Beta stability and the 1986 Tax Reform Act: some dividend policy implications.
Casey, K. Michael ; Duncan, John B. ; Watters, Michael P. 等
INTRODUCTION
The 1986 Tax Reform Act (TRA) represented the greatest change in
United States tax laws in recent years, both for corporations and
individuals. One of the major changes made by TRA was to eliminate much
of the preferential treatment afforded capital gains. With the passage
of TRA, the tax treatment of private investor income, whether from
capital gains or dividends, became more balanced. Assuming that
investors maximize after-tax, risk-adjusted portfolio returns,
investment preferences should have changed.
Between June 1981 and December 1986, the federal government allowed
taxpayers to exclude 60 percent of capital gains from taxation. During
this time period, maximum marginal tax rates of 50 percent applied to
dividend income and maximum marginal tax rates of 20 percent applied to
capital gains. The 1986 TRA eliminated the capital gains exclusion,
raising the maximum capital gains tax rate from 20 to 28 percent. The
TRA also had the effect of lowering the maximum marginal tax rate on
dividends to 38.5 percent. These changes became effective January 1,
1987. (1)
However, it is important to note, as Miller (1986) points out, that
capital gains can be deferred indefinitely. Income does not have to be
realized until the sale of the asset. Taxes on capital gains can also be
offset by capital losses, reducing or possibly eliminating tax
liabilities. Dividend income, on the other hand, is treated as ordinary
income. Although capital gains and dividend income still differed due to
the ability to defer capital gains and also offset capital gains with
capital losses, the relative relationship between the two forms of
income changed with the passage of the 1986 TRA. (2) A consequence of
this change should have been a reallocation of investor preference for
dividend income versus capital gains.
An additional change made by TRA was to repeal the investment tax
credit (ITC). Eliminating the ITC brought the potential for a decrease
in new investment. Without the ITC, potential investment projects would
be required to generate higher cash flows before being considered
feasible. As a result firms would have the ability to increase dividend
payout by utilizing funds formerly designated for investment. Managers
might recognize their decreased investment opportunities and pay out
earnings in the form of dividends instead of retaining them for
investment.
This line of reasoning delineates the two following reasons to
expect a significant increase in dividend payout ratios subsequent to
passage of the 1986 TRA: (1) changes in marginal tax rates, and (2) the
elimination of the ITC.
The arguments presented above suggest an expected increase in
dividend payout ratios following the passage of the 1986 TRA. The first
argument addresses investor demand for higher dividends. The passage of
the 1986 TRA could have had the effect of stimulating investor demand
for higher dividends. Subsequent market pressures brought about by this
increased demand should have forced firms to increase dividend payout
ratios.
Opposing theories suggest that dividend payout ratios would remain
the same, decrease, or increase insignificantly in response to the 1986
TRA. Miller and Scholes' (1978) classic study maintains taxes are
irrelevant in determining dividend policy because various legal
provisions exist that provide vehicles to avoid taxation on dividend
income.
An alternative viewpoint relating to elimination of the ITC
suggests that managers lower their dividend payout to provide additional
funds for investment. Corporations might reduce dividend payouts,
retaining a higher percentage of earnings to maintain current levels of
investment, due to this change in tax laws. Cash flow has a strong
positive influence on investment spending as documented by Vogt (1994)
and Whited (1992).
The previous paragraphs delineate the following two reasons not to
expect increases in dividend payout policy subsequent to the passage of
the 1986 TRA: (1) the existence of tax avoidance vehicles, and (2) the
elimination of the ITC.
Several studies attempted to address the question of whether firms
adjusted dividend payout ratios subsequent to the passage of the 1986
TRA. Ben-Horim, Hochman, and Palmon (1987) and Abrutyn and Turner (1990)
both focused on anticipated firm dividend policy response to the passage
of the 1986 TRA. Other studies such as Bolster and Janjigian (1991),
Means, Charoenwong, and Kang (1992), and Papaioannou and Savarese (1994)
empirically tested for change in dividend payouts subsequent to passage
of the 1986 TRA and found conflicting results.
A firm's choice of dividend policy is important if it affects
shareholder wealth. Most studies concentrate on the shareholder wealth
effects of tax law changes. A question remains as to whether firm
management believed the changes caused by the 1986 TRA affected
shareholder wealth and reacted to the 1986 TRA by changing dividend
policy. This study focuses on whether management altered dividend policy
as a result of the 1986 TRA. The choice of methodology allows for the
possibility of these changes being spread over a several year period.
This paper is organized in the following manner. Sections two and
three contain a review of the relevant literature. Section four includes
a discussion of the data and methodology. Section five contains a
presentation of the results, and the final section contains the
conclusions.
