Supplement): 1-13.
McKeown, J. C., J. F. Mutchler & W. Hopwood. (1991b). Reply.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, (Supplement): 21-24.
Menon, K. & D. D. Williams. (1999). Error cost and
auditors' termination decisions. Journal of Accounting, Auditing
& Finance, (Spring), 95-123.
Morris, M. H. & W. D. Nichols. (1988). Consistency exceptions:
Materiality judgments and audit firm structure. The Accounting Review,
(April), 237-254.
Morris R. E. & J. R. Strawser. (1999). An examination of the
effect of CPA firm type on bank regulators' closure decisions.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, (Fall), 142-158.
Mutchler, J. (1984). Auditor's perceptions of the
going-concern opinion. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory,
(Spring), 17-30.
Mutchler, J. (1985). A multivariate analysis of the auditor's
going-concern opinion decision. Journal of Accounting Research,
(Autumn), 668-682.
Mutchler, J., W. Hopwood & J.C. McKeown. (1997). The influence
of contrary information and mitigating factors on audit opinion
decisions on bankrupt companies. Journal of Accounting Research,
(Autumn), 295-310.
Mutchler, J. & D. D. Williams. (1990). The relationship between
audit technology, client risk profiles, and the going-concern opinion
decision. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, (Fall), 39-54.
Nichols, D. R. & D. B. Smith. (1983). Auditor credibility and
auditor changes. Journal of Accounting Research, (Autumn), 534-544.
Ohlson, J. A. (1980). Financial ratios and the probabilistic
prediction of bankruptcy. Journal of Accounting Research, (Spring),
109-131.
Palmrose, Z. V. (1986). Audit fees and auditor size: Further
evidence. Journal of Accounting Research, (Spring), 97-110.
Pratt, J. & J.D. Stice. (1994). The effects of client
characteristics on auditor litigation risk judgments, required audit
evidence, and recommended audit fees. The Accounting Review, (October),
639-656.
Private Securities Litigation Reform Act: 1995. Public Law 104-67.
Washington, D.C.:GPO.
Raghunandan, K. & D. V. Rama. (1995). Audit reports for
companies in financial distress: Before and after SAS No. 59. Auditing:
A Journal of Practice and Theory, (Spring), 50-63.
Raghunandan, K. & D. V. Rama. (1999). Auditor resignations and
the market for audit services. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and
Theory, (Spring), 124-134.
Simon D. & J.R. Francis. (1988). The effects of auditor change
on audit fees: Test of price cutting and price recovery. The Accounting
Review, (April), 255-269.
Simunic, D. (1980). The pricing of audit services: Theory and
evidence. Journal of Accounting Research, (Spring), 161-190.
Simunic, D. & M. T. Stein. (1987). Product differentiation in
auditing: Auditor choice in the market for unseasoned new issues,
Research Monograph No. 13 Vancouver: The Canadian Certified General
Accountants' Research Foundation).
Simunic, D. & M. T. Stein. (1990). Audit risk in a client
portfolio context. Contemporary Accounting Research, (Spring), 329-343.
Simunic, D. & M. T. Stein. (1996). The impact of litigation
risk on audit pricing: A review of the economics and the evidence.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, (Supplement): 119-134.
Spires, E. & D. Williams. (1990). Auditors' adoption of
SAS 58 audit reports. Accounting Horizons, (September), 76-82.
Teoh, S. & T. Wong. (1993). Perceived auditor quality and the
earnings response coefficient. The Accounting Review, 68, (April),
346-367.
U.S. House of Representatives. (1985). Hearings Before the
Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations of the Committee on Energy
and Commerce, (February 20), No. 99-17.
U.S. House of Representatives. (1990). Hearings Before the
Subcommittee on Telecommunications and Finance of the Committee on
Energy and Commerce, (August 2), No.101-196.
