Models for market structure.
Bulearca, Marius ; Serban, Claudia Elena ; Muscalu, Mihai-Sabin 等
Abstract: Market imperfections are usually called "best
friends of conservatism in research", and that is why we decided to
analyze the existence of industrial monopolies. We proved how their
existence is affecting depletion rates and thus the cost/price ratio or
fossil fuels and mining products. Key words: natural resources, mining
industry, profit trend, cartel, market, perfect competition
1. INTRODUCTION
Economic analysis of extractive industry is fundamentally different
from the analysis of agriculture, manufacturing and services. The main
reason is that the mineral resources are exhaustible resources. In other
words, in mining industry an initial stock of reserves will exhaust in
time. Consequently, if we start from the premise that the owner of a
resource, like any other owner, is seeking for maximum gain, we must
take into consider multiple factors, unique in the mining industry.
Until now, economic analysis in general, and especially that
related to the natural resources market, has been characterized by the
concept of natural resource scarcity, much of the methodological
concepts being closely related to resources allocation problems at micro
and macro-economic level.
Based on these considerations, it should be noted that in the
economic literature, the idea of resource reserves depletion has been
often accredited to the extent of economic and demographic development.
One of the objectives of this research is to examine the optimal
level of extraction of non-renewable mineral resources in terms of
government which wants to maximize social welfare by exploiting these
resources.
2. MARKET STRUCTURE AND NATURAL RESOURCES EXPLOITATION
Often it had been discussed the fact that market imperfections,
especially if highly monopoly, are "best friends of
conservatism", says Hotelling (1931). Should be emphasized that
monopoly can exist in mining industry as in manufacturing industry,
affecting depletion rates and thus the cost/price of fossil fuels and
mining products.
In this sense, arises the question in what ways a monopolistic
behavior may differ from a perfectly competitive behavior in the mining
industry. It should be recalled again that the objective of any business
is the same, that is extraction of resources in a manner which to
maximize the present value of profits over time. When this happens, the
market rate of return will be one of the determinants of firms both
monopolistic, and perfectly competitive firms. This is inherent in the
economic fundamental principle (Hartwick & Olewiler, 1986).
First, suppose that a monopolist owner is the sole owner of a set
stock that he can extract at zero cost. Market demand curve, the
monopolist owner must cope with, remains stationary in time. His problem
is to find an extraction scheme to bring maximum profits discounted over
time until all original stock (inventory) is depleted over time. Its
marginally income "MR" increase from two consecutive moments
of time will be:
MR(t + 1) - MR(t)/MR(t) = r (1)
that is the percentage change in marginal revenue equals the time
rate of profit, "r", meaning that in every moment of time
monopolist owners' marginal revenue amounts to the market rate of
return.
In Fig. 1 is represented the situation in which production in each
moment of time met conditions in equation (1). In Fig. 1(a), an output
level at time t, "[Q.sub.t]", corresponds to the price level,
"[P.sub.t]". In the next period, t+l, price, and thus marginal
revenue, must increase linearly with the market rate of profit, which
may be obtained only by reducing production, namely [Q.sub.t+1] <
[Q.sub.t].
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
When marginal revenue is discounted to market rate of profit, it is
the same in different time periods (Kula, 1994). Last unit of extracted
production will produce the highest undiscounted marginal income, which
corresponds to the price limit "p*".
As the monopolist owner shifts upward the marginal revenue curve,
traders that are competing on mining markets, very many on the market,
will shift upward the demand curve every moment of time. In both market
structures, the economic fundamental principle must meet the same profit
rate.
Since the marginal revenue curve is steeper than the demand curve,
that is slope MR > slope D, then the monopolist owner will have to
decrease production less than competing firms, each moment of time.
Thus, the monopolist owner will use its reserves more slowly than firms
existing on the competitive market.
Because the initial production of the monopolist owner is lower
than those in competition, under the condition of two different price
trends in both markets, then its initially price must be higher. Because
marginal revenue is less than the price (see Fig. 2), monopolist price
trend will be flatter than the competitive price, meaning that the price
is growing more slowly.
In the monopolistic situation, the initial prices are higher, but
their growth rate is lower. Assuming there is no change in demand for
natural resources, then, in the monopolistic situation the reserve
stocks will last for a longer time period compared to competition in the
extractive industry (Samuelson & Nordhaus, 1992).
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
It was stressed that when depletion time (T) is long, then many
changes can occur related to natural resource extraction technology and
their use, which will affect the demand curve. It can be argued that as
long as the competitive market prices are growing fast, this situation
will encourage the users of these resources to seek new sources of
alternative raw materials (Barnett, 1979).
