The opportunity cost and the law of demand.
Druica, Elena ; Cornescu, Viorel ; Bratu, Anca 等
1. INTRODUCTION
In the field of economics a wide literature exists having
undertaken the law of demand in view of numerous approaches: historical,
psychological, intuitive or profoundly formal (Teira 2006), (Beattie
& LaFrance 2006), (Zhang, 2005); many times our students do not have
access to such articles or they regard them as being too difficult
compared to their own purposes and background. The present article
provides an approach based on Walras' Law, which is in the same
time a rigorous and easy to understand method. As it is finding in any
course note in Economics, Walras' Law states that a consumer always
spends his entire budget, because the individual is tempted rather to
consume more than to consume less when it comes to satisfying his own
needs:
[N.summation over (i=1)] [p.sub.i][x.sub.i](p, [omega]) = [omega]
(1)
It is well known that very early on the hypotesis of Walras'
Law have been discussed and that some specialists found them as being
exaggerating claims and somehow unobservable (Walker, 1984). It is also
true that further work improved the concept of economic rationality as
being the basic of Walras' Law findings (Arrow, 1977) and lead to
some other discussions. Hwever, for our purposes all these
contradictions are not essential in our initiative to get the purpose of
this paper.
In (1), [p.sub.i] represents the price per unit of good i, [omega]
is the consumer's budget, and [x.sub.i] (p, [omega]) is the
quantity of good i purchased upon prices p = ([p.sub.1], [p.sub.2], ...,
[p.sub.N]) and budget [omega]. When modifications occur of price
[p.sub.j] of good j, for a fix j we obtain:
[N.summation over (i=1)] [p.sub.i] [partial
derivative][x.sub.i]/[partial derivative][p.sub.j] (p, [omega]) =
-[x.sub.j] (p, [omega]) (2)
In order for equality (2) to take place, it is absolutely necessary
for the sum in the left side to be negative, compensating by this the
positive value of [x.sub.j]. It is immediately deduced that in this sum
there should exist at least one negative element, large enough in order
to compensate for the potential positive nature of the other terms.
Because [p.sub.k] represents a price, it is understood that it can only
be a positive measure, hence we finally deduce that:
([there exists] k [member of] {1, ..., N} such that [partial
derivative][x.sub.k]/[partial derivative][p.sub.j] (p, [omega]) < 0.
The last formal writing can be interpreted by that there is at
least one product, k for which the quantity purchased by the consumer
decreases upon the increase of price [p.sub.j]. Whereas the increase of
a single price implies the decrease of the quantity for at least one of
the products wanted by the consumer under the condition of unmodified budget, there can be expected that when the increase is recorded
simultaneously for more prices, then the purchased quantities will
decrease even more. What is essential in describing this case is the
fact that nothing in the formal side of the phenomena can ensure for the
time being that a decrease in the quantity is automatically reflected on
the product the price of which has modified. The aspect must be kept in
mind and we shall insist on it by further comments.
2. IMPLICATIONS OF WALRAS' LAW OVER THE LAW OF DEMAND
We consider that a certain consumer manifests a demand x (p,
[omega]) which has N components, each position indicating the demand for
the corresponding good or service from N existent and available in the
economy. We are going to limit only to one arbitrary position i [member
of] {1, ..., N} and we'll know that [x.sub.i] (p, [omega])
represents the demand for good i under the stated conditions. Accepting
the context of ceteris paribus, we'll admit that only price
[p.sub.i] is variable, while the rest of the influence factors remain
constant and hence the function [x.sub.i] (p, [omega]) becomes of only
one variable, [x.sub.i] ([p.sub.i]) . Further more, the economists say
that a consumer will react promptly to the price conditions, meaning
that along with the increase of [p.sub.i] the demand function will
acquire a decreasing behavior, which is actually a well known feature
that we find stated in all specialized literature. Even if such attitude
is somehow understandable, we must draw the attention on the fact that
not a thing revealing out of the formalization of Walras' Law
renders such with a mandatory nature.
In the first section we came to the conclusion that once the price
[p.sub.i] is increased, there definitely exists a quantity [x.sub.k] of
which we can assert that it decreases, but we have no valid arguments
helping us know whether this is exactly the quantity [x.sub.i]. The only
context in which the decrease of [x.sub.i] could be claimed is the one
in which we are certain that there is no chance for this consumer to
waive any unit from the other goods, although the situation described
herein clearly exceeds the framework of ceteris paribus, which refers to
prices and not to quantities. It is true that the choices made by the
consumer are those which he prefers most, meaning it could become
apprehensive to say that all the quantities from the other goods
maximize the preferences and therefore their change is not intended. On
the other hand, we know that preferences can change once the
restrictions are modified. The increase of [p.sub.i] represents exactly
this sort of modification, thus the only argument which could help us
remains invalid.