LITERATURE REVIEW ON DIVIDENDS AND TAXES
Miller and Modigliani's (1961) proof of dividend irrelevance in the presence of perfect capital markets kindled a debate that
continues today. If dividends have no impact on firm value, then the
dividend decision is moot. If, however, dividends affect firm value,
then management can establish an optimal payout policy. Much of the
research, therefore, has focused on the question of dividend relevance
in the presence of market imperfections such as taxes. Walter (1963)
maintains that dividends matter because of the differential tax
treatment of income. Elton and Gruber (1970), Pettit (1977), and Barclay
(1987) all support the existence of tax clienteles.
Farrar and Selwyn (1967), Brennan (1970), Modigliani (1982), and
Poterba and Summers (1984) maintain that payment of cash dividends
should reduce firm value because of the tax disadvantage stockholders
face when receiving dividends. Litzenberger and Ramaswamy (1979 and
1980) concluded that investors demand higher returns on dividend paying
stocks to compensate for holding a tax disadvantaged stream of cash
flows. Litzenberger and Ramaswamy (1982) found a positive relationship
between stock returns and dividend yields, but concluded that it is
indeterminate whether these results are attributable to taxes or some
omitted variable. In contrast, Chen, Grundy, and Stambaugh (1990) found
no tax penalty on cash dividends.
Other researchers such as Miller and Scholes (1978), Black and
Scholes (1974), and Miller (1986) have contended that dividends are
irrelevant because certain provisions in the U.S. tax code allow
sheltering dividend income. DeAngelo and Masulis (1980) maintain that no
dividends should be demanded or paid without the existence of these tax
shelters. However, Feenberg (1981) and Feldstein and Green (1983)
indicated that few people have the ability to shelter dividends, and
Chaplinsky and Seyhun (1990) noted that many investors do not use the
shelters that are available.
Long (1978), Poterba (1986), and Sterk and Vandenberg (1990) found
modest support for a preference for cash dividends over capital gains
consistent with Gordon's (1959) "bird-in-hand" theory.
Most research contends that this "preference" results from the
signaling value of dividends especially in relation to changes in cash
flows [see Bhattacharya (1979) and Miller and Scholes (1982)]. Many
studies, such as Kalay (1982), Lakonishok and Vermaelen (1983 and 1986),
and Michaely (1991), have focused on ex-dividend day stock returns and
credited all or a portion of the price reaction to short-term traders
eliminating profits.
For dividend payout ratios to adjust to the passage of the 1986
TRA, management must treat dividend payouts as an active policy
variable. Support for this argument comes from the findings of Baker and
Farrelly (1988), Farrelly and Baker (1989), Baker, Farrelly, and Edelman
(1985), and Baker (1989). Management appears to favor dividend stability
and gradual changes consistent with Lintner's (1956) partial
adjustment results.
A number of studies approach dividend relevance from the Miller and
Rock (1985) perspective that describes dividends and investment as being
"two sides of the same coin." Masulis and Trueman (1988),
Chang and Rhee (1990), and Jensen, Solberg, and Zorn (1992) all document
a link between the investment and dividend decisions. To date, no
consensus exists regarding the relevance of dividends in the presence of
taxes.
LITERATURE REVIEW ON DIVIDENDS AND THE 1986 TRA
Several studies have found that the passage of TRA affected firms
in some manner. (3) Of particular relevance is a study by Jang (1994)
that uses event study methodology and finds significantly positive
(negative) abnormal returns for high-yield (low-yield) stocks as a
result of TRA's enactment. Several of these studies indicated that
reaction to the 1986 TRA differed by industry.
Some of the relevant research has attempted to address the question
of whether firms adjusted dividend payout ratios subsequent to the
passage of TRA. Ben-Horim, Hochman, and Palmon (1987) analyzed five
major tax groups of security holders and their dividend policy
preferences and concluded that "the reform is likely to induce
firms to raise their dividend payout ratios." However, this finding
focused on the tax reform's likely impact on corporate financial
policy and based results on data from 1986 and earlier.
Abrutyn and Turner (1990), showed that 85 percent of CEOs surveyed
expected no change in the dividend payout ratios as a result of TRA.
Only 11 percent of CEOs indicated their firms would pay a higher
percentage of after-tax profits in the form of dividends. However, the
time frame of the survey, early in 1988, coincided with the first year
that the tax changes were completed. Actual responses could be very
different if investor demand appears to warrant a change in dividend
payout ratios.
Bolster and Janjigian (1991) examined shareholder wealth effects
and dividend policy changes. High dividend yield stocks significantly
outperformed low dividend yield stocks immediately surrounding
TRA's passage. Anticipation of passage seems to have caused much of
the price adjustment to occur prior to formal passage. With respect to
dividends, however, no evidence indicated that dividend payouts
increased. Bolster and Janjigian defined dividend payout ratios as total
dividends divided by total after tax earnings and examined aggregate
dividend payouts, focusing only on the mean and median aggregate
dividend payments for 883 firms. Their findings indicate that dividends
increase monotonically throughout the time period, 1984-1989, with no
significant change after passage. While their findings indicate that
aggregate dividend payments remained constant in 1987, their analysis is
not industry specific. They concluded that the existence of tax
clienteles does not appear to impact significantly corporate dividend
decisions.
