Political institutions and comparative development.
Acemoglu, Daron ; Robinson, James A.
A great deal of evidence suggests that different patterns of
economic development are causally related to differences in economic
institutions. Countries that create inclusive and secure property rights
and the rule of law grow, while those that do not stagnate or decline.
(1)
But why do economic institutions vary so much across, and even
within, countries? Though there are different approaches to this
question, a central one emphasizes that economic institutions (conceived
broadly to include economic policies) are outcomes of processes of
collective choice. Such choices are shaped by the political institutions
that distribute power, aggregate preferences and interests, place
constraints, and determine the payoffs to different strategies in the
political process.
This perspective suggests that there ought to be evidence of
systemic relationships between political institutions, economic
institutions and policies, and economic outcomes.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Perhaps the largest research effort has gone into investigating the
impact of democracy on economic growth. There is obviously a strong
correlation between levels of GDP per capita and the extent of
democracy, yet at the same time theoretical work suggests that not all
the mechanisms unleashed by moving political institutions from
autocratic to democratic are positive for economic growth.
Democratization tends to shift power away from narrow elites
towards the mass of people. That can favor redistribution, the provision
of public goods in society, (2) and expansion of the role of the state
in society. These very processes may or may not be good for economic
growth. Redistribution can lead to distortions and disincentives, (3) or
it can stimulate growth. (4) The same is true of the expansion of the
size or role of the state. Finally, democratic political competition can
be very clientelistic, mitigating against the provision of public goods.
There is also obviously a considerable amount of heterogeneity in this
process. Dictatorships and democracies alike vary greatly in their
institutional architecture--such as in the extent of checks and balances
(5)--and societies that have ostensibly democratic politics may have
political power concentrated in the hands of a small group of economic
elites or bureaucrats.
Despite this evident heterogeneity, it is interesting to ask what
the average effect of moving from autocratic to democratic political
institutions is on economic policies and institutions and on economic
growth. We do that in our paper with Suresh Naidu and Pascual Restrepo.
(6) Ours is hardly the first study of this relationship but,
interestingly, the conventional wisdom has been that democratization has
at best small positive effects on economic growth. Our paper shows that
this "non result" is driven by the complicated dynamics of GDP
around democratization.
It is a robust fact that democratizations are often precipitated by
recessions and negative economic shocks. Clearly, unless one controls
for this properly, one can easily make a spurious inference about the
impact of democracy. We control for this using two different strategies.
The first is to control for lags of GDP in linear regressions. The
second is to adapt to our panel context the semi-parametric time-series
estimators proposed by Joshua Angrist and Guido Kuersteiner, (7) and
Angrist, Oscar Jorda, and Kuersteiner, (8) which use propensity
score-based matching methods to correct for the effects of GDP dynamics.
Beyond this problem lies the question of identification. In addition to
controlling for a full set of country and year fixed effects, we address
this issue with an instrumental-variables (IV) strategy. We develop an
instrument for democracy based on regional waves of democratizations and
reversals.
Our identification assumption is that democratization in a country
spreads to other nondemocratic countries in the same region, but does
not have a direct differential impact on economic growth in these
countries, at least conditional on lagged levels of country and regional
GDP and various covariates that could be correlated with country-level
GDP at the year, region, and initial regime level.
Focusing on a dichotomous variable which classifies regimes as
either democratic or not based primarily on whether or not a country has
free and fair elections with universal suffrage, our central estimates
suggest that a country which switches from autocracy to democracy
achieves about 20 percent higher GDP per capita over roughly 30 years.
We also investigate some of the mechanisms via which this may happen and
find broadly consistent positive estimates for the effect of democracy
on tax-to-GDP ratio and primary school enrollment rates.
But, as already noted, there is much more to the variation in
political institutions than differences in democracy. Indeed, the
quantitative magnitude of the results discussed above shows that the
main institutional difference between poor and rich countries is most
likely not that the former tend to be undemocratic while the latter are
democratic. Our study, like most, uses a minimalist definition of
democracy which leaves out detailed features of the constitutions of
countries that help determine the strength of checks and balances and
constraints on the use of power. (9) Moreover, how a given set of formal
political institutions functions varies greatly across societies.
