Economic consequences of gender identity.
Bertrand, Marianne
An increasingly discussed explanation for why women and men
experience different labor markets is the existence and persistence of
gender identity norms. Influential research by George Akerlof and Rachel
Kranton (1) has imported into economics insights from social psychology
regarding an individual's social identity and how it can influence
behaviors and choices. These researchers define identity as one's
sense of belonging to one or multiple social categories. One's
identity encompasses a clear view about how people who belong to that
category should behave. In their model, identity directly enters the
utility function: identity influences economic outcomes because
deviating from the behavior that is expected for one's social
category is assumed to decrease utility. Hence, people's economic
actions can in part be explained by a desire to conform with their sense
of self. Akerlof and Kranton apply their model to the concept of gender
identity. In this case, the two relevant social categories are those of
"man" and "woman," and these two categories are
associated with specific behavioral prescriptions which, if violated,
will decrease utility.
Gender identity norms may help to explain why occupational
segregation by gender has been slow to disappear. Women may feel
discomfort entering certain professions, and men may feel discomfort if
women enter these professions if the professions are strongly
"gendered" (for example, only men, not women, are bankers).
This is related to Claudia Goldin's pollution theory of
discrimination, (2) which also assumes that men derive utility from
their work not just because of the wage they earn but also because of
how their image is affected by where they work and with whom they work.
In Goldin's model, men want to keep women away from certain jobs
because broad female participation in those jobs would reduce the
prestige men obtain from working in them. The reduction in prestige in
Goldin's case is driven by the signals that might be sent to
outsiders about the qualifications required to perform these jobs if too
many women enter them. In other words, Goldin's model is closer to
a statistical discrimination model while Akerlof and Kranton's is
more directly reminiscent of a taste-based discrimination model.
Another application is women's labor force participation. As
long as there is a strong behavioral prescription indicating that
"men work in the labor force and women work in the home,"
gender identity norms could explain why women have been slow to increase
their labor force participation. Nicole Fortin uses data from the World
Values Surveys to assess how women's sense of self relates to their
labor force participation in a sample of OECD countries. (3) She shows
that the social representation of women as homemakers and men as
breadwinners appears quite predictive of women's labor force
participation across countries. Fortin reexamines a similar question in
a single country, the United States, over a longer time period (1977 to
2006). (4) A more central motivation in this particular paper is to
provide an explanation for the slowdown in the closing of the gender gap
in labor force participation in the United States since the mid-1990s
(see for example Francine Blau and Charles Kahn (5)). Fortin shows that
the evolution of gender role attitudes over time appears to map well
with the evolution of female labor force participation. Women's
gender role attitudes steadily became less traditional, with more and
more women disagreeing with the notion that husbands should be the
breadwinners and wives should be the homemakers, and more egalitarian,
with more and more women agreeing with the notion that they are as
capable as men in the workforce, until the mid-1990s when these trends
reversed. Raquel Fernandez and Alessandra Fogli study the labor force
participation of second-generation American women. (6) They use past
values of female labor force participation in these women's country
of ancestry as cultural proxies for gender identity norms. Controlling
for individual and spousal socioeconomic backgrounds, they find that
American women whose ancestry is from higher labor force participation
countries work more. Spousal culture also appears to matter in
explaining the labor force participation of these women.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Motherhood has been shown to be particularly disruptive to
women's labor force participation and earnings. With Lawrence Katz
and Goldin, I demonstrate that much of the large gender gap that emerges
over time between male and female graduates of top MBA programs is
attributable to gender differences in hours worked and frequency of
career interruptions; the presence of children is the main contributor
to women's shorter work hours and greater career discontinuity. (7)
The fact that work-family balance considerations are more binding for
mothers than for fathers could be seen as another manifestation of
gender identity norms (for example, "a working mom cannot have a
warm relationship with her child") that have not fully adjusted to
improving educational and labor market opportunities for women.
Another behavioral prescription often associated with gender
identity is that "a man should earn more than his wife." With
Emir Kamenica and Jessica Pan, I explore the possible manifestations of
this gender identity norm in patterns of relative income within
households, marriage formation, wives' labor force participation,
marital satisfaction, and the division of home production. 8 Using U.S.
administrative data on individual income, we show that the distribution
of relative income within couples (wife income/(wife income + husband
income)) exhibits a sharp drop to the right of .5, for example, when a
wife starts to earn more than her husband. This is shown in Figure 1,
above.