In a study of dividend policy, Means, Charoenwong, and Kang (1992)
focused on changes in dividend yield patterns over the period 1984-1988.
Calculation of yearly dividend yield involved summation of monthly
dividend yields divided by summation of monthly total yields, with all
data being collected from the CRSP tapes. Total yields, from the CRSP
tapes, include capital gains yields and dividend yields. The authors
expected TRA to cause increasing dividend yields and decreasing capital
gains yields. They divided the sample of firms into the following four
groups based on percentage of dividend yield: (1) no dividend, (2)
dividend yield less than 3 percent per year, (3) dividend yield between
3 percent and 5 percent, and (4) dividend yield greater than 5 percent.
Their findings indicated that dividend yields had a downward trend over
the period 1984-1986. Following TRA's passage, dividend yields
started trending upward. (4) The authors did not notice any significant
changes between 1987 and 1988 and concluded that firms had fully
adjusted to the tax changes.
More recently, Papaioannou and Savarese (1994) conducted a study of
243 industrial firms and 40 utilities. The authors divided firms into
quintiles according to their average dividend payouts during the
fourteen quarters prior to TRA's passage. Matched pairs t-tests,
conducted on each quintile, indicated that the three quintiles with the
lowest dividend payout ratios increased dividend payouts significantly
following the passage of TRA. The fourth quintile results were
insignificant while the firms with the highest dividend payouts
significantly decreased dividend payout ratios. The conflicting evidence
presented in these sections indicates further research is necessary.
DATA AND METHODOLOGY
The sample used in the current study consists of 470 observations;
one set of pre-1986 and one set of post-1986 observations for 235 firms.
The number of firms with stable betas is 115 while the remaining 120
firms have unstable betas. The sample excludes firms in industries
subject to significant regulation such as banking, insurance, air
transportation, railroad, transportation, electric and gas utilities,
financial services, and telecommunications. The sample also excludes:
(1) foreign firms, (2) firms not paying dividends throughout the entire
period (1982-1992), (3) firms experiencing negative cash flows during
any one year of the study period, and (4) firms in the petroleum
industry. (5) The study includes only firms that have positive earnings
in every year and have data available in Value Line Investment Surveys
during the entire time period of 1982 through 1992.
The previous research related to TRA extends, at best, back to the
third quarter of 1983. The present study extends the analysis to include
additional years of data, specifically 1982 through 1986 and 1988
through 1992. The last major change in the U.S. tax laws, prior to 1986,
became effective in January 1982. At that time the highest marginal tax
rate on dividends dropped from 70 percent to 50 percent. The fact that
1987 was a transition year for changes in the tax laws requires omission
of data from 1987 . Other studies of dividend policy and the 1986 TRA,
including Papaioannou and Savarese (1994), followed this procedure.
To test the impact of TRA on corporate dividend policy, the present
research estimates a modification of Rozeff's (1982) model using
data obtained from Value Line Investment Surveys. This revised model
incorporates variables that allow testing for possible changes in
dividend payout policy subsequent to the passage of the 1986 TRA. The
model also introduces other variables to test the impact of investment
spending and beta stability on dividend payout policy.
Beta measures the sensitivity of returns for securities compared to
general market movements. A stock with a beta of one is expected to
mirror the market. A stock with a beta of greater than one is expected
to have returns that go up or down proportionately more than those of
the market. Alternatively, a stock with a beta of less than one is
expected to have its returns go up or down proportionately less than
those of the market. According to Value Line's glossary, the beta
coefficient is derived from a regression analysis of the relationship
between weekly percentage changes in the price of a stock and weekly
percentage changes in the New York Stock Exchange Index over a period of
five years. In the case of shorter price histories, a smaller time
period is used, but two years is the minimum (Lindahl and Wachowicz,
2001).
One basic premise of this study is that firms not changing dividend
policy in response to the 1986 TRA exhibit significant changes in
representative firm betas. Testing for this change requires regressing a
series of twelve annual betas for each individual firm against time and
dummy variables to detect for structural shifts. Estimation of the
following model permits classification of firms as having either stable
or unstable betas.
[Beta.sub.T] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1]T + [[beta].sub.2]DV
+ [[beta].sub.3]DV*T
where:
[Beta.sub.T] = Individual firm beta in year T. T = years 1-12, 1981
through 1993 with 1987 omitted. DV = dummy variable coded 0 for years
1-6, and 1 for years 7-12.