In conclusion, we have every reason to question why the economists
consider that the "inverse" relation between price and the
demanded quantity from the corresponding product is a general truth,
usually stated under the name of Law of Demand and referring to the
market demand. In order for us to be able to pertinently comment on this
Law, which is somehow outside the common sense assertions, however not
being definitely supported by what has been emphasized by formal tools,
we need to go back at this point to identity (2) above and to the
consequences of its validity. We have established and appropriately
argued that an increase in price [p.sub.i] determines a decrease in the
quantity purchased by the consumer from at least one of the goods he
wants, for instance k. We assume now that this good is not by any means
the one for which the price increase was recorded, therefore k [not
equal to] i. This means that [x.sub.i], the purchased quantity from good
i remained the same and that in the consumer's list the quantity of
at least one product decreased. We define [[??].sub.k] as the new
quantity of product k, obviously smaller than [x.sub.k] and [[??].sub.i]
as the new price of good i, obviously larger than [p.sub.i]. If these
two measures modify, then Walras' Law for the situations
"before" and "after" the occurrence of the change is
written as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Diminishing each member of the two equalities, we obtain:
[p.sub.k][DELTA][x.sub.k] = [x.sub.i][DELTA][p.sub.i] (3)
It is highly important to notice that the left side of the last
equality represents the sum which the consumer should pay in addition
for the quantitative difference from good k to which he is forced to
give up consequent to the fact that he chooses to keep unchanged the
quantity [x.sub.i] from the good the price of which increased. If for a
minute we don't take into account the minus sign, the right side
represents the money difference which should be supported consequent to
maintaining the consume of good i constant, although its price rises.
Relation (3) actually illustrates a "cost" of the
consumer's decision, which the economists call opportunity cost.
Although the consumer does not actually spend more than his budget which
remains unchanged, there is however a measurable effect of the potential
waive, which is the opportunity price of the version of maintaining
[x.sub.i] constant.
In all probability relation (3) is one of the few manners in which
this cost, considered as not-accountancy and somehow difficult to
emphasize in the various situations we can encounter in practice, can be
however formally expressed and represents one of the arguments in favor
of Law of Demand's functionality. It is only natural to notice in
this context that while [[??].sub.i] increases, the difference
[DELTA][p.sub.i] in its turn increases, so that the opportunity cost for
keeping [x.sub.i] constant increases as well, up to a critical point
from which the consumer stops finding it reasonable to buy a quantity of
the product which would compel him, grounded on relation (3) to reduce
the quantity of one or more products he finds necessary. This perfectly
real phenomenon cannot be viewed by simply applying the derivation operator in (3).
The opportunity cost is not the tool of a mechanism for reducing
the demanded quantity which could be mandatory put into practice along
with the increase in a product's price. The reason is a matter of
the consumer's perception over the initial price [p.sub.i] and over
the new price [[??].sub.i], whilst the economics theory refers to this
context by means of the concept of "consumer surplus". This
concept includes a side which is very difficult to measure and which has
an impact which can hardly be foreseen over the quantity which the
consumer is willing to purchase once the price increases. It can be
argued that besides any subjective dimension the individual must pay
from the same amount c, and then the opportunity cost exists no matter
how large or small is the consumer's surplus. Once more we must say
that the formal relation (3) is not enough in order to understand the
context. If the consumer's surplus for good i is clearly larger
than for any other good on the list, then it is probably that this
opportunity cost could function somehow in the opposite direction,
generating a thinking such as: "the good k seemed kind of
expensive, anyway; instead of maintaining the quantity I buy constantly,
I'd rather reduce it and direct the money towards good i, which has
a more reasonable price". Therefore, the opportunity cost manifests
as an instrument for reducing the demand only when the consumers'
surplus for the goods under discussion becomes a relatively uniform
measure in the life of decisions made by the individuals. In order to
agree with this last assertion, we must say that the consumer surplus
implicitly includes the qualitative component, which is difficult to
measure, namely the need of the individual for the respective product.
Regardless whether it is a real need or if it describes a consume habit,
keeping a tradition or an anticipation regarding the market situation,
it is the first one of effective importance when it comes to
interpreting the opportunity cost.
3. CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS
We dare to assert that the Law of Demand is a truth which might not
manifest itself as a prompt phenomenon consequent to the price
modification, and that it is actually possible for the "curve"
of the function modeling the price-quantity relation to be sometimes
null and to ascertain by such a constant in the consume, until the
economical entities decide to react to the impact of the opportunity
cost. Far from being unimportant, this possible tendency of the demand
of remaining constant for a period of time has a strong impact in the
research of critical loss which might be registered consequent to
increasing the price at a certain moment. The concept actually takes
shape as "demand inertia", which once established is of help
in deciding the level of increasing the price which allows the
enterpriser to increase his profit throughout the period left until the
consumers' reply.
4. REFERENCES
Arrow, K. J., (1977). Social Choice and Individual Values (Paperback), Yale University Press; 2d Ed edition, ISBN-10: 0300013647,
ISBN-13: 978-0300013641, USA
Beattie, B. & LaFrance, J. (2006). The Law of Demand versus
Diminishing Marginal Utility. Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 28,
No.2, March 2006, p. 263-271, ISSN 1058-7195
Teira, D. (2006). A Positivist Tradition in Early Demand Theory.
Journal of Economic Methodology, Vol. 13, No.1, March 2006, p. 25-47,
ISSN 1350-178X
Walker, D. A. (1984). William Jaffe's Essays on Walras.
Economica, New Series, Vol. 51, No. 204, Nov., 1984, p. 480-481, ISSN
00130427
Zhang, Y. C. (2005). Supply and Demand under Limited Information,
Physica A, Vol. 350, No.2-4, May 2005, p. 599-532, ISSN 0378-4371