Finally, and equally importantly, there are major differences
across and within nations in the way the state is organized. Having a
state with "capacity"--to regulate, implement and govern, to
establish order, monopolize force, and raise revenues--is potentially an
important prerequisite for economic growth. A large social science
literature suggests that many facets of modernity are consequences of
the development of states, including not just economic growth (10) but
also identities (11) and values. (12)
To see why the nature of the state might be an important
determinant of comparative development, consider the following famous
puzzle identified by Robert Lucas:
"In I960 the Philippines and South Korea had about the same
standard of living as measured by their per-capita GDPs of about $640
U.S. (measured in 19-5 prices). The two countries were similar in many
other respects.... In both countries, all boys of primary school age
were in school, and almost all girls, but only about a quarter of
secondary school age children were in school. Only 5 percent of Koreans
in their early twenties were in college, as compared to 13 percent in
the Philippines. Twenty-six percent of Philippine GDP was generated in
agriculture, and 28 percent in industry. In Korea, the comparable
numbers were 37 and 20 percent." (13)
Despite all these similarities, a radical economic divergence
ensued. Lucas' explanation is based on differential patterns of
learning by doing and human capital accumulation related to openness.
Human capital certainly accumulated a lot faster in Korea, but from our
perspective Lucas' discussion of what was different about Korea and
the Philippines in 1960 is very narrow. A huge unmentioned difference
was that Korea was able to lay claim to a long history of centralized,
bureaucratized, state authority with a homogeneous national identity.
The Philippines was not.
Though we often take for granted that states have
"capacity," this is in fact missing in many less-developed
parts of the world. And there are large challenges to pinpointing the
role of state capacity in promoting economic development. State capacity
is multi-dimensional, and we have few theories how political capacity,
fiscal capacity, and bureaucratic capacity co-vary or are determined.
They obviously may be influenced by development or by other factors,
such as the nature of society (think of homogeneous Korea). Thus there
are problems of both reverse causality and endogeneity to be addressed
before we can say convincingly that state capacity plays a causal role
in promoting economic development.
In joint work with Camilo Garcia Jimeno, we study the effect of
state capacity of Colombian municipalities on public goods provision and
development outcomes. (14) We conceptualize state capacity as the
presence of state functionaries and agencies. This represents a central
aspect of what Michael Mann calls the "infrastructural power"
of the state. (15) Colombia provides an ideal laboratory for such an
investigation because there is a wide diversity of development and
public good outcomes across Colombian municipalities. For example, the
proportion of the population above the poverty line in the 2005 census
and average secondary school enrollment 1992-2002 vary from near zero to
100 percent.
Our data exhibit strong positive correlations between our basic
measures of state capacity and both public good provision and
development outcomes. But are these indicative of a causal relationship?
To address this question, we develop an identification strategy based on
the history of Colombian state formation. In particular, we focus on two
variables: the historical presence of colonial state officials and
agencies in 1794 and the location of the colonial "royal
roads" network. This network has disappeared and thus provides an
attractive source of variation in the historical presence of the state
and the cost of building and expanding local state capacity, especially
when we control for distance to current roads. There is indeed a
positive correlation between the number of colonial state employees at
the municipality level and the same measure today. Since the
state-building strategy of the colonial authorities was quite unrelated
to subsequent republican state-building aims, this historical data
creates an appealing source of variation.
Yet reverse causality and omitted variables biases are not the only
challenges to estimating the impact of state capacity on development. We
argue that local state capacity in one municipality is likely to create
spillovers on public good provision and economic outcomes, and even on
state capacity development, in neighboring municipalities. We formulate
a simple, empirically operational model of such spillovers and develop
an econometric strategy for identifying them. Our results reveal fairly
large spillovers across municipalities and also non-trivial strategic
effects whereby greater state capacity in one municipality induces an
increase in the state capacity of neighboring municipalities.