Detection of either a change in slope ([[beta].sub.3] [not equal
to] 0) or a discontinuity ([[beta].sub.2] [not equal to] 0) classifies a
firm as having an unstable beta and it receives a dummy variable coding
of zero for the STABLE variable in the following model. Stable beta
firms receive a dummy variable coding of one for the variable STABLE.
After classification of firms into stable or unstable categories
this study estimates the following modification of Rozeff's model:
Beta Stability Model
[PAY.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.0] - [[beta].sub.1]INS -
[[beta].sub.2]GROW1 - [[beta].sub.3]GROW2 - [[beta].sub.4]STABLE +
[[beta].sub.5]STOCK - [[beta].sub.6]CSP [+ or -] [[beta].sub.7]DV [+ or
-] [[beta].sub.17]INS*DV [+ or -] [[beta].sub.27][GROW1.sup.*]DV [+ or
-] [[beta].sub.37][GROW2.sup.*]DV [+ or -]
[[beta].sub.47][STABLE.sup.*]DV [+ or -] [[beta].sub.57][STOCK.sup.*]DV
[+ or -] [[beta].sub.67][CSP.sup.*]DV + [[epsilon].sub.i]
where:
[PAY.sub.i] = Average dividend payout ratio of firm i over a five
year period calculated as a percentage of EPS. The two separate five
year periods are 1982 through 1986 and 1988 through 1992.
INS = Percentage of common stock held by insiders at the end of
each five year period, 1982 through 1986 and 1988 through 1992.
GROW1 = Realized five year average growth rate of revenues over
each five year period, 1982 through 1986 and 1988 through 1992.
GROW2 = Forecasted future five year average growth rate of revenues
using Value Line's estimates. Forecast period includes the years
1987 through 1991 for firms in pre-1986 sample and 1993 through 1997 for
firms in post-1986 sample.
STABLE = Dummy variable coded 1 for firms classified as having
stable betas over the period 1981 through 1993 with the year 1987
omitted, and 0 otherwise.
STOCK = Natural logarithm of number of common stockholders at end
of each five year period, 1982 through 1986 and 1988 through 1992.
CSP = The ratio of total capital spending per share over each five
year period (1982 through 1986 and 1988 through 1992) divided by total
cash flow per share over each five year period. (can exceed 1.0)
DV = Dummy variable coded 1 for the years 1988 through 1992, 0 for
the years 1982 through 1986.
[INS.sup.*]DV, [GROW1.sup.*]DV, [GROW2.sup.*]DV, [STABLE.sup.*]DV,
[STOCK.sup.*]DV, and [CSP.sup.*]DV = interaction terms between the terms
defined above and the dummy variable, DV.
[[epsilon].sub.i] = error term distributed as N(0,[[sigma].sup.2]).
Note that the operational signs indicate the hypothesized direction
of impact each variable should have on dividend payout policy. The
following discussion addresses Rozeff's justification for inclusion
of each of the variables.
According to Rozeff (1982), the higher the percentage of stock held
by insiders (INS), the lower the dividend payout ratio. Dividend payment
functions as a bonding cost by decreasing the time and effort expended by outside ownership to monitor the corporation. If insiders hold a
significant portion of the shares, the demand for higher dividend payout
declines. Conversely, if insiders own very little of the firm's
stock, then higher dividend payouts function to lower monitoring costs.
Rozeff also expects the previous five year average growth rate of
revenues (GROW1) to have a negative impact on dividend payout policy.
The rationale of this variable is that the higher the past revenue
growth, the higher the past demand for investment funds to support that
revenue growth. Rozeff considers the forecasted five year revenue growth
(GROW2) to be a proxy for future investment capital needs. The expected
relationship is also negative. The higher the forecasted revenue growth,
the lower the dividend payout ratio, assuming maintenance of a target
capital structure.
Rozeff used beta to proxy a firm's operating and financial
leverage. According to Rozeff (1982), a firm with a higher use of total
leverage will have a higher beta. Therefore, to lower the cost of
external financing, these higher beta firms would choose lower dividend
payout ratios. Dividend payout should then be negatively related to
beta. This paper investigates whether beta stability is impacted by the
dividend decision. A firm not increasing dividend payout ratio should
see a greater instability in firm beta subsequent to TRA's passage.
STABLE is a dummy variable included to address this issue.
Rozeff hypothesizes the dispersion of ownership, as measured by the
total number of stockholders, should also affect dividend payout ratios.
A smaller number of stockholders would be able to monitor the firm much
more easily than a larger number. Therefore, as the number of
stockholders increases, the likelihood of higher dividend payout ratios
also increases. Again, the distribution of dividends functions to reduce
monitoring costs. The natural log of the number of shareholders (STOCK)
corrects for scale effects.