Wheeler, S., K. Pany & E. Chewning. (1993). Inter-Firm
differences in propensities to modify audit opinions for pre-SAS No. 58
accounting principles changes. Accounting Horizons, (September), 46-54.
Zmijewski, M. E. (1984). Methodological issues related to the
estimation of financial distress prediction models. Journal of
Accounting Research, (Supplement), 59-82.
ENDNOTES
(1) A large majority of these studies have been performed before
the mergers among the largest accounting firms 1 reduced their number
from eight to six to five. This study includes data from the time period
before the number of the largest firms was reduced to five, so we refer
to the "Big 6" in this paper.
(2) The Private Securities Reform Act (1995) has an audit
requirement section related to going-concern reporting. 2 Specifically,
the Act requires that
"Each audit ..of the financial statements of an issuer by an
independent public accountant shall include, in accordance with
generally accepted auditing standards, as may be modified or
supplemented from time to time by the Commission (SEC) ... an evaluation
of whether there is a substantial doubt about the ability of the issuer
to continue as a going concern during the ensuing fiscal year."
This is the only instance where Congress has mandated a specific
auditing standard for financial statement audits since its inception
under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934.
(3) Note that the revenues lost include not only audit fees, but
also revenues from the supply of non-audit services. 3 In addition,
there also may be costs associated with other displeased existing
clients who may switch to another audit firm, or from potential clients
who choose a different audit firm.
(4) The firm view is appropriate for understanding going-concern
modified audit reporting because more extensive 4 consultation with
others within the audit firm is likely to occur in the case of
distressed companies (such as those receiving a going-concern modified
audit opinion). Furthermore, at a minimum, second partner reviews are
required for public companies, requiring at least one additional firm
partner to concur with the audit opinion rendered.
(5) Mutchler (1984) examined audit firm size as a factor in
assessing the issuance of a going-concern qualified 5 opinion. However,
her analysis focused only on the issuance of going-concern qualified
opinions to stressed companies, and did not assess the resolution of the
going-concern opinions to the companies that received them, or prior
audit opinions for bankrupt companies.
(6) This argument assumes that lawsuit related losses of audit
firms are not linear functions of the client revenue 6 derived from the
audit engagement being litigated.
(7) For example, Pratt and Stice (1994) note that "partners
from Laventhol & Horwath, previously the seventh 7 largest
accounting firm in the U.S., cited litigation claims against their firm
in their decision to declare bankruptcy" (p. 639).
(8) In addition a Big 6 firm may charge higher audit fees and also
may have greater non-audit service related 8 revenues from a given
client. Francis and Simon (1987) note that the average Big 6 fee premium
in various studies ranges from 16 to 19 percent. However, the size of
the smallest Big 6 firm is many times greater than that of the largest
non-Big 6 firm. Consequently, while Big 6 fee premia may mitigate the
lower [C.sub.I] for a Big 6 firm, they may not completely eliminate this
phenomenon.
Further, it may be infeasible for some clients to switch auditors
from a Big 6 firm to a non-Big 6 firm, due in part to the pressures from
investors and creditors to maintain a Big 6 auditor. This may afford the
Big 6 firms greater leverage to issue a going-concern modified report
with a reduced fear of losing the client. These factors could then lead
to a relatively lower [C.sub.I] for a Big 6 firm and result in more
conservative reporting.
(9) Our analysis focuses on differences in the perceived costs
associated with the two types of audit reporting errors across Big 6 and
non-Big 6 audit firms. That is, audit firms' reporting decisions
are influenced by their perceptions of the future consequences of their
decisions. It is plausible to suggest that audit firms may have
considered the costs associated with reporting errors and accordingly
priced risk into their engagement fee. However, to make specific
predictions about the impact of audit firm size on audit reporting and
pricing, there have to be systematic differences in the relative
magnitudes of risk premia (if any) incorporated into audit fees by Big 6
and non-Big 6 firms. This is an unanswered empirical question, and
arguments can be marshaled on both sides. Consequently, we cannot make
ex-ante predictions in a specific direction related the impact of risk
premia on audit reports. Further, Simunic and Stein (1996) found that in
the context of one large public accounting firm, auditors responded to
client-specific increases in litigation risk by increasing the audit
fee; however, this was largely due to changes in audit effort as opposed
to the audit firm charging a higher price premium for client risk.