In a monopolistic situation, however, demand for natural resources,
raw materials for manufacturing industry cannot be avoided as long as
their users are getting familiar to the slow growth of resource prices
and thus will maintain their constant demand. With a constant demand,
the ultimate depletion will take place in the competitive market, and if
users gradually pass to substitutes, it is possible some of the stock of
reserves to remain in deposits (Wonnacott & Wonnacott, 1986).
It is also inherent in our previous assertion that monopoly rent,
which includes both the resource rent and excess profits, exceeds the
resource rent obtained in the competitive market. It is therefore
understandable why independent owners of natural resources are willing
to form a cartel where they believe that may manifest as a collective
monopoly.
Indeed, a cartel is a group of independent owners who are trying,
by common understanding, to act as a firm. In a cartel case, each owner
agrees to produce less than they would produce under competitive market
conditions. The expected effect of the cartel is to increase the market
price so that producers can earn excess profits.
In Fig. 3 are shown the production levels both in competitive
market and in terms of a cartel. To simplify the calculations let's
assume that we analyze the case of a zero rate of profit (Pearce, 1983).
Fig. 3(a) provides competitive price "0[P.sub.p]" and
production competition "0[Q.sub.p]" by intersecting supply and
demand curve. A competitive market firm believes the market price as
given and produce at a level where price equals marginal cost, which
then becomes the marginal revenue and schedules its own production at
this level. Its market segment covers only part of its total sales.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Suppose now that to achieve excess profits all competing firms
would join together to form a cartel. In this case, their production
"0Q" would fall so that market prices are rising to
"0[P.sub.c]". Note that the ability to offer is not
diminishing as production level reduces artificially. To each cartel
firm is given such a share so that the reduced rate of production on the
market can be maintained. Individual company depicted in Fig. 3(b) is
told to reduce production at "0[Q.sub.c]" (Home, 1979).
In this new situation created there is a great temptation "to
deceive". Individual company, by reducing its price just a little
(slightly below the cartel price), may sell more, "0[Q.sub.d]"
at the same expenses as other members. For production
"0[Q.sub.d]", the firm's marginal cost equals the new
marginal revenue, "MR'", and shaded area shows
over-excess profit that can be achieved "through cheating" the
cartel.
3. RESULTS
To conclude this analysis, we must point out that a cartel may
increase prices only by reducing its production. However, at higher
prices, members forming a cartel are tempted to produce even more than
when the competitive market equilibrium. As the cartel situation has
more success, the temptation "to deceive" will tend to grow.
Therefore in order to be successful a cartel requires some measures
of domestic policy group to ensure that each member takes care of its
own control share. In regards to natural resources depletion, for a
cartel, the amount extracted at all points in time will be less than in
the competitive situation, otherwise reserve stocks will get blocked in
deposits.
Hence, the researches undertook in this paper stress out that
natural resource market involves a comprehensive analysis according to several criteria: requirements of economic growth, future potential of
environmental factors, scientific and technological progress and
demographic change; these factors affect both demand and supply rate, as
well as substitution rates, specific consumption rate reduction, etc.
The economic literature contains a comprehensive analysis of most
of the aforementioned issues, which is why in this paper we shall dwell
only on the following matters: limited character and scarcity of natural
resources (supply) in relation to the development of demand; mechanisms
and economic laws that describe the supply-demand ratio of natural
resources determined by economic and social factors.
4. REFERENCES
Barnett, H. (1979). Scarcity and growth revisited, In: Scarcity and
Growth Reconsidered (editor: V. K. Smith), Johns Hopkins University Press, ISBN 0801862310, Baltimore.
Hartwick, J.M. & Olewiler, N.D. (1986). The Economics of
Natural Resource Use, Harper & Row, ISBN 978-960-474-253-0, New York
Home, C.N. (1979). Natural Resources Economics, Issues, Analysis
and Policy, Wiley, ISBN 978-0-470-72395-1, New York.
Hotelling, H. (1931). The Economics of Exhaustible Resources, In:
Journal of Political Economy 39, ISBN 9780192820808, London
Kula, E. (1994). Economies of Natural Resources, the Environment
and Policies, Second Edition, Chapman and Hall, ISBN 978-960-474-253-0,
London
Pearce, D.W. (1983). Cost-benefit Analysis, Second Edition,
MacMillan, ISBN 0333120639, London
Samuelson, P.A. & Nordhaus, W.D. (1992). Economics, 14-th
Edition, McGraw Hill Book Co., ISBN 0-07-1180648, New York
Wannacott, P. & Wannacott, R. (1986). Economics, Third Edition,
McGraw Hill Co., ISBN 0393970833, New York