Rozeff (1982) finds all five original variables to be significant
in explaining dividend payout. Later studies by Dempsey and Laber (1992)
and Dempsey, Laber, and Rozeff (1993) replicate and extend Rozeff (1982)
by examining another seven year period. These studies confirm the
stability of Rozeff's original five variable model.
An additional variable suggested by the literature includes some
measure of investment. Rozeff's two revenue variables, past and
future revenue growth, are intended to proxy a firm's investment
requirements, but more recent studies, specifically Dempsey, Laber, and
Rozeff (1993), indicate that other variables may be more suitable for
measuring investment. This study introduces a new variable, capital
spending per share (CSP), as a proxy for investment. CSP's
calculation sums capital spending per share over each five year period
and divides by the sum of cash flows per share over the same five year
period. This ratio represents the percentage of total cash flow required
for investment needs during each five year time period and can exceed
1.0. As the ratio increases, firms might reduce dividend payout and
satisfy investment requirements using internally generated funds first.
The variable CSP should be a more accurate measurement of investment
needs.
The current study includes a dummy variable representing the impact
of the change in tax laws. A dummy variable DV, coded as zero,
represents the time period 1982 through 1986, and coded as one,
represents the second period, 1988 through 1992.
Calculation of Rozeff's original variable of PAY uses a five
year period instead of a seven year period. Data for the variables INS
and STOCK come from the end of the two five year periods, 1986 and 1992.
Selecting the end of the period maintains consistency with all previous
studies employing variations of Rozeff's model. Dempsey and Laber
(1992) use alternative two-year and four-year mean payout definitions
and found the model to be robust over these shorter time horizons.
RESULTS
Table l contains a presentation of the regression results.
Calculation of the Durbin-Watson statistic indicates that serial
correlation is not a problem.
Calculation of the correlation matrix and variance inflation
factors indicates that this model suffers from multicollinearity. The
use of a stepwise regression procedure can correct the problem of
multicollinearity by retaining only one variable from a set of highly
correlated regressors (Wonnacott and Wonnacott, 1979). Shalagan (1991)
followed a similar procedure.
A stepwise regression procedure yields a more parsimonious model
and determines which of the independent variables has the greatest
impact on dividend payout policy. Stepwise regression is a common
procedure in studies when models have large numbers of variables.
Woodside and Trappey (1992), Malone, Fries, and Jones (1993), and
Bagozzi (1978) all used a similar methodology.
Table 2 contains a presentation of the results using the SAS stepwise procedure with an [alpha] = 0.10. All the variables present in
Rozeff's original study have the expected signs. Both models are
overall significant at the .0001 level or better. The Durbin-Watson
statistic indicated no serial correlation. Visual inspection of the
residuals of the reduced model indicated no discernable patterns, but
analysis of residuals consistent with White (1980) and Breusch and Pagan
(1979) indicated heteroskedasticity. Consequently, column four in Table
2 also contains White's (1980) p-values after the correction for
heteroskedasticity.
CONCLUSIONS
The results presented in Table 2 indicate both growth variables are
significant in the overall model. In addition, firms with higher
historical growth rates increased dividend payouts subsequent to
TRA's passage. Possibly firms that had previously retained earnings for growth elected to distribute a higher percentage of earnings in a
more favorable tax environment.
The results support the hypothesis that firms not increasing their
dividend payouts subsequent to the passage of the 1986 TRA consistently
had structurally unstable betas. The firms with structurally stable
betas have significantly higher dividend payout ratios, with a
coefficient of 0.075, than firms with structurally unstable betas.
The results of the study indicate that TRA's passage affected
corporate dividend policy. This study provides additional evidence for
the relevance of dividend policy in changing tax environments. Since
firms alter dividend payout in response to tax changes, managers
potentially should adopt a more active posture regarding dividend
decisions. Assuming changes in dividend payout policy result from
investor demand pressures, firms adjusting more rapidly to changes in
tax treatment of capital gains versus ordinary income might conceivably
benefit from rapid adoption of new policies. Temporary clientele
imbalances might allow first-movers to increase shareholder wealth by
providing a dividend policy more suitable to the new tax environment.
The specifics of whether to increase or decrease dividend payout would
vary with the direction of the tax change, the magnitude of the change
and the growth prospects of the firm.
One of the most interesting findings is that investment (CSP) is
positively related to dividend payout. This result supports the theory
of dividend distributions functioning to reduce agency costs. Firms with
higher levels of investment have higher payout ratios possibly forcing
them into external capital markets more frequently to face more
stringent monitoring pressures.
Possible public policy implications exist regarding the impact of
tax changes on corporate America. These results indicate that lowering
taxes on ordinary income relative to capital gains could change the
aggregate level of dividends, thus affecting the income subjected to
double taxation. It remains to be seen whether overall government
receipts from corporate taxes and taxes on dividends increase as a
result of this change.