(10) As discussed later, an even broader definition of failure
would include bankruptcy as well as both payment and 10 technical
default. We also performed analyses using this alternative definition of
BAD. The results from such additional analyses were substantively the
same as those reported in the paper.
(11) SAS No. 59 specifically noted that the term "reasonable
period of time" meant one year from the date of the 11 financial
statements. Our sample includes companies where the audit report on the
preceding financial statements was dated more than one year prior to the
bankruptcy date. When we restricted our analysis to only those companies
where the bankruptcy occurred within one year of the preceding fiscal
year end, the results were substantively the same as those reported in
this paper.
(12) We performed sensitivity analysis by using an even broader
definition of failure, by also considering technical 12 default.
Specifically, we considered a company to have failed if any one of the
following conditions were met: (a) filing for bankruptcy, (b) entering
payment default or (c) entering technical default. Analysis with this
expanded definition was performed on those companies not already in
technical or payment default (or bankruptcy) at the time they received
the initial going-concern modified audit opinion. The logistic
regression results for this reduced sample (n=325) were substantively
similar to those presented in Table 2. Specifically, all control
variable coefficients were positive and significant (p<.05), and the
coefficient on the Big 6 variable was negative and significant (p
<.01).
(13) We performed sensitivity analysis by including a dummy
variable for firms in high-tech industries, as defined 13 in Kasznik and
Lev (1995). In such analysis, the results remained substantively similar
to those presented in Table 4 and the Big 6 variable continued to remain
significant (p < .05).
(14) The financial stress indicators are based upon the measures
used by prior researchers, such as McKeown et al. 14 (1991a). Note that
the third factor used here, negative stockholder's equity, is a
more stringent measure than the negative retained earnings measure used
by McKeown et al. (1991a).
(15) Mutchler et al. (1997) found that their Big 6 variable was not
significant in explaining differences in audit 15 opinions prior to
bankruptcy. One possible reason for our different results may be the
different nature of the samples. In particular, Mutchler et al. (1997)
include only companies traded on the NYSE or AMEX, while our sample
includes a substantial number of companies (191 out of 247) not traded
on these exchanges. Companies listed on the NYSE and AMEX may be
different along many dimensions than companies not traded on such
exchanges.
Marshall A. Geiger, University of Richmond
K. Raghunandan, Texas A & M International University
TABLE 1: Descriptive Statistics--Going Concern Modified Opinion
Sample (Means)
Auditor (n = 533) Bankrupt (n = 533)
Non-Big 6
Item Big 6 (n = 343) (n = 190) Yes (n = 66) No (n = 467)
PRB 0.66 0.73 0.76 0.67
DFT 157 (45.8%) 51 (26.8%) 39 (59.1%) 169 (36.2%)
LNSL 9.48 7.71 10.13 8.67
BKT 51 (14.9%) 15 (7.9%) -- --
BAD * 47 17.3% 38 (23.2%) -- --
BAD * (n = 435)
Item Yes (n = 85) No (n = 350)
PRB 0.74 0.66
DFT 31 (36.5%) 79 (22.6%)
LNSL 9.42 8.40
BKT -- --
BAD * -- --
Legend:
PRB = Probability of bankruptcy, calculated from Zmijewski's (1984)
model.
DFT = In default when receiving modified report.
LNSL = Natural log of sales (in thousands of dollars).
BKT = Bankrupt within one year from the financial statement date.
BAD = Bankrupt or in payment default within one year from the
financial statement date.