The theory of how state capacity in one municipality should affect
that in other jurisdictions is ambiguous. When one municipality can
free-ride on the investments of neighboring localities, a high spending
level in one location may reduce the optimal outlay in adjoining
jurisdictions. When greater state capacity in one jurisdiction makes it
less costly to build such capacity in adjoining jurisdictions, or raises
the benefits of such outlays, then greater spending in one location will
be associated with higher outlays in neighboring jurisdictions.
Theoretically, how these strategic effects should work out is
unclear. If municipalities free-ride on their neighbors'
investments, state capacity choices will be strategic substitutes.
Conversely, if municipalities find it harder or less beneficial to build
state capacity when it is missing in their neighborhood, they will be
strategic complements. We incorporate these strategic aspects by
modeling the building of state capacity as a network game. We then
estimate the parameters of this model, exploiting both the network
structure and the exogenous sources of variation discussed above.
Our benchmark estimates imply, for example, that moving all
municipalities below median state capacity to the median will have a
"partial equilibrium" direct effect (holding the level of
state capacity of all municipalities above the median constant) of
reducing the median poverty rate by 3 percentage points, increasing the
median coverage rate of public utilities (electricity, aqueduct and
sewage) by 4 percentage points, and increasing the median secondary
school enrollment rate by 3 percentage points. About 57 percent of these
impacts is due to a direct effect, while 43 percent is due to network
spillovers, The "full equilibrium" effect is very different,
however. Once we take into account the equilibrium responses to the
initial changes in local state capacity in the network, median coverage
rate of public utilities increases 10 percentage points, the median
fraction of the population in poverty falls by 11 percentage points, and
median secondary school enrollment rates increase by over 26 percentage
points. These large impacts, which are entirely due to network effects,
highlight not only the central role that state capacity plays in
economic development but also the importance of taking the full
equilibrium effects into account.
Much remains to be done in understanding theoretically and
empirically how political institutions shape development. Clearly other
forms of state capacity need to be investigated and the external
validity of our results probed. Also important is to consider how
different political institutions interact. James A. Robinson is a
research associate in the NBER's Programs on the History of the
American Economy and Political Economy. As of July 1, 2015, he will be a
University Professor at the Harris School of Public Policy at the
University of Chicago.
Robinson's research focuses on comparative economic and
political development from both a theoretical and an empirical
perspective. Over the past two decades, he has conducted research and
collected data in Botswana, Chile, the Democratic Republic of the Congo,
Haiti, the Philippines, Sierra Leone, South Africa, and Colombia, where
he teaches every summer at the University of the Andes in Bogota. He is
co-author with Daron Acemoglu of the books Economic Origins of
Dictatorship and Democracy and Why Nations Fail.
Robinson received a B.Sc. in economics from the London School of
Economics in 1982, an M.A. in economics from the University of
"Wirwick in 1987, and his Ph.D. in economics from Yale University
in 1993. Before joining the Chicago faculty, he taught at Harvard
University, die University of California, Berkeley, die University of
Southern California, and the University of Melbourne.
Robinson lives in Somerville, Massachusetts, with his wife and
younger son. In his spare time, he enjoys exploring the world with his
elder son, dancing salsa with his wife, listening to music and reading
history, anthropology, and archaeology books.
Daran Accmoglu is Elizabeth and James Killian Professor of
Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology
His areas of research include political economy, economic
development and growth, human capital theory, growth theory, innovation,
search theory, network economics and learning.
His recent research focuses on the political, economic, and social
causes of differences in economic development across societies; the
factors affecting the institutional and political evolution of nations;
and how technology impacts growth and distribution of resources and is
itself determined by economic and social incentives.
In addition to scholarly articles, Acemoglu has published several
books: Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, jointly with
James A. Robinson; Why Nations Fail, also jointly with Robinson; and
Economics, jointly with David Taibson and John List.