REFERENCES
Abrutyn, S., and R.W. Turner (1990). Taxes and Firms' Dividend
Policies: Survey Results. National Tax Journal, 43(4), 491-496.
Bagozzi, R.P. (1978). Salesforce Performance and Satisfaction as a
Function of Individual Difference, Interpersonal, and Situational
Factors. Journal of Marketing Research, 15(4), 517-531.
Baker, K.H. (1989). Why Companies Pay No Dividends. Akron Business
and Economic Review, 20(2), 4861.
Baker, K.H. & G.E. Farrelly (1988). Dividend Achievers: A
Behavioral Perspective. Akron Business and Economic Review, 19(1),
79-92.
Baker, K.H., G.E. Farrelly, & R.B. Edelman (1985). A Survey of
Management Views on Dividend Policy. Financial Management, 14 (3),
78-84.
Barclay, M.J. (1987). Dividends, Taxes, and Common Stock Prices:
The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior of Common Stock Prices Before the Income
Tax. Journal of Financial Economics, 19(1), 31-44.
Ben-Horim, M., S. Hochman, & O. Palmon (1987). The Impact of
the 1986 Tax Reform Act on Corporate Financial Policy. Financial
Management, 16(3), 29-35.
Bhattacharya, S. (1979). Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy,
and "the bird in the hand" Fallacy. The Bell Journal of
Economics, 10(1), 259-270.
Black, F., & M. Scholes (1974). The Effects of Dividend Yield
and Dividend Policy on Common Stock Prices and Returns. Journal of
Financial Economics, 3(1), pp. 1-22.
Bolster, P. J., & V. Janjigian (1991). Dividend Policy and
Valuation Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986. National Tax Journal,
44(4), 511-518.
Brennan, M. J. (1970). Taxes, Market Valuation and Corporate
Financial Policy. National Tax Journal, December 23(4), 417-427.
Breusch, T. & A Pagan (1979). A Simple Test for
Heteroskedasticity and Random Coefficient Variation. Econometrica,
47(5), 1287-1294.
Chaplinsky, S. & H.N. Seyhun (1990). Dividends and Taxes:
Evidence on Tax-Reduction Strategies. The Journal of Business, 63(2),
239-261.
Chang, R.P. & G. Rhee (1990). The Impact of Personal Taxes on
Corporate Dividend Policy and Capital Structure Decisions. Financial
Management, 19(2), 21-31.
Chen, N., B. Grundy, & R.F. Stambaugh (1990). Changing Risk,
Changing Risk Premiums, and Dividend Yield Effects. Journal of Business,
January 63(1), S51-S70.
Cox, R.A.K., R.T. Kleiman, & R.G. Stout (1994). Tax Policy and
Shareholder Wealth: Some Evidence from the Tax Reform Act of 1986. The
Financial Review, 29(2), 249-273.
DeAngelo, H. & R.W. Masulis (1980). Leverage and Dividend
Irrelevancy Under Corporate and Personal Taxation. The Journal of
Finance, 35(2), 453-467.
Dempsey, S.J., & G. Laber (1992). Effects of Agency and
Transaction Costs on Dividend Payout Ratios: Further Evidence of the
Agency-Transaction Cost Hypothesis. The Journal of Financial Research,
15(4), 317-321.
Dempsey, S., G. Laber, & M. Rozeff (1993). Dividend Policies in
Practice: Is There an Industry Effect? Quarterly Journal of Business and
Economics, 32(4), 3-13.
Elton, E.J., & M.J. Gruber (1970). Marginal Stockholder Tax
Rates and the Clientele Effect. The Review of Economics and Statistics,
52(1), 68-74.
Farrar, D.E., & L.L. Selwyn (1967). Taxes, Corporate Financial
Policy and Return to Investors. National Tax Journal, December 20(4),
445-454.
Farrelly, G.E., & K.H. Baker (1989). Corporate Dividends: Views
of Institutional Investors. Akron Business and Economic Review, 20(2),
89-100.
Feenberg, D., (1981). Does the Investment Interest Limitation
Explain the Existence of Dividends? Journal of Financial Economics,
9(3), 265-269.
Feldstein, M., & J. Green (1983). Why Do Companies Pay
Dividends? The American Economic Review, 73(1), 17-30. Gordon, M. J.
(1959). Dividends, Earnings, and Stock Prices. The Review of Economics
and Statistics, 41(2), 99-105.
Graddy, D.B., G. Homaifar, & K.W. Hollman (1992). Tax
Reform's Impact on Insurance Industry Stock Returns. Journal of
Risk and Insurance, 59(2), 284-290.
Grammatikos, T. & P. Yourougou (1990). Market Expectations of
the Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 on Banking Organizations.
Journal of Banking and Finance, 14(6), 1171-1187.