In U.S. Census data, we also show that within a marriage market
over time, when a randomly chosen woman becomes more likely to earn more
than a randomly chosen man, the marriage rate declines (see also Tara
Watson and Sara McLanahan (9)). Looking within couples, we show that
when the probability that the wife's potential income exceeds her
husband's actual income is higher, the wife is less likely to
participate in the labor force. We also provide suggestive evidence that
this specific gender identity norm might influence the quality of
marriage, with couples where the wife earns more than the husband
reporting being less happy. Finally, using the American Time Use
Surveys, we show that the gender gap in home production, how much more
time the wife spends on non-market work than the husband, is larger in
couples where the wife earns more than the husband, a finding that runs
counter to standard models of the division of labor within the
household.
One could also ask whether gender identity norms are responsible
for gender differences in psychological attributes, such as attitudes
toward risk, negotiation, and competition, which have been related to
differences in career choices and earnings between men and women (10)
and might contribute to women's under-representation at the very
top of the corporate hierarchy. (11) Psychologists have shown that
people expect women to be docile and men to be confident and
self-assertive. Some have argued that a higher degree of risk aversion
is viewed as the norm for females while part of the male identity is to
be a risk-taker. These expectations could be part of socially
constructed gender norms, rather than a reflection on innate
differences; behaving according to these expectations may reflect a
willingness to conform to what is expected from one's social
category.
In a laboratory setting, Daniel Benjamin, James Choi, and A. Joshua
Strickland study how making salient a specific aspect of one's
gender or racial identity affects a subject's likelihood of making
riskier choices or more patient choices. 12 The study consists of
generating exogenous variation in identity effects by temporarily making
more salient ("priming") a certain social category and seeing
how the subjects' choices are affected by this priming. The gender
identity salience manipulation is done through a questionnaire at the
beginning of the experiment in which subjects are asked to identify
their gender and whether they are living on a coed versus a single-sex
dormitory floor. While the study uncovers some rich patterns with
respect to racial identity, making gender salient appears to have no
significant effects on either men's or women's patience, or
their level of risk aversion. Of course, it is possible that the
experimental priming was too weak to temporarily affect preferences.
Assuming that the gender identity model is relevant to women's
labor market outcomes, one is left with the question of what drives the
strength of gender identity norms. In an identity model, the changes in
women's labor market outcomes over the last decades could only have
occurred in conjunction with deep societal changes in the strength and
meaning of the male and female social categories. Innovations in
contraception may have contributed to altering women's identity in
the 1960s and 1970s. As Goldin and Katz show, the introduction of the
birth control pill led to both an increase in women's investment in
schooling and an increase in the age at first marriage. (13) This,
Goldin argues, meant that women's adult identities were less
influenced by traditional gender roles, as these identities were now
more likely to be formed before marriage and more influenced by career
considerations. (14)
Other papers have discussed the influence of nurturing in the
formation of gender identities. Many believe that gender role attitudes
are largely determined in early childhood, and several papers have
documented something akin to an intergenerational transmission of gender
identity norms. Fernandez, Fogli, and Claudia Olivetti (15) provide an
explanation for why men may differ in how traditional their views are
with respect to whether women belong at home or in the workplace. They
argue that a significant factor in the steady increase of women's
involvement in the labor force has been the growing number of men being
raised in families with working mothers. These men may have developed
less stereotypical gender role attitudes, with weaker association
between their masculinity and being the only or main breadwinner in
their household. In particular, they show that men whose mothers worked
are more likely to have working wives. This finding suggests a virtuous
cycle: with more of these "new" men around, women should
rationally invest more in labor market skills and thereby expose their
sons to this less traditional family structure.
Olivetti, Eleonora Patacchini, and Yves Zenou explore how the work
behavior of a teenager's own mother, as well as that of her
friends' mothers, affect the work decisions of that teenager once
she becomes an adult. (16) They find that both intergenerational
channels positively affect a woman's work hours in adulthood, but
the cross effect is negative, indicating the existence of cultural
substitutability. That is, the mother's role model effect is larger
the more distant she is (in terms of working hours) from the
friends' mothers.
While the literature discussed above suggests the malleability of
gender identity norms over rather short horizons (one generation), other
work suggests stickiness of these norms in the longer term. Alberto
Alesina, Paola Giuliano, and Nathan Nunn show that ethnicities and
countries where ancestors practiced plough cultivation, which required
more physical strength than shifting cultivation and hence was less
suited to female labor, today have beliefs that exhibit greater gender
inequality as well as lower rates of female labor force participation.
(17) They identify the causal impact of plough cultivation use by
exploiting variation in the historical geo-climatic suitability of the
environment for growing crops that differentially benefited from the
adoption of the plough.