Acemoglu is a fellow of the National Academy of Sciences, the
Science Academy (Turkey), the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, and
the Econometric Society. He was the recipient of the John Bates Clark
Medal in 2005, and the Erwin Plein Nemmers Prize. He holds honorary
doctorates from the University of Utrecht, Bosporus University, and the
University of Athens. He received his B.A. in economics at the
University of York, M.Sc. in mathematical economics and econometrics at
the London School of Economics, and Ph.D. in economics at the London
School of Economics. He lives in Newton, Massachusetts with his wife,
Asu Ozdaglar, and his two young sons, Arda and Aras.
(1) D. Acemoglu, S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson, "The Colonial
Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical
Investigation',' NBER Working Paper No. 7771, June 2000, and
American Economic Review, 91(5), 2001, pp. 1369-1401; D. Acemoglu, F. A.
Gallego, and J A. Robinson, "Institutions, Human Capital and
Development)' NBER Working Paper No. 19933, February 2014, and
Annual Review of Economics, 6(1), 2014, pp. 875-912. Return to text
(2) A. Lizzeri, and N. Persico, "Why Did the Elites Extend the
Suffrage? Democracy and the Scope of Government, With an Application to
Britain's Age of Reform,'" Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 119(2), 2004, pp. 707-65. Return to text
(3) A. Alesina and D. Rodrik "Distributive Politics and
Economic Growth," NBER Working Paper No. 3668, March 1991, and
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(2), 1994, pp. 465-90; T. Persson and
G. Tabellini, "Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?" NBER Working
Paper No. 3599, January 1991, and American Economic Review, 84(3), 1994,
pp. 600-21. Return to text
(4) G. Saint-Paul and T. Verdier, "Education, Democracy and
Growth," Journal of Development Economics, 42(2), 1993, pp.
399-407. Return to text
(5) D. Acemoglu, J. A. Robinson, and R. Torvik, "Why Do I
bters Dismantle Checks and Balances?" NBER Working Paper No. 17293,
August 2011, and Review of Economic Studies, 80(3), 2013, pp. 845-75.
Return to text
(6) D. Acemoglu, S. Naidu, P. Restrepo, and J. A. Robinson,
"Democracy Does Cause Growth," NBER Working Paper No. 20004,
March 2014. Return to text
(7) J. D. Angrist and G. Kuersteiner, "Causal Effects of
Monetary Shocks: Semiparametric Conditional Independence Tests with a
Multinomial Propensity Score," Review of Economics and Statistics,
93(3), 2011, pp. 725-47. Return to text
(8) J. D. Angrist, O. Jorda, and G. Kuersteiner,
"Semiparametric Estimates of Monetary Policy Effects: String Theory
Revisited)' NBER Working Paper No. 19355, August 2013. Return to
text
(9) D. Acemoglu, S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson, "The Rise of
Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth."
NBER Working Paper No. 9378, December 2002, and American Economic
Review, 95(3), 2005, pp. 546-79; D. C. North and B. R. Weingast,
"Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutional
Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England, "Journal of
Economic History, 49(4), 1989, pp. 803-32. Return to text
(10) P. B. Evans, Embedded Autonomy, Princeton, New Jersey:
Princeton University Press, 1995; J. I. Herbst, States and Power in
Africa, Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2000. Return
to text
(11) E. Gellner, Nations and Nationalism, Oxford, United Kingdom:
Blackwell, 1983. Return to text
(12) N. Elias, The Civilizing Process, Volume I. The History of
Manners, Oxford, United Kingdom: Blackwell, 1969; N Elias, The
Civilizing Process, Volume II, State Formation and Civilization, Oxjord,
United Kingdom: Blackwell, 1982; M. Foucault, Discipline and Punish: the
Birth of the Prison, New York, New York: Random House, 1975. Return to
text
(13) R. E. Lucas, Jr., "Making a Miracle)' Econometrica,
61(2), 1993, p. 251. Return to text
(14) D. Acemoglu, C. Garcia-Jimeno, and J. A. Robinson, "State
Capacity and Economic Development: A Network Approach)' NBER
Working Paper No. 19813, January 2014, and forthcoming in American
Economic Review. Return to text
(15) M. Mann, Sources of State Power: Volume 1, A History of Power
from the Beginning to AD 1760, New York, New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1986. Return to text