Han, K.C. (1994). The Effect of the 1986 Tax Reform Act on
Ex-Dividend Day Return Behavior. The Journal of Financial Research,
17(2), 175-186.
Hearth, D. & J.N. Rimbey (1993) The Dividend-Clientele
Controversy and the Tax Reform Act of 1986. Quarterly Journal of
Business and Economics, 32(1), 68-81.
Jang, H.J.(1994). The Market Reaction to the 1986 Tax Reform
Overhaul: A Study of the Capital Gain Tax Change. Journal of Business
Finance and Accounting, 22(6), 1179-1193.
Kalay, A. (1982). The Ex-Dividend Day Behavior of Stock Prices: A
Re-Examination of the Clientele Effect. The Journal of Finance, 37(4),
1059-1070.
Lakonishok, J. & T. Vermaelen (1983). Tax Reform and
Ex-Dividend Day Behavior. The Journal of Finance, September 1983, 38(4),
1157-1179.
Lakonishok, J. & T. Vermaelen (1986). Tax-Induced Trading
Around Ex-Dividend Days. Journal of Financial Economics, July, 16(3),
287-319.
Lindahl, M. & J. Wachowicz, Jr. (2001). Judging Your
Portfolio's Return, Given Its Risk. Review of Business, 22 (1-2),
59-61.
Lintner, J. (1956). Distribution of Incomes of Corporations Among
Dividends, Retained Earnings, and Taxes. American Economic Review,
46(2), 97-113.
Litzenberger, R.H., & K. Ramaswamy (1979). The Effect of
Personal Taxes and Dividends on Capital Asset Prices. Journal of
Financial Economics, 7(2) 163-195.
Litzenberger, R.H., & K. Ramaswamy (1980). Dividends, Short
Selling Restrictions, Tax-Induced Investor Clienteles and Market
Equilibrium. The Journal of Finance, 35(2), 469-485.
Litzenberger, R.H., & K. Ramaswamy (1982). The Effects of
Dividends on Common Stock Prices; Tax Effects or Information Effects?
The Journal of Finance, 37(2), 429-443.
Long, J.B. (1978). The Market Valuation of Cash Dividends, A Case
to Consider. Journal of Financial Economics, 6(2,3) 235-264.
Malone, D., C. Fries, & T. Jones (1993). An Empirical
Investigation of the Extent of Corporate Financial Disclosure in the Oil
and Gas Industry. Journal of Accounting, Auditing, and Finance, 8(3),
249-273.
Masulis, R.W., & B. Trueman (1988). Corporate Investment and
Dividend Decisions under Differential Personal Taxation. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 23(4), 369-385.
Means, D.B. Jr., C. Charoenwong, & Y. Kang (1992). Changing
Dividend Policies Caused by the Tax Reform Act of 1986: An Empirical
Analysis. Journal of Economics and Finance, 16(3), 153-160.
Michaely, R. (1991). Ex-Dividend Day Stock Price Behavior: The Case
of the 1986 Tax Reform Act. The Journal of Finance, 46(3), 845-859.
Miller, M.H. & R.J. Shiller (1986). Behavioral Rationality in
Finance: The Case of Dividends. The Journal of Business, 59(4),
S451-S468.
Miller, M.H. & F. Modigliani (1961). Dividend Policy, Growth,
and the Valuation of Shares. The Journal of Business, 34(4), 1961,
411-433.
Miller, M.H., & K. Rock (1985). Dividend Policy under
Asymmetric Information. The Journal of Finance, 40(4), 10311051.
Miller, M.H., & M.S. Scholes (1978). Dividends and Taxes.
Journal of Financial Economics, 6(4), 333364.
Miller, M.H., & M.S. Scholes (1982). Dividends and Taxes: Some
Empirical Evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 90(6), 1118-1141.
Modigliani, F. (1982). Debt, Dividend Policy, Taxes, Inflation and
Market Valuation. The Journal of Finance, 37(2), 255- 273.
Papaioannou, G. J., & C.M. Savarese (1994). Corporate Dividend
Policy Response to the Tax Reform Act of 1986. Financial Management,
23(1), 56-63.
Pettit, R.R. (1977). Taxes, Transaction Costs and the Clientele
Effect of Dividends. Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 419-436.
Poterba, J.M. (1986). The Market Valuation of Cash Dividends: The
Citizens Utilities Case Reconsidered. Journal of Financial Economics,
15(3), 395-405.
Poterba, J.M., & L.H. Summers (1984). New Evidence That Taxes
Affect the Valuation of Dividends. The Journal of Finance, 39(5),
1397-1415.
Robin, A.J. (1991). The Impact of the 1986 Tax Reform Act on
Ex-Dividend Day Returns. Financial Management, 20(1), 60-70.
Rozeff, M.S. (1982). Growth, Beta, and Agency Costs as Determinants
of Dividend Payout Ratios. The Journal of Financial Research, 5(3),
249-259.