* Note that the BAD sample includes only companies which were
not in payment default at the time of receiving the initial
going-concern modified audit opinion. There were 435 such
companies, of which 271 were audited by the Big 6.
TABLE 2: Subsequent Resolution Model--Going-Concern Modified Sample
Logistic Regressions: [GC.sub.BANK]/[GC.sub.BAD] =
f(PRB, DFT, LNSL, TIME, BIG6)
Bankruptcy Analysis (n = 533)
Variable Coefficient Chi-square Signif. *
Intercept -5.62 50.27 .0001
PRB 0.91 4.31 .0189
DFT 0.21 0.47 .2461
LNSL 0.22 10.11 .0008
TIME 0.71 3.75 .0264
BIG6 0.40 1.41 .1178
Model chi-sq. 34.25
p-value .0001
c-statistic 0.71
BAD Analysis (n = 435)
Variable Coefficient Chi-square Signif. *
Intercept -4.35 45.34 .0001
PRB 0.75 3.78 .0261
DFT -- -- --
LNSL 0.23 14.73 .0001
TIME 1.10 11.98 .0003
BIG6 -0.70 6.27 .0061
Model chi-sq. 39.28
p-value .0001
c-statistic 0.71
Legend:
[GC.sub.Bank] = 1 if entered bankruptcy, 0 otherwise.
[GC.sub.BAD] = 1 if entered bankruptcy or payment default,
0 otherwise.
PRB = Probability of bankruptcy, calculated from Zmijewski's
(1984) model.
DFT = 1 if in default, 0 otherwise.
LNSL = Natural log of sales (in thousands of dollars).
TIME = 1 if post-SAS No. 59, 0 otherwise.
BIG6 = 1 if Big 6 auditor, 0 otherwise.
* Significance levels are one-tail, except for the intercept term.
TABLE 3: Descriptive Statistics--Bankrupt Sample (Means)
Auditor Audit Report
Big 6 Non-Big 6 GC NGC
Item (n = 211) (n = 36) (n = 136) (n = 111)
LNSL 11.39 9.88 10.78 11.68
BKLAG 14.30 13.51 13.28 15.22
REPLAG 8.90 9.45 9.28 8.60
PRB 0.68 0.53 0.83 0.43
Proportion in default 60% 39% 76% 34%
Proportion with 57% 42% -- --
going-concern
modified opinion
Legend:
LNSL = Natural log of sales (in thousands of dollars).
BKLAG = Time, in sq. root of days from audit report date to
bankruptcy date.
REPLAG = Time, in sq. root of days from fiscal year end to
audit report date.
PRB = Probability of bankruptcy, calculated from Zmijewski's
(1984) model.
TABLE 4: Audit Report Model--Bankrupt Sample
Logistic Regression: [BANK.sub.GC] = f(PRB, DFT, BKLAG, REPLAG,
LNSL, BIG6)
Expected
Variable Sign Coefficient Chi-square Significance *
Intercept 3.94 3.77 .052
PRB + 4.30 43.97 .0001
DFT + 2.04 22.87 .0001
BKLAG - -0.20 11.53 .0007
REPLAG + 0.11 0.70 .401
LNSL - -0.61 25.51 .0001
BIG6 + 1.27 4.65 .031
Model Chi-square = 156.0, 6 df., p < .0001; c-statistic = 0.91
Legend:
[BANK.sub.GC] = 1 if going-concern modified, 0 otherwise.
PRB = Probability of bankruptcy, calculated from Zmijewski(1984).
DFT = 1 if company in financial default, 0 otherwise.
BKLAG = Time, in sq. root of days from audit report date to
bankruptcy date.
REPLAG = Tim e, in sq. root of days from fiscal year end to audit
report date.
LNSL = Natural log of sales (in thousands of dollars).
BIG6 = 1 if Big 6 auditor, 0 otherwise.
* Significance levels are one-tail, except for the intercept term.