Conflict and strategy models in automotive competing markets.
Izvercianu, Monica ; Vartolomei, Mihaela ; Staicu, Florentiu 等
1. INTRODUCTION
The bargain process supposes both the cooperation and the conflict
elements. Each of the participants on automotive market should have well
determined target (Izvercian, 2002) with respecting the rules known by
partners, even if there are contradictory interests for them. These
interactions are so called conflict situations and they're very
real inside automotive industry. Understanding the automotive industry
structure is essential to the strategists in the field, but
understanding the competitive forces and underlying causes reveals the
industry profitability and provides a framework for influencing
competition and profitability (Vartolomei-M, 2009). The strongest
competitive forces (that are not always obviously) determine the
profitability of industry and become the most important thing in order
to formulate the strategy. In the following we'll identify these
five forces for a studied plant. Also, other automotive market strategy
we study is Blue Ocean Strategy. Its principle is to be focused on the
big picture not on the numbers. It is about growing demand and breaking
away from the competition, a new and avant-garde strategy. New
strategies are necessary for company strategic changes (Imbrescu, 2005).
2. GAME AND NEGOTIATION THEORY AS ELEMENTS OF CONFLICT THEORY
APPLIED ON AUTOMOTIVE MARKET
This pat we offer analyses regarding conflict subjective elements
on automotive industry: dislike feeling (the availability to hurt the
other side), rivalry feelings (if resources are very limited, one of the
parts can enhance its position by aggression; while the dislike produces
a strong emotional charging conflict, rivalry leads to an essential
cooling), super-confidence (the bigger the self confidence is, the less
the possibilities for disgraced situations is), incapacity to impose the
own accords
Figure 1 illustrates confidence and conflict situation on
automotive industry for studied plant.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[I.sub.1] and [I.sub.2] represents inputs (position, territory,
power or ability to gain goods consumption) of first player and
respectively second player (everyone looks the other's input as bad
omen--concavity of II' curve). II' represents the social
opportunity curve (the combinations of inputs obtained from the two
players decisions), [I.sup.0.sub.1] and [I.sup.0.sub.2] represents the
expectations or availabilities considered enough undesired or being
acceptable in some situations by first, respectively, second player. The
first player considers that in case of a conflict, the benefit will be
somewhere to [I.sup.0.sub.1] level; the second player anticipates the
[I.sup.0.sub.2] point. There is also a mutual advantages area:
MSS', where both sides can gain using peaceful methods and
attitudes, to which we can arise only by a compromise agreement and the
efficient solution is along the SS' arc, on the opportunity curve
II'. There is no possibility to reach to a compromise in figure 2
because everyone is too confident in his success in case of a
confrontation, there is no mutual advantage zone, so no compromise
possible and a direct or indirect fight is unavoidable since the both
are expecting to obtain the best results better by fighting rather than
argument adjustment.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
3. PORTER MODEL APPLIED TO AUTOMOTIVE INDUSTRY
3.1 Threat of New Entrants
It appears due to the new capacity and desire to obtain market
share and put pressure on prices, costs and rate of investment, limiting
the potential industry profit. This threat is high for automotive
industry, so, incumbent plant must hold down the prices or boosts the
investments in order to deter the newcomers. This threat depends on the
height of entry obstacles and on the reaction of the incumbent. If entry
obstacles are low and are expected little retaliations from inside, the
threat is high and industry profitability is moderated. The supposed
reaction of incumbents will have a great influence on likely
newcomers' decision to come in or stay out of industry.
3.2 Bargaining Power of Suppliers
It captures more of the value for themselves by higher prices,
limited quality or services. A suppliers group is powerful if: it is
more concentrated than the industry it sells to; it does not depend
heavily on the industry for its revenues; industry participants face
switching costs in changing suppliers; suppliers offer differentiated
products; there's no substitute for what the supplier group
provides; the supplier group can credibly threaten to integrate forward
into the industry.