Shalagan, S. (1991). In the Eye of the Beholder: Commercial Bank
Priorities for Maximizing Shareholder Value. Journal of Business and
Economic Studies, 1(1), 33-44.
Siddiqi, M.A. (1995). An Indirect Test For Dividend Relevance. The
Journal of Financial Research, 18(1), 89-101.
Skinner, D.L. (1993). Twenty-Five Years of Tax Law Changes and
Investor Response. The Journal of Financial Research, 18(1), 61-70.
Sterk, W.E. & P.A. Vandenberg (1990). The Market Valuation of
Cash Dividends and the Tax Differential Theory of Dividend Policy: A
Case Revisited. The Financial Review, 25(3), 441-455.
Value Line Investment Surveys, vols. 1-39, 1982-1992.
Vogt, S.C. (1994). The Cash Flow/Investment Relationship: Evidence
from U.S. Manufacturing Firms. Financial Management, 23(2), 3-20.
Walter, J.E. (1963). Dividend Policy: Its Influence on the Value of
the Enterprise. The Journal of Finance, 18, 280-291.
White, H. (1980). A Heteroskedasticity Consistent Covariance
Matrix. Econometrica, 48(4), 817-838.
Whited, T. (1992). Debt, Liquidity Constraints, and Corporate
Investment: Evidence from Panel Data. Journal of Finance, 47(4),
1425-1460.
Wonnacott, R.J. & T.H. Wonnacott (1979). Econometrics. John
Wiley & Sons.
Woodside, A.G.& R.J. Trappey, III (1992). Finding Out Why
Customers Shop Your Store and Buy Your Brand: Automatic Cognitive
Processing Models of Primary Choice. Journal of Advertising Research,
32(6), 59-78.
ENDNOTES
(1) The Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 reduced the capital gains tax
rates that had been in place since the passage of 1986 Tax Reform Act.
When fully phased in, most capital gains on assets held more than five
years will be taxed at a maximum rate of 18 percent. Assets held between
one and five years will be taxed at a maximum rate of 20 percent.
(2) Certain investors already prefer dividend income in spite of
the preferential tax treatment afforded capital gains.
(3) Robin (1991), Cox, Kleiman, and Stout (1994), Graddy, Homaifar,
and Hollman (1992), Han (1994), and Siddiqi (1995) all find market
reactions subsequent to the passage of TRA. In contrast, Michaely
(1991), Hearth and Rimbey (1993), Skinner (1993), and Grammatikos and
Yourougou (1990) find no reaction to TRA's passage.
(4) The authors did not indicate why dividend yields trended
upward. A decrease in price while maintaining a stable dividend could
yield the same upward trend.
(5) Firms in the petroleum industry are subject to different
accounting practices which makes EPS not strictly comparable to other
industries.
K. Michael Casey, Henderson State University
John B. Duncan, The University of Louisiana at Monroe
Michael P. Watters, Henderson State University
TABLE 1: Regression Results for EPS Dividend Payout on Rozeff's
Original Variables, Capital Spending and Beta Stability
Prob. >
Variable Parameter Estimate [absolute value of T]
INTERCEPT 0.486038 0.0171
INS -0.000393 0.8058
GROW1 -0.017087 0.0002
GROW2 -0.013358 0.0272
STOCK 0.011582 0.5760
CSP 0.131384 0.0978
STABLE 0.089331 0.0527
DV 0.349929 0.2099
[INS.sup.*] DV -0.000293 0.8938
[GROW1.sup.*] DV -0.014435 0.0258
[GROW2.sup.*] DV -0.000511 0.9603
[STOCK.sup.*] DV -0.011458 0.6797
[CSP.sup.*] DV -0.020087 0.8509
[STABLE.sup.*] DV -0.034759 0.5934
[R.sup.2] = 0.2247
F Value = 10.163 *
Adjusted [R.sup.2] = 0.2026
N = 470
* = significant at the 0.0001 level
TABLE 2
Stepwise Regression Results for EPS Dividend Payout on Rozeff's
Original Variables, Capital Spending and Beta Stability
Parameter Prob. > White's Prob. >
Variable Estimate [absolute value of T] [absolute value of T]
INTERCEPT 0.603403 0.000100 0.000100
GROW1 -0.017455 0.000100 0.000100
GROW2 -0.013784 0.004500 0.007800
CSP 0.129039 0.011900 0.002600
STABLE 0.075115 0.011900 0.016200
DV 0.204855 0.000300 0.008900
[GROW1.sup.*]
DV 0.014135 0.013400 0.033700
[R.sup.2] = 0.2225
Adjusted [R.sup.2] = 0.2124
F Value = 22.080 *
N = 470
Durbin-Watson = 1.801
* significant at the 0.0001 level