(1) G. A. Akerlof and R. E. Kranton, "Economics and
Identity," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (2000), pp. 715-53.
(2) C. Goldin, "A Pollution Theory of Discrimination: Male and
Female Differences in Occupations and Earnings," NBER Working Paper
No. 8985, June 2002, and forthcoming in Leah P. Boustan, C. Frydman, and
R. A. Margo, eds., Human Capital in History: The American Record,
Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2014.
(3) N. Fortin, "Gender Role Attitudes and the Labour Market
Outcomes of Women Across OECD Countries," Oxford Review of Economic
Policy, 21 (2005), pp. 41638.
(4) N. Fortin, "Gender Role Attitudes and Women's Labor
Market Participation: Opting Out, AIDS, and the Persistent Appeal of
Housewifery" University of British Columbia Working Paper, December
2013.
(5) F. D. Blau and L. M. Kahn, "Female Labor Supply: Why is
the U.S. Falling Behind?" NBER Working Paper No. 18702, January
2013, and American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 103 (2013),
pp. 251-6.
(6) R. Fernandez and A. Fogli, "Culture: An Empirical
Investigation of Beliefs, Work, and Fertility" NBER Working Paper
No. 11268, April 2005, and American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1
(2009), pp. 146-77.
(7) M. Bertrand, C. Goldin, and L. F. Katz, "Dynamics of the
Gender Gap for Young Professionals in the Corporate and Financial
Sectors," NBER Working Paper No. 14681, January 2009, and American
Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2 (2010), pp. 228-55.
(8) M. Bertrand, J. Pan, and E. Kamenica, "Gender Identity and
Relative Income within Households," NBER Working Paper No. 19023,
May 2013.
(9) T. Watson and S. McLanahan, "Marriage Meets the Joneses:
Relative Income, Identity, and Marital Status," NBER Working Paper
No. 14773, March 2009, and Journal of Human Resources, 46 (2011), pp.
482-517.
(10) See M. Niederle and L. Vesterlund, "Do Women Shy Away
From Competition? Do Men Compete Too Much?" NBER Working Paper No.
11474, July 2005, and Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (2007), pp.
1067-101; and T. Buser, M. Niederle, and H. Oosterbeek, "Gender,
Competitiveness and Career Choices," NBER Working Paper No. 18576,
November 2012, and forthcoming in Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129
(2014).
(11) M. Bertrand and K. F. Hallock, "The Gender Gap in Top
Corporate Jobs," NBER Working Paper No. 7931, October 2000, and
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 55 (2001), pp. 3-21.
(12) D. J. Benjamin, J. J. Choi, and A. J. Strickland, "Social
Identity and Preferences," NBER Working Paper No. 13309, August
2007, and American Economic Review, 100 (2010), pp. 1913-28.
(13) C. Goldin and L. F. Katz, "The Power of the Pill: Oral
Contraceptives and Women's Career and Marriage Decisions" NBER
Working Paper No. 7527, February 2000, and Journal of Political Economy,
110 (2002), pp. 730-70.
(14) C. Goldin, "The Quiet Revolution that Transformed
Women's Employment, Education, and Family," NBER Working Paper
No. 11953, January 2006, and American Economic Review: Papers and
Proceedings, 96 (2006), pp. 1-21.
(15) R. Fernandez, A. Fogli, and C. Olivetti, "Preference
Formation and the Rise of Women's Labor Force Participation:
Evidence from WWII" NBER Working Paper No. 10589, June 2004; R.
Fernandez, A. Fogli, and C. Olivetti, "Marrying Your Mom:
Preference Transmission and Women's Labor and Education
Choices," NBER Working Paper No. 9234, September 2002; and R.
Fernandez, A. Fogli, and C. Olivetti, "Mothers and Sons: Preference
Formation and Female Labor Force Dynamics," Quarterly Journal of
Economics 119 (2004), pp. 1249-99.
(16) C. Olivetti, E. Patacchini, Y. Zenou, "Mothers, Friends,
and Gender Identity," NBER Working Paper No. 19610, November 2013.
(17) A. F. Alesina, P. Giuliano, and N. Nunn, "On the Origins
of Gender Roles: Women and the Plough," NBER Working Paper No.
17098, May 2011, and Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128 (2013), pp.
469-530.
Marianne Bertrand *
* Bertrand is a Research Associate in the NBER's Programs on
Corporate Finance, Development Economics, and Labor Studies, and the
Chris P. Dialynas Distinguished Service Professor of Economics at the
University of Chicago's Booth School of Business. Her profile
appears later in this issue.