3.3 Bargaining Power of Buyers
It can capture more value by forcing down prices, demanding better
quality or more service and generally playing industry participants off
against one another, influencing industry profitability. A customer
group has negotiating leverage if there are few buyers, or each one
purchases in volumes that are large relative to the size of single
vendor.
3.4 Threat of substitutes
Substitute performs the same or similar function as industry's
product. When the threat of substitute is high, the profitability and
growth potential suffer. This threat is high if: it offers an attractive
price-performance for automotive products; the buyer's cost of
switching to the substitute is low. Technological changes or competitive
discontinuities in some business can have major impacts on industry
profitability. Improvement in advanced materials, for instance, allowed
them to substitute steel in many automotive components.
3.5 Rivalry among competitors
It takes familiar forms: price discounting, new product
introduction, advertising campaigns, and service improvements. As Porter
said (Porter, 2008), this strength reflects the intensity of competition
but also the basis of competition. Profitability is influenced by
dimensions on which competition takes place, if rivals converge to
compete on the same dimensions. Furthermore, rivalry is especially
destructive to profitability if it gravitates solely to price because
price competition transfers profits directly from an industry to its
customers.
4. BLUE OCEAN STRATEGY VERSUS RED OCEAN STRATEGY ANALYSES IN
AUTOMOTIVE INDUSTRY
The Blue Ocean Strategy is created by Chan Kim W. and Mauborgne
Renee and wants to challenge companies to break out of the red ocean of
bloody competition by creating uncontested market space that makes the
competition irrelevant. Blue Ocean strategy is about growing demand and
breaking away from the competition. The comparison between aed Ocean and
Blue Ocean Strategy is shown in table 1. aed Ocean is represented by
existed industry (known market space) and Blue Ocean is represented by
the industries that does not exist (unknown market). The companies from
aed Ocean followed a conventional approach, racing to beat the
competition by building a defensible position within the existing
industry order. Contrarily, the creators of blue oceans didn't use
the competition as their benchmark, but they follow a different
strategic logic so called "value innovation" (Chan Kim, W.
& Mauborgne, R. 2005), the cornerstone of Blue Ocean Strategy.
5. CONCLUSION
The strength of the five competitive forces affects prices, costs,
and investment required to compete. The forces are directly tied to
income statements and balance sheets of automotive industry plants. This
paper helps to understand industry structure. It guides manager toward
good possibilities for strategic action, such as: positioning the
company to better cope with competitive forces; anticipating and
exploiting shifts in the forces; and defining and shaping the balance of
forces to create a new industry structure that is more favourable for
the company. The strategic profile with high blue ocean potential has
three complementary qualities: focus, divergence, and a compelling
tagline. In conclusion companies should build their Blue Ocean Strategy
in the sequence of customer utility, price, cost, and adoption. These
criteria form an integral whole in order to ensure trade success.
6. REFERENCES
Chan Kim, W., Mauborgne, R. (2005): Blue Ocean Strategy How to
Create Uncontested Market Space and Make the Competition Irrelevant,
Harvard Business School Press, Boston, Massachusetts, ISBN 1-59139-619-0
Imbrescu, M.C. (2005). Reorganization and dissolution of companies,
Mirton Publisher, ISBN 973-661-770-X, Timisoara
Izvercian, M. (2002). "Marketing Elements"; Solness
Publisher, ISBN 973-8472-19-9, Timisoara
Porter, M. (2008). Leadership and Strategy. The Five Competitive
Forces That Shape Strategy, Harvard Business Review, pg. 78-93, London
Vartolomei-M, M. (2009). Contribution to the management of change
and energy in military industry in the frame of suprastate play,
Politehnica Publisher, ISBN 978-973-625803-9, Timisoara
Tab. 1. RO Strategy vs. BO Strategy for industry
Read Ocean Strategy Blue Ocean Strategy
Compete in existing market Create uncontested market
space space
Beat the competition Make the competition
irrelevant
Exploit existing demand Create and capture new
demand
Make the value-cost Break the value-cost
trade-off trade-off
Strategic choice of Differentiating and low cost
differentiation or low cost