The fraction of income saved by the consumers: an mathematical "output" of a utility function.
Predescu, Iuliana ; Toader, Stela ; Predescu, Antoniu 等
1. INTRODUCTION
In microeconomics, it is of great importance to turn into numbers
and formulae the (economic) behavior of the average consumer--in our
paper, of the producer, in its quality as a taxpayer (Maddala &
Miller, 1989). Our starting point is based on a rather simple
observation, that is the fact one will save some of his incomes if the
remainder of his incomes are sufficient for consumption, and, as a
result of his own thinking about the utility of saving (Romer, 1996).
This research will lead to a more structured and analytic vision of the
relation between the saving phenomenon and utility.
2. QUANTIFYING THE SAVING RATE THROUGH THE UTILITY OF CONSUMPTION
Every individual is presumed to have some particular desires of his
own concerning what he wants; in order to measure the amplitude of the
desires of the tax payer, concerning consumption, it is used, especially
in this mathematical model of human economic behavior, the [theta]
factor, factor which has the following properties: the size of this
coefficient diminishes every time the consumers will change his mind
about his consumption desires and decisions, and will decrease with an
increment which is as large as the number of those changes in
'consumption strategy'. This [theta] factor, called the factor
of constant relative risk aversion is lower as the individual is more
willing to decide, more frequently, how much that person consumes in a
period of their life and how much in another period (Romer, 1996).
In the mathematical modeling of this psycho-socioeconomic
mechanism, the factor of relative risk aversion is constant, and
therefore, the utility function which uses this factor is called
constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility.
In principle, the utility function with constant relative risk
aversion has the following form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (1)
where C is the input.
The utility function counts on constant relative risk aversion,
using two different inputs, for two periods:
[U.sub.t] [C.sup.1-[theta].sub.1t] / 1 - [theta] + 1 / 1+ [rho] x
[C.sup.1-[theta].sub.2t+1] / 1 - [theta], where [rho] > -1. (2)
[rho] is the discount rate, respectively the rate whose value
determines the position of the individual with respect to the values
granted to present and future input related to the balance position.
3. THE LAGRANGE MULTIPLIER
The multiplier Lagrange ([lambda]) is used to express
mathematically the utility function and with its help we build the
Lagrange of our utility function. We have the function objectively and,
respectively, its related restriction (r = real interest rate):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (3)
Young people share their income from work between the two
"accounts", namely the period between consumption and savings.
The amount of the savings noted with [S.sub.t], noting, on the other
hand, the proportion of income that an individual saves--in the first
period--with s(r), we have:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (4)
Then:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (5)
(1 + p)6 + (1 + rt+1) 6 We say that we have a regulator of the
macroeconomic policy, which is the real interest rate (Schiller, 2003).
It is indeed a regulator, not the only one, but through it, it is no
less important than it is in fact, and--obviously--in particular from
the perspective of balance that any individual achieves (in one way or
another), for themselves and their own efforts, between personal
consumption and savings (hence, investments).
4. MAXIMIZATION OF THE SAVING RATE-THE CASE OF LOGARITHMIC UTILITY
We calculate the condition of order I for the maximization of s(r),
depending on [r.sub.t]--by applying the conditions on the numerator only:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (6)
The value of the numerator--and of s(r)--increases if the value of
6 is higher than 1 and decreases if the value of [theta] is less than 1.
As regards the situation in which [theta] = 1, to observe its influence
on the value of s(r) (i.e., the rate of saving for young individuals),
we analyze the behavior of that economic entity r--the real interest
rate.
An increase in the value of r presents both an income effect and
substitution effect, i.e. the substitution effect is the phenomenon of
increasing savings rate, when the individual wishes a higher consumption
in the second period of their life than the first period (Mishkin,
2004).
The effect of income is characterized by the decrease of the
savings rate--the individual relying on that, whereas the (real)
interest rate has grown, they can consume "nearly" (we say
"nearly", because that level of consumption in the first
period will be equal to the level of consumption in the next period
namely, the concept of the concerned individual; levels will be,
however, of similar size) as much as in the first period of their life
and in the second.
Therefore, when [theta] < 1, the behavior of the individual is
one in which the substitution effect prevails, while, conversely, the
same behavior will be characterized by a predominance of the effect of
income--a situation which, mathematically, is defined as one in which
[theta] > 1. When [theta] = 1, the two effects, the substitution and
income are in balance, more specifically, the saving rate of young
individuals is independent from r. This case is called the logarithmic
utility (Romer, 1996).
This case is one where we have something to say, especially in
regard to taxation (i.e. rate income tax): as in many other studies, we
see that saving is a more or less flexible phenomenon--i.e. the savings
rate is not (very) sensitive to the rate of return on saving. Thus,
fiscal measures to encourage savings through reducing the tax on
interest income will not increase the rate of savings, but will have two
main results, more or less undesirable:
On the one hand, the holders of bank deposits will record higher
revenue--by paying a lower tax on such income.
On the other hand, revenues available to the government are reduced
by reducing the tax rate on income from interest, which may, alone or in
conjunction with others, generate (a) budget deficit (Von Mises, 1996).
What happens, however, where [theta] = 1? Like we said, in this case
savings--even savings rate, i.e. the proportion of (total) saved
income--is practically independent of the real interest rate.
For [theta] = 1, the savings rate is calculated as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (7)
The condition for [rho] is [rho] > -1; which means that, if
[theta] = 1, s([r.sub.t+l]) it cannot have a value higher than the one
it would have if [rho] = -1; therefore,
s([r.sub.t+1]) = 1 / 2 + (-1) = 1 / 2 - 1 = 1/1 = 1. (8)
This means that the entire income would be saved [??] [C.sub.1t] =
0.
If [rho] = 0, the value of the savings rate is
s([r.sub.t+1]) = 1 / 2 + 0 = 1 / 2. (9)
5. CONCLUSIONS
Like any other model, the model we have presented hereby uses
certain simplifications which, as in any effective model, do not impair
the outcome: the fact the saving decisions taken by any individual
consumer (and, of course, tax payer) have a strong connection with his
psychological constitution and social habits.
This demonstration illustrates that when, for an individual, the
consumption of the first period of their life has equal value as
consumption in the second period, the individual will save in the first
period, as we said--half of their income.
The individual considers that, because the (real) interest rate has
increased, they will be able to consume in the second period of their
life "nearly" as much as in the first period of their life
(Lipsey & Chrystal, 1999); this is, considering its beginnings, a
psychological principle, not an economic one, but with firm economic
consequences.
6. REFERENCES
Lipsey, R. G.& Chrystal, K. A. (1999). Economia Pozitiva,
Economica Publishing House, ISBN 973-590-088-2, Bucharest (Romania)
Maddala, G.S.& Miller, E. (1989). Microeconomics: Theory and
Applications, The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., ISBN 0-07-039415-6,
U.S.A.
Mishkin, F.S. (2004). The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial
Markets (7th edition--The Addison-Wesley series in economics), Pearson
Addison-Wesley, ISBN 0-32112235-6, U.S.A.
Romer, D. (1996). Advanced Macroeconomics, The McGraw-Hill
Companies, Inc., ISBN 0-07-053667-8, U.S.A.
Schiller, B.R. (2003). The Economy Today (9th edition), The
McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., INTERNATIONAL EDITION ISBN 0-07-115114-1,
New York
Von Mises, L. (1996), Human Action: A Treatise on Economics (Fourth
revised edition), Fox&Wilkes, ISBN 0-930073-185, San Francisco, CA
(U.S.A.)